id
int64
673k
4.14M
tag
stringlengths
1
39.7k
cite
stringlengths
1
8.39k
fullcite
stringlengths
1
50.9k
summary
stringlengths
1
47k
spoken
stringlengths
1
13.9k
fulltext
stringlengths
1
138k
textLength
float64
0
138k
markup
stringlengths
10
139k
pocket
stringlengths
1
863
hat
stringlengths
1
5.45k
block
stringlengths
1
16.5k
bucketId
int64
37
1.65M
duplicateCount
int64
1
3.81k
fileId
int64
14k
129k
filePath
stringlengths
60
188
roundId
int64
565k
915k
side
stringclasses
2 values
tournament
stringlengths
1
62
round
stringclasses
34 values
opponent
stringlengths
1
57
judge
stringlengths
1
87
report
stringlengths
1
612k
opensourcePath
stringlengths
48
176
caselistUpdatedAt
float64
teamId
int64
48.4k
77.9k
teamName
stringlengths
3
5
teamDisplayName
stringlengths
8
31
notes
float64
debater1First
stringclasses
164 values
debater1Last
stringclasses
183 values
debater2First
stringclasses
151 values
debater2Last
stringclasses
186 values
schoolId
int64
18.7k
26.1k
schoolName
stringclasses
306 values
schoolDisplayName
stringclasses
306 values
state
float64
chapterId
float64
caselistId
int64
1k
1.04k
caselistName
stringclasses
10 values
caselistDisplayName
stringclasses
10 values
year
int64
2.01k
2.02k
event
stringclasses
2 values
level
stringclasses
2 values
teamSize
int64
1
2
742,005
The only issue was discrimination---that law applied differently between U.S. and foreign operators---which the CP solves.
Chander 9
Chander 9 – Anupam Chander, Visiting Professor, The University of Chicago Law School; Professor, University of California, Davis. Yale Law School, J.D. Harvard College, “Trade 2.0”, The Yale Journal of International Law, Summer, 34 Yale J. Int'l L. 281, Lexis
Antigua responded filed a claim against the U S before the WTO the market access requirement, the U S argued, did not bar a total prohibition on a particular service The Appellate Body, held that a blanket prohibition operated as a "zero quota," and thus presented a quantitative restraint prohibited by the market access commitment GATS, however, permits derogation where "necessary to protect public morals or to maintain public order." This clause serves as a crucial regulatory safety valve, ensuring that liberalizing commitments do not unintentionally jeopardize important local public policies The Appellate Body accepted the American contention that the restraints on online gambling were necessary to protect concerns related to "(1) organized crime; (2) money laundering; (3) fraud; (4) risks to youth, including underage gambling; and (5) public health. Appellate Body agreed that the "distinctive characteristics of the remote supply of gambling services may call for distinctive regulatory methods." But the U S stumbled on an inconsistency: U.S. law "authorizes domestic service suppliers, but not foreign service suppliers, to offer remote betting services in relation to certain horse races." With the U S stubborn in its resistance to resolving this inconsistency, the WTO granted Antigua the right to retaliate by suspending Antigua's TRIPS obligation to respect U.S. intellectual property rights in an amount corresponding to the estimated lost revenues from online horse-racing
A B held a blanket prohibition operated as a "zero quota," GATS, however, permits derogation where "necessary to protect public morals This clause serves as a crucial regulatory safety valve The A B accepted the contention that restraints on online gambling were necessary distinctive characteristics of gambling call for distinctive regulatory methods But the U S stumbled on inconsistency law "authorizes domestic suppliers not foreign
Antigua responded to U.S. enforcement efforts like any country that found its exports hampered by legal restrictions elsewhere: it filed a claim against the United States before the WTO. Antigua's claim, however, was novel: it was the first brought under GATS, n34 and the first to challenge barriers to trade via the Internet. Antigua argued that the requirement of physical establishment in certain specified zones in the United States ran afoul of the national treatment obligation by disadvantaging foreign providers. n35 Antigua further argued that the United States violated its commitment to provide market access to trade in "other recreational services." n36 The United States protested that it never agreed to open up trade in gambling services, specifically excluding "sporting" from its liberalization commitment. n37 Canvassing a number of sources, the Appellate Body concluded that the United States had indeed committed to open up gambling services. n38 Controversy over whether a country committed to liberalize a particular service might seem awkward; after all, should not the parties to the trade agreement know what economic activities each side has agreed to liberalize? But because it is often possible to characterize a particular service in multiple ways, some liberalized and some not, this most basic of disputes (is there a liberalization commitment?) will prove a consistent thorn in the side of net-work. More importantly, changes in tradability make possible cross-border [*289] competition in services that nation-states may not have anticipated when they committed to liberalization. The United States argued that, even if it had committed to liberalize gambling, it had met its obligations. After all, Antiguan corporations were welcome - like any American national - to provide gambling to Americans, as long as they set up shop in Las Vegas or another permissive American jurisdiction. n39 The United States also insisted that, because of their differing consumer experiences and regulatory risks, offline gambling and online gambling were two distinct services, and thus opening up one and not the other did not effectively deny national treatment. Moreover, the market access requirement, the United States argued, did not bar a total prohibition on a particular service. Seized of the dispute, the WTO's Appellate Body confined its analysis to the market access complaint, finding it unnecessary to resolve the national treatment complaint. The United States argued that its rules against online gambling were merely rules regulating the form or manner in which services are delivered, not quantitative constraints on services or suppliers. n40 Under this reasoning, the United States would meet its market access commitment for a service even if it barred the provision of that service online entirely. The Appellate Body, however, held that a blanket prohibition operated as a "zero quota," and thus presented a quantitative restraint prohibited by the market access commitment. n41 GATS, however, permits derogation where "necessary to protect public morals or to maintain public order." n42 This clause serves as a crucial regulatory safety valve, ensuring that liberalizing commitments do not unintentionally jeopardize important local public policies. The Appellate Body accepted the American contention that the restraints on online gambling were necessary to protect concerns related to "(1) organized crime; (2) money laundering; (3) fraud; (4) risks to youth, including underage gambling; and (5) public health." n43 Gambling via the Internet posed special concerns: "(i) the volume, speed and international reach of remote gambling transactions; (ii) the virtual anonymity of such transactions; (iii) low barriers to entry in the context of the remote supply of gambling and betting services; and the (iv) isolated and anonymous environment in which such gambling takes place." n44 [*290] The Appellate Body agreed that the "distinctive characteristics of the remote supply of gambling services may call for distinctive regulatory methods." n45 But the United States stumbled on an inconsistency: U.S. law "authorizes domestic service suppliers, but not foreign service suppliers, to offer remote betting services in relation to certain horse races." n46 With the United States stubborn in its resistance to resolving this inconsistency, the WTO granted Antigua the right to retaliate by suspending Antigua's TRIPS obligation to respect U.S. intellectual property rights in an amount corresponding to the estimated lost revenues from online horse-racing. n47 Antigua can now truly become a Pirate of the Caribbean.
4,663
<h4><strong>The only issue was <u>discrimination</u>---that law applied differently between U.S. and foreign operators---which the CP solves.</h4><p>Chander 9</strong> – Anupam Chander, Visiting Professor, The University of Chicago Law School; Professor, University of California, Davis. Yale Law School, J.D. Harvard College, “Trade 2.0”, The Yale Journal of International Law, Summer, 34 Yale J. Int'l L. 281, Lexis</p><p><u><strong>Antigua responded</u></strong> to U.S. enforcement efforts like any country that found its exports hampered by legal restrictions elsewhere: it <u><strong>filed a claim against the U</u></strong>nited <u><strong>S</u></strong>tates <u><strong>before the WTO</u></strong>. Antigua's claim, however, was novel: it was the first brought under GATS, n34 and the first to challenge barriers to trade via the Internet. Antigua argued that the requirement of physical establishment in certain specified zones in the United States ran afoul of the national treatment obligation by disadvantaging foreign providers. n35 Antigua further argued that the United States violated its commitment to provide market access to trade in "other recreational services." n36 The United States protested that it never agreed to open up trade in gambling services, specifically excluding "sporting" from its liberalization commitment. n37 Canvassing a number of sources, the Appellate Body concluded that the United States had indeed committed to open up gambling services. n38 Controversy over whether a country committed to liberalize a particular service might seem awkward; after all, should not the parties to the trade agreement know what economic activities each side has agreed to liberalize? But because it is often possible to characterize a particular service in multiple ways, some liberalized and some not, this most basic of disputes (is there a liberalization commitment?) will prove a consistent thorn in the side of net-work. More importantly, changes in tradability make possible cross-border [*289] competition in services that nation-states may not have anticipated when they committed to liberalization. The United States argued that, even if it had committed to liberalize gambling, it had met its obligations. After all, Antiguan corporations were welcome - like any American national - to provide gambling to Americans, as long as they set up shop in Las Vegas or another permissive American jurisdiction. n39 The United States also insisted that, because of their differing consumer experiences and regulatory risks, offline gambling and online gambling were two distinct services, and thus opening up one and not the other did not effectively deny national treatment. Moreover, <u><strong>the market access requirement, the U</u></strong>nited <u><strong>S</u></strong>tates <u><strong>argued, did not bar a total prohibition on a particular service</u></strong>. Seized of the dispute, the WTO's Appellate Body confined its analysis to the market access complaint, finding it unnecessary to resolve the national treatment complaint. The United States argued that its rules against online gambling were merely rules regulating the form or manner in which services are delivered, not quantitative constraints on services or suppliers. n40 Under this reasoning, the United States would meet its market access commitment for a service even if it barred the provision of that service online entirely. <u><strong>The <mark>A</mark>ppellate <mark>B</mark>ody,</u></strong> however, <u><strong><mark>held</mark> that <mark>a blanket prohibition operated as a "zero quota,"</mark> and thus presented a quantitative restraint prohibited by the market access commitment</u></strong>. n41 <u><strong><mark>GATS, however, permits derogation where "necessary to protect public morals</mark> or to maintain public order."</u></strong> n42 <u><strong><mark>This clause serves as a crucial regulatory safety valve</mark>, ensuring that liberalizing commitments do not unintentionally jeopardize important local public policies</u></strong>. <u><strong><mark>The A</mark>ppellate <mark>B</mark>ody <mark>accepted the</mark> American <mark>contention that</mark> the <mark>restraints on online gambling were necessary</mark> to protect concerns related to "(1) organized crime; (2) money laundering; (3) fraud; (4) risks to youth, including underage gambling; and (5) public health.</u></strong>" n43 Gambling via the Internet posed special concerns: "(i) the volume, speed and international reach of remote gambling transactions; (ii) the virtual anonymity of such transactions; (iii) low barriers to entry in the context of the remote supply of gambling and betting services; and the (iv) isolated and anonymous environment in which such gambling takes place." n44 [*290] The <u><strong>Appellate Body agreed that the "<mark>distinctive characteristics</mark> of the remote supply <mark>of gambling</mark> services may <mark>call for distinctive regulatory methods</mark>."</u></strong> n45 <u><strong><mark>But the U</u></strong></mark>nited <u><strong><mark>S</u></strong></mark>tates <u><strong><mark>stumbled on</mark> an <mark>inconsistency</mark>: U.S. <mark>law "authorizes domestic</mark> service <mark>suppliers</mark>, but <mark>not foreign</mark> service suppliers, to offer remote betting services in relation to certain horse races."</u></strong> n46 <u><strong>With the U</u></strong>nited <u><strong>S</u></strong>tates <u><strong>stubborn in its resistance to resolving this inconsistency, the WTO granted Antigua the right to retaliate by suspending Antigua's TRIPS obligation to respect U.S. intellectual property rights in an amount corresponding to the estimated lost revenues from online horse-racing</u></strong>. n47 Antigua can now truly become a Pirate of the Caribbean.</p>
2NC
null
Solves - Laundering
430,531
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,006
Try or die evidence is in the context of super-volcano eruptions—you should disregard extremely low risk future indeterminate impacts out of hand—AND—GM would only be able to resolve one effect of a super-volcano eruption
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Try or die evidence is in the context of <u>super-volcano eruptions</u>—you should disregard extremely low risk future indeterminate impacts out of hand—AND—GM would only be able to resolve <u>one effect</u> of a super-volcano eruption</h4>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,530
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,007
The scope of the aff is laughably small – several waves of federal financial services regulations in other sectors swamp the aff - banks are resiliently adapting now anyway
DCFS 2013
DCFS (Deloitte Center for Financial Services) 2013 “2014 Banking Industry Outlook Repositioning for growth Agility in a re-regulated world” http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CC0QFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.deloitte.com%2Fassets%2FDcom-UnitedStates%2FLocal%2520Assets%2FDocuments%2FFSI%2Fus_fsi_DCFS2014BankingIndustryOutlook_111113.pdf&ei=NKcpVOjlN_a1sQSt3IGoAw&usg=AFQjCNHiNozpwkRrLTPwW0hlFPM_9hOsPw&sig2=FkSz2LPEeBfOk4_T59DV0w
Regulations and compliance continue to dominate the attention of bank executives. In 2013 , the industry faced a new wave of rules covering capital, liquidity, consumer protection, anti-money laundering and risk management other regulations in the euro area further complicated the global regulatory landscape. Extensive enforcement of regulations in 2013 also created additional stress The CFPB) has added to this pressure with various new rules on mortgages, credit cards, and student loans. Furthermore, the industry has been adjusting to the new era of macroprudential oversight, evident in regulators’ broad focus on systemic risk. Most compliance efforts have focused on remediation and redesign of the banks’ operations banks have increased investment in their compliance infrastructure . In light of regulatory pressure, banks have focused on building more robust and comprehensive data systems to better drive risk, business, and compliance decisions. In 2014, the industry is likely to get more acclimated to the regulatory climate “2014 will be the year of getting it done, and getting it right.” , banks are likely to pay greater attention to data and analytics. These investments could empower banks to have an enterprise-wide view of customers and to proactively identify and address any problems. They will also help in having more informed conversations with regulators, and enable them to appreciate the specific nuances of different business decisions. Firms that institutionalize compliance could create competitive advantages, Boards are likely to become more engaged in risk governance in order to reshape bank risk culture Boards could be more emboldened to challenge management,
Regulations dominate the attention of bank s In 2013 the industry faced a new wave of rules covering capital liquidity AML), and risk management regulations created additional stress The CFPB) added pressure with rules on mortgages, credit cards, and student loans banks have increased investment in their compliance infrastructure the industry get more acclimated to the regulatory climate 2014 will be the year of getting it done
Regulations and compliance continue to dominate the attention of bank executives. In 2013, three years after the Dodd-Frank Act was enacted, the industry faced a new wave of rules covering capital, liquidity, consumer protection, anti-money laundering (AML), and risk management. Basel III rules and various other regulations in the U.K. and the euro area further complicated the global regulatory landscape. Extensive enforcement of regulations in 2013 also created additional stress, particularly for large institutions, which were the main targets of attention until recently. The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) has added to this pressure with various new rules on mortgages, credit cards, and student loans. Furthermore, the industry has been adjusting to the new era of macroprudential oversight, evident in regulators’ broad focus on systemic risk. “Most compliance efforts have focused on remediation and redesign of the banks’ operations,” said J.H. Caldwell, partner, Deloitte & Touche LLP. Many banks have increased investment in their compliance infrastructure and made efforts to build improved risk cultures within their institutions. In light of regulatory pressure, banks have focused on building more robust and comprehensive data systems to better drive risk, business, and compliance decisions. Despite many improvements – and more than $100 billion in restitution, fines, and litigation costs paid to date – much work remains to be done to excel in risk management and governance.15 Continuation of these efforts may be essential as the regulatory pressure is not expected to dissipate in the near future. What's new for 2014 In 2014, the industry is likely to get more acclimated to the regulatory climate by moving past remediation issues to focus on instituting strong compliance programs across the organization. In “getting to strong” in their risk management programs, banks should continue bolstering their risk practices and governance.16 According to Deborah Bailey, director, Deloitte & Touche LLP, “2014 will be the year of getting it done, and getting it right.” In seeking to improve their risk infrastructure, banks are likely to pay greater attention to data and analytics. These investments could empower banks to have an enterprise-wide view of customers and to proactively identify and address any problems. They will also help in having more informed conversations with regulators, and enable them to appreciate the specific nuances of different business decisions. In 2014, regulatory pressure is expected to flow downstream to smaller institutions, encouraging them to retool their compliance infrastructure. Proposed stress tests for midsized banks may expose deficiencies, forcing some to restructure their risk profiles. Smaller institutions may need to invest in new talent and training to ensure that adequate compliance resources are available. As a result, regulatory compliance could become more ingrained in the broader industry culture. Firms that are able to institutionalize compliance in an effective and efficient manner could create competitive advantages, allowing them to best pursue their growth agenda. But as Tom Rollauer, executive director, Deloitte Center for Regulatory Strategies, Deloitte & Touche LLP, said, “It is also essential that banks continue to work more collaboratively with regulators in strengthening their compliance programs.” Boards are likely to become more engaged in risk governance in order to reshape bank risk culture and to review business strategies with a sharper focus on risk controls. Boards could be more emboldened to challenge management, particularly regarding risk appetites, and document their recommendations for regulators. It is also expected that they will interact more with staff below the executive level, to ensure the tone at the top is well reflected in the firm’s culture.
3,895
<h4><strong>The scope of the aff is laughably small – several waves of federal financial services regulations in other sectors swamp the aff - banks are resiliently adapting now anyway</h4><p>DCFS</strong> (Deloitte Center for Financial Services) <strong>2013</strong> “2014 Banking Industry Outlook Repositioning for growth Agility in a re-regulated world” http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CC0QFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.deloitte.com%2Fassets%2FDcom-UnitedStates%2FLocal%2520Assets%2FDocuments%2FFSI%2Fus_fsi_DCFS2014BankingIndustryOutlook_111113.pdf&ei=NKcpVOjlN_a1sQSt3IGoAw&usg=AFQjCNHiNozpwkRrLTPwW0hlFPM_9hOsPw&sig2=FkSz2LPEeBfOk4_T59DV0w</p><p><u><strong><mark>Regulations</mark> and compliance continue to <mark>dominate the attention of bank</mark> executive<mark>s</mark>. <mark>In 2013</u></strong></mark>, three years after the Dodd-Frank Act was enacted<u><strong>, <mark>the industry faced a new wave of rules</mark> <mark>covering capital</mark>, <mark>liquidity</mark>, consumer protection, anti-money laundering</u></strong> (<mark>AML), <u><strong>and risk management</u></strong></mark>. Basel III rules and various <u><strong>other regulations in the</u></strong> U.K. and the <u><strong>euro area further complicated the global regulatory landscape. Extensive enforcement of <mark>regulations</mark> in 2013 also <mark>created additional stress</u></strong></mark>, particularly for large institutions, which were the main targets of attention until recently. <u><strong><mark>The</u></strong></mark> Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (<u><strong><mark>CFPB)</mark> has <mark>added</mark> to this <mark>pressure with</mark> various new <mark>rules on mortgages, credit cards, and student loans</mark>. Furthermore, the industry has been adjusting to the new era of macroprudential oversight, evident in regulators’ broad focus on systemic risk. </u></strong>“<u><strong>Most compliance efforts have focused on remediation and redesign of the banks’ operations</u></strong>,” said J.H. Caldwell, partner, Deloitte & Touche LLP. Many <u><strong><mark>banks have increased investment in their compliance infrastructure</mark> </u></strong>and made efforts to build improved risk cultures within their institutions<u><strong>. In light of regulatory pressure, banks have focused on building more robust and comprehensive data systems to better drive risk, business, and compliance decisions. </u></strong>Despite many improvements – and more than $100 billion in restitution, fines, and litigation costs paid to date – much work remains to be done to excel in risk management and governance.15 Continuation of these efforts may be essential as the regulatory pressure is not expected to dissipate in the near future. What's new for 2014 <u><strong>In 2014, <mark>the industry</mark> is likely to <mark>get more acclimated to the regulatory climate</u></strong></mark> by moving past remediation issues to focus on instituting strong compliance programs across the organization. In “getting to strong” in their risk management programs, banks should continue bolstering their risk practices and governance.16 According to Deborah Bailey, director, Deloitte & Touche LLP, <u><strong>“<mark>2014 will be the year of getting it done</mark>, and getting it right.”</u></strong> In seeking to improve their risk infrastructure<u><strong>, banks are likely to pay greater attention to data and analytics. These investments could empower banks to have an enterprise-wide view of customers and to proactively identify and address any problems. They will also help in having more informed conversations with regulators, and enable them to appreciate the specific nuances of different business decisions. </u></strong>In 2014, regulatory pressure is expected to flow downstream to smaller institutions, encouraging them to retool their compliance infrastructure. Proposed stress tests for midsized banks may expose deficiencies, forcing some to restructure their risk profiles. Smaller institutions may need to invest in new talent and training to ensure that adequate compliance resources are available. As a result, regulatory compliance could become more ingrained in the broader industry culture. <u><strong>Firms that</u></strong> are able to <u><strong>institutionalize compliance</u></strong> in an effective and efficient manner <u><strong>could create competitive advantages,</u></strong> allowing them to best pursue their growth agenda. But as Tom Rollauer, executive director, Deloitte Center for Regulatory Strategies, Deloitte & Touche LLP, said, “It is also essential that banks continue to work more collaboratively with regulators in strengthening their compliance programs.” <u><strong>Boards are likely to become more engaged in risk governance in order to reshape bank risk culture</u></strong> and to review business strategies with a sharper focus on risk controls. <u><strong>Boards could be more emboldened to challenge management,</u></strong> particularly regarding risk appetites, and document their recommendations for regulators. It is also expected that they will interact more with staff below the executive level, to ensure the tone at the top is well reflected in the firm’s culture.</p>
2NC
adv 1
Solves - Laundering
430,532
3
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,008
Technological adaptation is coming now and solves
Moore ’08
Moore ’08 Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University, Stanford, (Thomas Gale 7/9/12 “Global warming; the good, the bad and the ugly and the efficient” EMBO reports http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3317379/?tool=pmcentrez)KG
Even if the pessimists are correct human beings will be better able to handle such terrible conditions than they are now because technology will advance and people will become richer over the next century. Evidence of an increasing rate of technological advancement comes from patents; the number of patents issued for inventions has continued to rise at an increasing rate since 1790 Although patented inventions are only a crude measure of technological growth, they do indicate that technology will continue to change the world in which we live. Thus progress will allow our descendants to deal with almost any difficulties that climate change brings.
Even if the pessimists are correct human beings will be better able to handle terrible conditions because technology will advance and people will become richer patented inventions indicate technology will continue to change the world in which we live progress will allow our descendants to deal with almost any difficulties that climate change brings
Even if the pessimists are correct and future climate change reduces food production, wicked storms lash much of the planet, summers are plagued by terrible heat waves, and floods and droughts inundate large areas of the world and reduce the availability of clean water, human beings will be better able to handle such terrible conditions than they are now because technology will advance and people will become richer over the next century. Evidence of an increasing rate of technological advancement comes from patents; the number of patents issued for inventions has continued to rise at an increasing rate since 1790 (Fig 2). Although patented inventions are only a crude measure of technological growth, they do indicate that technology will continue to change the world in which we live. Consider the world 200 years ago when the fastest means of communication was by horseback, or just 100 years ago when telephones were only slowly spreading and radio, much less TV or the internet, were almost undreamed of. Thus progress will allow our descendants to deal with almost any difficulties that climate change brings.
1,122
<h4>Technological adaptation is coming now and solves</h4><p><strong>Moore ’08</strong> Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University, Stanford, (Thomas Gale 7/9/12 “Global warming; the good, the bad and the ugly and the efficient” EMBO<u> reports http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3317379/?tool=pmcentrez)KG</p><p><mark>Even if the pessimists are correct</mark> </u>and future climate change reduces food production, wicked storms lash much of the planet, summers are plagued by terrible heat waves, and floods and droughts inundate large areas of the world and reduce the availability of clean water, <u><mark>human beings will be better able to handle</mark> such <mark>terrible conditions</mark> than they are now <mark>because technology will advance and people will become richer</mark> over the next century. Evidence of an increasing rate of technological advancement comes from patents; the number of patents issued for inventions has continued to rise at an increasing rate since 1790</u> (Fig 2). <u>Although <mark>patented inventions</mark> are only a crude measure of technological growth, they do <mark>indicate</mark> that <mark>technology will continue to change the world in which we live</mark>.</u> Consider the world 200 years ago when the fastest means of communication was by horseback, or just 100 years ago when telephones were only slowly spreading and radio, much less TV or the internet, were almost undreamed of. <u>Thus <mark>progress will allow our descendants to deal with almost any difficulties that climate change brings</mark>.</p></u>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
284,202
2
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,009
No climate modeling – states lack infrastructural capacity
Levi 11
Levi 11 [Michael A. Levi David M. Rubenstein Senior Fellow for Energy and the Environment Why Don’t States Cooperate More on Energy and Climate? Posted on Tuesday, January 18, 2011 http://blogs.cfr.org/levi/2011/01/18/why-dont-states-cooperate-more-on-energy-and-climate/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed%3A+mlevi+%28Michael+Levi%27s+Blog%29&utm_content=Google+Reader]
states’ capacity to cooperate when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity cooperation will fail. India won’t be able to force power plants to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation under control without stronger capacity to enforce laws China won’t improve its IPR protection until its innovation system becomes much more capable of developing tech Our view of international politics tends to focus much more on pure ambition than on these sorts of features that directly influence results.
India won’t be able to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation under control without stronger capacity to enforce laws China won’t improve IPR protection until its more capable of developing tech Our view of international politics tends to focus more on ambition than these features that directly influence results.
I spent Friday and Saturday at an excellent (largely academic) workshop on international institutions and global governance. In our discussions about why states do and don’t cooperate, I was struck by how absent states’ capacity to cooperate was from the discussion. In particular, when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how both practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. Here’s a simple example of what I’m referring to: People argue that international oil markets would function more smoothly if states would publish basic data on their domestic markets (supply, demand, stocks, etc). They observe that China (among others) doesn’t do that. The immediate conclusion is that Beijing doesn’t want to. The only policy recourse, then, is to pressure or persuade China to change tack. But in more than one recent conversation, people have emphasized to me that Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics itself (though it’s working on developing its capacity). Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity to collect the right statistics, cooperation will fail. The same thing is true much more broadly. India, for example, won’t be able to force power plants to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation properly under control without stronger capacity to enforce the laws that it puts on the books. One might even argue that China won’t improve its IPR protection until its innovation system becomes much more capable of developing technologies itself. Our view of international politics, though, tends to focus much more on pure ambition than on these sorts of features that directly influence results.
1,750
<h4>No climate modeling – states lack infrastructural capacity</h4><p><u><strong>Levi 11</strong><mark> [Michael A. Levi David M. Rubenstein Senior Fellow for Energy and the Environment Why Don’t States Cooperate More on Energy and Climate? Posted on Tuesday, January 18, 2011 http://blogs.cfr.org/levi/2011/01/18/why-dont-states-cooperate-more-on-energy-and-climate/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed%3A+mlevi+%28Michael+Levi%27s+Blog%29&utm_content=Google+Reader]</p><p></u></mark>I spent Friday and Saturday at an excellent (largely academic) workshop on international institutions and global governance. In our discussions about why states do and don’t cooperate, I was struck by how absent <u>states’ capacity to cooperate</u> was from the discussion. In particular, <u>when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how</u> both <u>practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. </u> Here’s a simple example of what I’m referring to: People argue that international oil markets would function more smoothly if states would publish basic data on their domestic markets (supply, demand, stocks, etc). They observe that China (among others) doesn’t do that. The immediate conclusion is that Beijing doesn’t want to. The only policy recourse, then, is to pressure or persuade China to change tack. But in more than one recent conversation, people have emphasized to me that <u>Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics</u> itself (though it’s working on developing its capacity). <u>Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity</u> to collect the right statistics, <u>cooperation will fail.</u> The same thing is true much more broadly. <u><mark>India</u></mark>, for example, <u><mark>won’t be able to </mark>force power plants to<mark> internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation</u></mark> properly <u><mark>under control without stronger capacity to enforce</u></mark> the <u><mark>laws</u></mark> that it puts on the books. One might even argue that <u><mark>China won’t improve</mark> its <mark>IPR protection until its</mark> innovation system becomes much <mark>more capable of developing tech</u></mark>nologies itself. <u><mark>Our view of international politics</u></mark>, though, <u><mark>tends to focus </mark>much<mark> more on </mark>pure<mark> ambition than </mark>on<mark> these </mark>sorts of<mark> features that directly influence results.</p></u></mark>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,283
4
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,010
Global institutions like the WTO, IMF, and World Bank will retain legitimacy even if US influence decline
Maher, 2011
Maher, 2011, Orbis, Winter, [Ph.D. political science candidate at Brown, Richard], p. 65-6
We know that institutions acquire a certain ‘‘stickiness’’ that allow them to exist long after the features or forces at the time of their creation give way to a new landscape of global politics. . Institutions such as the (IMF), World Bank, and (WTO have near-universal membership and overwhelming legitimacy Even China, Russia, and Iran have strongly desired membership in these institutions. these institutions will disproportionately benefit the United States long after the demise of its unparalleled position in world politics. the United States will be able to ‘‘lock in’’ a durable international order that will continue to reflect its own basic interests and values.
institutions acquire a ‘‘stickiness’’ that allow them to exist long after the features or forces at the time of their creation give way to a new landscape of global politics Institutions such as the (IMF), World Bank, and WTO have near-universal membership and overwhelming legitimacy. Even China, Russia, and Iran strongly desired membership in these institutions
We know that institutions acquire a certain ‘‘stickiness’’ that allow them to exist long after the features or forces at the time of their creation give way to a new landscape of global politics. The transaction costs of creating a whole new international—or even regional— institutional architecture that would compete with the American post-World War II vintage would be enormous. Institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), World Bank, and World Trade Organization (WTO), all reflect basic American preferences for an open trading system and, with a few exceptions, have near-universal membership and overwhelming legitimacy. Even states with which the United States has significant political, economic, or diplomatic disagreement—China, Russia, and Iran—have strongly desired membership in these ‘‘Made in USA’’ institutions. Shifts in the global balance of power will be reflected in these institutions—such as the decision at the September 2009 Pittsburgh G-20 summit to increase China’s voting weight in the IMF by five percentage points, largely at the expense of European countries such as Britain and France. Yet these institutions, if their evolution is managed with deftness and skill, will disproportionately benefit the United States long after the demise of its unparalleled position in world politics. In this sense, the United States will be able to ‘‘lock in’’ a durable international order that will continue to reflect its own basic interests and values.
1,490
<h4>Global institutions like the WTO, IMF, and World Bank will retain legitimacy even if US influence decline</h4><p><strong>Maher, 2011</strong>, Orbis, Winter, [Ph.D. political science candidate at Brown, Richard], p. 65-6</p><p><u><strong>We know that <mark>institutions acquire a</mark> certain <mark>‘‘stickiness’’ that allow them to exist long after the features or forces at the time of their creation give way to a new landscape of global politics</mark>.</u></strong> The transaction costs of creating a whole new international—or even regional— institutional architecture that would compete with the American post-World War II vintage would be enormous<u><strong>. <mark>Institutions such as the</u></strong></mark> International Monetary Fund <u><strong><mark>(IMF), World Bank, and</u></strong></mark> World Trade Organization <u><strong>(<mark>WTO</u></strong></mark>), all reflect basic American preferences for an open trading system and, with a few exceptions, <u><strong><mark>have near-universal membership and overwhelming legitimacy</u></strong>. <u><strong>Even</u></strong></mark> states with which the United States has significant political, economic, or diplomatic disagreement—<u><strong><mark>China, Russia, and Iran</u></strong></mark>—<u><strong>have <mark>strongly desired membership</u></strong> <u><strong>in these</u></strong></mark> ‘‘Made in USA’’ <u><strong><mark>institutions</mark>.</u></strong> Shifts in the global balance of power will be reflected in these institutions—such as the decision at the September 2009 Pittsburgh G-20 summit to increase China’s voting weight in the IMF by five percentage points, largely at the expense of European countries such as Britain and France. Yet <u><strong>these institutions</u></strong>, if their evolution is managed with deftness and skill, <u><strong>will disproportionately benefit the United States long after the demise of its unparalleled position in world politics.</u></strong> In this sense, <u><strong>the United States will be able to ‘‘lock in’’ a durable international order that will continue to reflect its own basic interests and values.</p></u></strong>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
185,034
5
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,011
No global pandemic.
Ridley 8/17
Ridley 8/17 [Matt Ridley (rationaloptimist.com) is a columnist for The Wall Street Journal and the author, most recently, of The Rational Optimist: How Prosperity Evolves. Apocalypse Not: Here’s Why You Shouldn’t Worry About End Times By Matt RidleyEmail Author August 17, 2012 http://www.wired.com/wiredscience/2012/08/ff_apocalypsenot/all]
Repeatedly the past five decades, the imminent advent of a new pandemic has been foretold. a new global pandemic is growing less likely, not more. Water- and insect-borne infections—generally the most lethal—are declining as living standards improve. Even if a lethal virus does go global, the ability of medical science to sequence its genome and devise a vaccine or cure is getting better all the time.
Repeatedly the past five decades, the imminent advent of a new pandemic has been foretold. a new global pandemic is growing less likely, not more. Water- and insect-borne infections—generally the most lethal—are declining as living standards improve. Even if a lethal virus does go global, the ability of medical science to sequence its genome and devise a vaccine or cure is getting better all the time.
Repeatedly throughout the past five decades, the imminent advent of a new pandemic has been foretold. The 1976 swine flu panic was an early case. Following the death of a single recruit at Fort Dix, the Ford administration vaccinated more than 40 million Americans, but more people probably died from adverse reactions to the vaccine than died of swine flu. A few years later, a fatal virus did begin to spread at an alarming rate, initially through the homosexual community. AIDS was soon, rightly, the focus of serious alarm. But not all the dire predictions proved correct. “Research studies now project that one in five—listen to me, hard to believe—one in five heterosexuals could be dead from AIDS at the end of the next three years. That’s by 1990. One in five,” Oprah Winfrey warned in 1987. Bad as AIDS was, the broad-based epidemic in the Americas, Europe, and Asia never materialized as feared, though it did in Africa. In 2000 the US National Intelligence Council predicted that HIV/AIDS would worsen in the developing world for at least 10 years and was “likely to aggravate and, in some cases, may even provoke economic decay, social fragmentation and political destabilization in the hardest hit countries in the developing and former communist worlds.” Yet the peak of the epidemic had already passed in the late 1990s, and today AIDS is in slow retreat throughout the world. New infections were 20 percent lower in 2010 than in 1997, and the lives of more than 2.5 million people have been saved since 1995 by antiretroviral treatment. “Just a few years ago, talking about ending the AIDS epidemic in the near term seemed impossible, but science, political support, and community responses are starting to deliver clear and tangible results,” UNAIDS executive director Michel Sidibé wrote last year. The emergence of AIDS led to a theory that other viruses would spring from tropical rain forests to wreak revenge on humankind for its ecological sins. That, at least, was the implication of Laurie Garrett’s 1994 book, The Coming Plague: Newly Emerging Diseases in a World Out of Balance. The most prominent candidate was Ebola, the hemorrhagic fever that starred in Richard Preston’s The Hot Zone, published the same year. Writer Stephen King called the book “one of the most horrifying things I’ve ever read.” Right on cue, Ebola appeared again in the Congo in 1995, but it soon disappeared. Far from being a harbinger, HIV was the only new tropical virus to go pandemic in 50 years. In the 1980s British cattle began dying from mad cow disease, caused by an infectious agent in feed that was derived from the remains of other cows. When people, too, began to catch this disease, predictions of the scale of the epidemic quickly turned terrifying: Up to 136,000 would die, according to one study. A pathologist warned that the British “have to prepare for perhaps thousands, tens of thousands, hundreds of thousands, of cases of vCJD [new variant Creutzfeldt-Jakob disease, the human manifestation of mad cow] coming down the line.” Yet the total number of deaths so far in the UK has been 176, with just five occurring in 2011 and none so far in 2012. In 2003 it was SARS, a virus from civet cats, that ineffectively but inconveniently led to quarantines in Beijing and Toronto amid predictions of global Armageddon. SARS subsided within a year, after killing just 774 people. In 2005 it was bird flu, described at the time by a United Nations official as being “like a combination of global warming and HIV/AIDS 10 times faster than it’s running at the moment.” The World Health Organization’s official forecast was 2 million to 7.4 million dead. In fact, by late 2007, when the disease petered out, the death toll was roughly 200. In 2009 it was Mexican swine flu. WHO director general Margaret Chan said: “It really is all of humanity that is under threat during a pandemic.” The outbreak proved to be a normal flu episode. The truth is, a new global pandemic is growing less likely, not more. Mass migration to cities means the opportunity for viruses to jump from wildlife to the human species has not risen and has possibly even declined, despite media hype to the contrary. Water- and insect-borne infections—generally the most lethal—are declining as living standards slowly improve. It’s true that casual-contact infections such as colds are thriving—but only by being mild enough that their victims can soldier on with work and social engagements, thereby allowing the virus to spread. Even if a lethal virus does go global, the ability of medical science to sequence its genome and devise a vaccine or cure is getting better all the time.
4,676
<h4>No global pandemic.</h4><p><u><strong>Ridley 8/17</u></strong> [Matt Ridley (rationaloptimist.com) is a columnist for The Wall Street Journal and the author, most recently, of The Rational Optimist: How Prosperity Evolves. Apocalypse Not: Here’s Why You Shouldn’t Worry About End Times By Matt RidleyEmail Author August 17, 2012 http://www.wired.com/wiredscience/2012/08/ff_apocalypsenot/all<u><mark>]</p><p>Repeatedly</u></mark> throughout <u><mark>the past five decades, the imminent advent of a new pandemic has been foretold. </u></mark>The 1976 swine flu panic was an early case. Following the death of a single recruit at Fort Dix, the Ford administration vaccinated more than 40 million Americans, but more people probably died from adverse reactions to the vaccine than died of swine flu. A few years later, a fatal virus did begin to spread at an alarming rate, initially through the homosexual community. AIDS was soon, rightly, the focus of serious alarm. But not all the dire predictions proved correct. “Research studies now project that one in five—listen to me, hard to believe—one in five heterosexuals could be dead from AIDS at the end of the next three years. That’s by 1990. One in five,” Oprah Winfrey warned in 1987. Bad as AIDS was, the broad-based epidemic in the Americas, Europe, and Asia never materialized as feared, though it did in Africa. In 2000 the US National Intelligence Council predicted that HIV/AIDS would worsen in the developing world for at least 10 years and was “likely to aggravate and, in some cases, may even provoke economic decay, social fragmentation and political destabilization in the hardest hit countries in the developing and former communist worlds.” Yet the peak of the epidemic had already passed in the late 1990s, and today AIDS is in slow retreat throughout the world. New infections were 20 percent lower in 2010 than in 1997, and the lives of more than 2.5 million people have been saved since 1995 by antiretroviral treatment. “Just a few years ago, talking about ending the AIDS epidemic in the near term seemed impossible, but science, political support, and community responses are starting to deliver clear and tangible results,” UNAIDS executive director Michel Sidibé wrote last year. The emergence of AIDS led to a theory that other viruses would spring from tropical rain forests to wreak revenge on humankind for its ecological sins. That, at least, was the implication of Laurie Garrett’s 1994 book, The Coming Plague: Newly Emerging Diseases in a World Out of Balance. The most prominent candidate was Ebola, the hemorrhagic fever that starred in Richard Preston’s The Hot Zone, published the same year. Writer Stephen King called the book “one of the most horrifying things I’ve ever read.” Right on cue, Ebola appeared again in the Congo in 1995, but it soon disappeared. Far from being a harbinger, HIV was the only new tropical virus to go pandemic in 50 years. In the 1980s British cattle began dying from mad cow disease, caused by an infectious agent in feed that was derived from the remains of other cows. When people, too, began to catch this disease, predictions of the scale of the epidemic quickly turned terrifying: Up to 136,000 would die, according to one study. A pathologist warned that the British “have to prepare for perhaps thousands, tens of thousands, hundreds of thousands, of cases of vCJD [new variant Creutzfeldt-Jakob disease, the human manifestation of mad cow] coming down the line.” Yet the total number of deaths so far in the UK has been 176, with just five occurring in 2011 and none so far in 2012. In 2003 it was SARS, a virus from civet cats, that ineffectively but inconveniently led to quarantines in Beijing and Toronto amid predictions of global Armageddon. SARS subsided within a year, after killing just 774 people. In 2005 it was bird flu, described at the time by a United Nations official as being “like a combination of global warming and HIV/AIDS 10 times faster than it’s running at the moment.” The World Health Organization’s official forecast was 2 million to 7.4 million dead. In fact, by late 2007, when the disease petered out, the death toll was roughly 200. In 2009 it was Mexican swine flu. WHO director general Margaret Chan said: “It really is all of humanity that is under threat during a pandemic.” The outbreak proved to be a normal flu episode. The truth is, <u><strong><mark>a new global pandemic is growing less likely, not more.</u></strong></mark> Mass migration to cities means the opportunity for viruses to jump from wildlife to the human species has not risen and has possibly even declined, despite media hype to the contrary. <u><mark>Water- and insect-borne infections—generally the most lethal—are declining as living standards</u></mark> slowly <u><mark>improve.</u></mark> It’s true that casual-contact infections such as colds are thriving—but only by being mild enough that their victims can soldier on with work and social engagements, thereby allowing the virus to spread. <u><mark>Even if a lethal virus does go global, the ability of medical science to sequence its genome and devise a vaccine or cure is getting better all the time.</p></u></mark>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
97,826
175
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,012
Decline causes peaceful retrenchment—prolonging hegemony makes a stable transition less likely
MacDonald, 11
MacDonald, 11 - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Williams College (Paul K, Spring 2011, "Graceful Decline?: The Surprising Success of Great Power Retrenchment", International Security, Vol. 35, No. 4, UTD McDermitt Library, KONTOPOULOS)
Our findings are directly relevant to an impending great power transition between China and the U S Many scholars foresee major conflict during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition Contrary to these predictions, our analysis suggests grounds for optimism. Based on the historical track record the U S should be able to retrench In the next few years, the U S is ripe to overhaul its military shift burdens to its allies, and decrease costly international commitments. It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes than the average great power and settle these disputes more amicably. Some might view this fearing the erosion of U.S. credibility Yet our analysis suggests retrenchment need not signal weakness Holding on to expensive commitments for the sake of reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble Some observers dispute argu that hegemonic transitions are more conflict prone there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this hegemonic powers should find it easier to manage acute relative decline Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability which threatens grave harm to any state that tries to cross them they are no longer the top target for balancing coalitions and they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation hegemonic powers should be able to identify and eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities or exciting domestic populations the empirical record supports these conclusions periods of hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone similar factors may cushion the impending Sino-American transition Both are large secure continental great powers, a fact that mitigates potential geopolitical competition the U S will experience a "moderate" decline Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal. The U S would still possess of a third of the share of great power GDP and would have little to gain from provoking a crisis over a peripheral issue China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy it is unclear how Beijing could consolidate or expand its advantageous position through confrontation
Our findings are relevant to power transition between China and the U S Many scholars foresee conflict analysis suggests grounds for optimism the U S is ripe to overhaul its military and decrease international commitments It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes and settle these more amicably retrenchment need not signal weakness. Holding on to commitments for reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble Some argu hegemonic transitions are conflict prone there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability, which threatens any state that tries them hegemonic powers eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities the empirical record supports these conclusions hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone The U S would have little to gain from provoking a crisis China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness
Our findings are directly relevant to what appears to be an impending great power transition between China and the United States. Estimates of economic performance vary, but most observers expect Chinese GDP to surpass U.S. GDP sometime in the next decade or two.91 This prospect has generated considerable concern. Many scholars foresee major conflict during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition. Echoing Gilpin and Copeland, John Mearsheimer sees the crux of the issue as irreconcilable goals: China wants to be America's superior and the United States wants no peer competitors. In his words, "[N]o amount [End Page 40] of goodwill can ameliorate the intense security competition that sets in when an aspiring hegemon appears in Eurasia."92 Contrary to these predictions, our analysis suggests some grounds for optimism. Based on the historical track record of great powers facing acute relative decline, the United States should be able to retrench in the coming decades. In the next few years, the United States is ripe to overhaul its military, shift burdens to its allies, and work to decrease costly international commitments. It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes than the average great power and to settle these disputes more amicably. Some might view this prospect with apprehension, fearing the steady erosion of U.S. credibility. Yet our analysis suggests that retrenchment need not signal weakness. Holding on to exposed and expensive commitments simply for the sake of one's reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble than withdrawing to cheaper, more defensible frontiers. Some observers might dispute our conclusions, arguing that hegemonic transitions are more conflict prone than other moments of acute relative decline. We counter that there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this argument. Theoretically, hegemonic powers should actually find it easier to manage acute relative decline. Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability, which threatens grave harm to any state that tries to cross them. Further, they are no longer the top target for balancing coalitions, and recovering hegemons may be influential because they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation. In addition, hegemonic powers, almost by definition, possess more extensive overseas commitments; they should be able to more readily identify and eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities or exciting domestic populations. We believe the empirical record supports these conclusions. In particular, periods of hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone than those of acute decline. The last reversal at the pinnacle of power was the Anglo-American transition, which took place around 1872 and was resolved without armed confrontation. The tenor of that transition may have been influenced by a number of factors: both states were democratic maritime empires, the United States was slowly emerging from the Civil War, and Great Britain could likely coast on a large lead in domestic capital stock. Although China and the United [End Page 41] States differ in regime type, similar factors may work to cushion the impending Sino-American transition. Both are large, relatively secure continental great powers, a fact that mitigates potential geopolitical competition.93 China faces a variety of domestic political challenges, including strains among rival regions, which may complicate its ability to sustain its economic performance or engage in foreign policy adventurism.94 Most important, the United States is not in free fall. Extrapolating the data into the future, we anticipate the United States will experience a "moderate" decline, losing from 2 to 4 percent of its share of great power GDP in the five years after being surpassed by China sometime in the next decade or two.95 Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline relative to China, the incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal. The United States would still possess upwards of a third of the share of great power GDP, and would have little to gain from provoking a crisis over a peripheral issue. Conversely, China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness.96 Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy, in addition to the critical role played by the dollar as a global reserve currency, it is unclear how Beijing could hope to consolidate or expand its increasingly advantageous position through direct confrontation.
4,515
<h4>Decline causes <u>peaceful retrenchment</u>—<u>prolonging</u> hegemony makes a <u>stable transition</u> less likely </h4><p><strong>MacDonald, 11</strong> - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Williams College (Paul K, Spring 2011, "Graceful Decline?: The Surprising Success of Great Power Retrenchment", International Security, Vol. 35, No. 4, UTD McDermitt Library, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p><u><mark>Our findings are</mark> directly <mark>relevant to</u></mark> what appears to be <u><strong>an impending great <mark>power transition</u></strong> <u>between China and the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates. Estimates of economic performance vary, but most observers expect Chinese GDP to surpass U.S. GDP sometime in the next decade or two.91 This prospect has generated considerable concern. <u><mark>Many scholars foresee</mark> major <mark>conflict</mark> during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition</u>. Echoing Gilpin and Copeland, John Mearsheimer sees the crux of the issue as irreconcilable goals: China wants to be America's superior and the United States wants no peer competitors. In his words, "[N]o amount [End Page 40] of goodwill can ameliorate the intense security competition that sets in when an aspiring hegemon appears in Eurasia."92 <u>Contrary to these predictions, our <mark>analysis suggests</u></mark> some <u><strong><mark>grounds for optimism</mark>.</u></strong> <u>Based on the historical track record</u> of great powers facing acute relative decline, <u>the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates <u>should be able to</u> <u>retrench</u> in the coming decades. <u><strong>In the next few years,</u></strong> <u><mark>the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u><mark>is ripe to overhaul its military</u></mark>, <u>shift burdens to its allies, <mark>and</u></mark> work to <u><mark>decrease</mark> costly <mark>international commitments</mark>.</u> <u><mark>It is</u> <u><strong>likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes</u></strong></mark> <u>than the average great power <mark>and</u></mark> to <u><strong><mark>settle these</mark> disputes <mark>more amicably</mark>.</u></strong> <u>Some might view this</u> prospect with apprehension, <u>fearing the</u> steady <u><strong>erosion of U.S. credibility</u></strong>. <u>Yet our analysis suggests</u> that <u><strong><mark>retrenchment need not signal weakness</u></strong>. <u><strong>Holding on to</u></strong></mark> exposed and <u>expensive <strong><mark>commitments</mark> </u></strong>simply <u><mark>for</mark> the sake of</u> one's <u><mark>reputation is a</u> <u><strong>greater geopolitical gamble</u></strong></mark> than withdrawing to cheaper, more defensible frontiers. <u><mark>Some</mark> observers</u> might <u>dispute</u> our conclusions, <u><mark>argu</u></mark>ing <u>that</u> <u><mark>hegemonic transitions are</mark> more <mark>conflict prone</u></mark> than other moments of acute relative decline. We counter that <u><mark>there are</u> <u><strong>deductive and empirical reasons</u></strong> <u>to doubt this</u></mark> argument. Theoretically, <u>hegemonic powers should</u> actually <u>find it easier to</u> <u>manage acute relative decline</u>. <u><mark>Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability</u>, <u>which</u> <u><strong>threatens</mark> grave harm</u></strong> <u>to <mark>any state that tries</mark> to cross <mark>them</u></mark>. Further, <u>they are</u> <u>no longer the top target for balancing coalitions</u>, <u>and</u> recovering hegemons may be influential because <u>they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation</u>. In addition, <u><mark>hegemonic powers</u></mark>, almost by definition, possess more extensive overseas commitments; they <u>should be able to</u> more readily <u>identify and <mark>eliminate extraneous burdens</u> <u><strong>without exposing vulnerabilities</u></strong></mark> <u>or exciting domestic populations</u>. We believe <u><mark>the empirical record supports these conclusions</u></mark>. In particular, <u>periods of <mark>hegemonic transition</u> <u><strong>do not appear more conflict prone</u></strong></mark> than those of acute decline. The last reversal at the pinnacle of power was the Anglo-American transition, which took place around 1872 and was resolved without armed confrontation. The tenor of that transition may have been influenced by a number of factors: both states were democratic maritime empires, the United States was slowly emerging from the Civil War, and Great Britain could likely coast on a large lead in domestic capital stock. Although China and the United [End Page 41] States differ in regime type, <u>similar factors may</u> work to <u>cushion the impending Sino-American transition</u>. <u>Both are large</u>, relatively <u>secure continental great powers, a fact that</u> <u>mitigates potential geopolitical competition</u>.93 China faces a variety of domestic political challenges, including strains among rival regions, which may complicate its ability to sustain its economic performance or engage in foreign policy adventurism.94 Most important, the United States is not in free fall. Extrapolating the data into the future, we anticipate <u>the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates <u>will</u> <u><strong>experience a "moderate" decline</u></strong>, losing from 2 to 4 percent of its share of great power GDP in the five years after being surpassed by China sometime in the next decade or two.95 <u>Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline</u> relative to China, the <u><strong>incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal.</u></strong> <u><mark>The U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u>would still possess</u> upwards <u>of a third of the share of great power GDP</u>, <u>and <mark>would have</u> <u><strong>little to gain from provoking a crisis</u></strong></mark> <u>over a peripheral issue</u>. Conversely, <u><mark>China has</u> <u><strong>few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness</u></strong></mark>.96 <u>Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy</u>, in addition to the critical role played by the dollar as a global reserve currency, <u>it is unclear how Beijing could</u> hope to <u>consolidate or expand its</u> increasingly <u>advantageous position through</u> direct <u>confrontation</u>.</p>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
97,153
117
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,013
No resource wars.
Tertrais 12
Tertrais 12 [Bruno, Senior Research Fellow at the Fondation pour la Recherche Strat gique (FRS) The Demise of Ares: The End of War as We Know It? The Washington Quarterly • 35:3 pp. 722]
resource wars are unlikely. two fallacies. One is scarcity, a notion challenged by many energy experts. As prices rise, previously untapped reserves and non-conventional hydrocarbons become economically attractive. The other is spilling blood is a rational way to access resources. the economic rationale for war has always been overstated. because of globalization, it has become cheaper to buy than to steal. In an era of liberalizing trade, many natural resources are fungible goods. It is the abundance of resources, not their scarcity, which fuels conflicts.
resource wars are unlikely. two fallacies. One is scarcity, a notion challenged by many energy experts. As prices rise, previously untapped reserves and non-conventional hydrocarbons become economically attractive. The other is spilling blood is a rational way to access resources. the economic rationale for war has always been overstated. because of globalization, it has become cheaper to buy than to steal. In an era of liberalizing trade, many natural resources are fungible goods. It is the abundance of resources, not their scarcity, which fuels conflicts.
Future resource wars are unlikely. There are fewer and fewer conquest wars. Between the Westphalia peace and the end of World War II, nearly half of conflicts were fought over territory. Since the end of the Cold War, it has been less than 30 percent. 61 The invasion of Kuwaita nationwide bank robberymay go down in history as being the last great resource war. The U.S.-led intervention of 1991 was partly driven by the need to maintain the free flow of oil, but not by the temptation to capture it. (Nor was the 2003 war against Iraq motivated by oil.) As for the current tensions between the two Sudans over oil, they are the remnants of a civil war and an offshoot of a botched secession process, not a desire to control new resources. China’s and India’s energy needs are sometimes seen with apprehension: in light of growing oil and gas scarcity, is there not a risk of military clashes over the control of such resources? This seemingly consensual idea rests on two fallacies. One is that there is such a thing as oil and gas scarcity, a notion challenged by many energy experts. 62 As prices rise, previously untapped reserves and non-conventional hydrocarbons become economically attractive. The other is that spilling blood is a rational way to access resources. As shown by the work of historians and political scientists such as Quincy Wright, the economic rationale for war has always been overstated. And because of globalization, it has become cheaper to buy than to steal. We no longer live in the world of 1941, when fear of lacking oil and raw materials was a key motivation for Japan’s decision to go to war. In an era of liberalizing trade, many natural resources are fungible goods. (Here, Beijing behaves as any other actor: 90 percent of the oil its companies produce outside of China goes to the global market, not to the domestic one.) 63 There may be clashes or conflicts in regions in maritime resource-rich areas such as the South China and East China seas or the Mediterranean, but they will be driven by nationalist passions, not the desperate hunger for hydrocarbons. Only in civil wars does the question of resources such as oil, diamonds, minerals, and the like play a significant role; this was especially true as Cold War superpowers stopped their financial patronage of local actors. 64 Indeed, as Mueller puts it in his appropriately titled The Remnants of War, ‘‘Many [existing wars] have been labeled ‘new war,’ ‘ethnic conflict,’ or, most grandly ‘clashes of civilization.’ But in fact, most. . .are more nearly opportunistic predation by packs, often remarkably small ones, of criminals, bandits, and thugs.’’ 65 It is the abundance of resources, not their scarcity, which fuels such conflicts. The risk is particularly high when the export of natural resources represents at least a third of the country’s GDP. 66
2,856
<h4>No resource wars.</h4><p><u><strong>Tertrais 12</u></strong> [Bruno, Senior Research Fellow at the Fondation pour la Recherche Strat gique (FRS) The Demise of Ares: The End of War as We Know It? The Washington Quarterly • 35:3 pp. 722]</p><p>Future <u><strong><mark>resource wars are unlikely.</u></strong></mark> There are fewer and fewer conquest wars. Between the Westphalia peace and the end of World War II, nearly half of conflicts were fought over territory. Since the end of the Cold War, it has been less than 30 percent. 61 The invasion of Kuwaita nationwide bank robberymay go down in history as being the last great resource war. The U.S.-led intervention of 1991 was partly driven by the need to maintain the free flow of oil, but not by the temptation to capture it. (Nor was the 2003 war against Iraq motivated by oil.) As for the current tensions between the two Sudans over oil, they are the remnants of a civil war and an offshoot of a botched secession process, not a desire to control new resources. China’s and India’s energy needs are sometimes seen with apprehension: in light of growing oil and gas scarcity, is there not a risk of military clashes over the control of such resources? This seemingly consensual idea rests on <u><mark>two fallacies. One is</u></mark> that there is such a thing as oil and gas <u><mark>scarcity, a notion challenged by many energy experts.</u></mark> 62 <u><mark>As prices rise, previously untapped reserves and non-conventional hydrocarbons become economically attractive. The other is</u></mark> that <u><mark>spilling blood is a rational way to access resources.</u></mark> As shown by the work of historians and political scientists such as Quincy Wright, <u><mark>the economic rationale for war <strong>has always been overstated.</u></strong></mark> And <u><mark>because of globalization, it has become cheaper to buy than to steal.</u></mark> We no longer live in the world of 1941, when fear of lacking oil and raw materials was a key motivation for Japan’s decision to go to war. <u><mark>In an era of liberalizing trade, many natural resources are fungible goods.</u></mark> (Here, Beijing behaves as any other actor: 90 percent of the oil its companies produce outside of China goes to the global market, not to the domestic one.) 63 There may be clashes or conflicts in regions in maritime resource-rich areas such as the South China and East China seas or the Mediterranean, but they will be driven by nationalist passions, not the desperate hunger for hydrocarbons. Only in civil wars does the question of resources such as oil, diamonds, minerals, and the like play a significant role; this was especially true as Cold War superpowers stopped their financial patronage of local actors. 64 Indeed, as Mueller puts it in his appropriately titled The Remnants of War, ‘‘Many [existing wars] have been labeled ‘new war,’ ‘ethnic conflict,’ or, most grandly ‘clashes of civilization.’ But in fact, most. . .are more nearly opportunistic predation by packs, often remarkably small ones, of criminals, bandits, and thugs.’’ 65 <u><mark>It is the abundance of resources, not their scarcity, which fuels</u></mark> such <u><mark>conflicts.</u></mark> The risk is particularly high when the export of natural resources represents at least a third of the country’s GDP. 66 </p>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
114,940
195
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,014
Heg causes economic collapse
Eland, 09 , KONTOPOULOS)
Eland, 09 – Senior Fellow and Director of the Center on Peace and Liberty at the Independent Institute (Ivan, 5/11/09, “How the U.S. Empire Contributed to the Economic Crisis”, http://www.independent.org/newsroom/article.asp?id=2498, KONTOPOULOS)
only a few prescient commentators have questioned whether the U.S. can sustain its informal global empire in the wake of the most severe economic crisis since World War II the U.S. Empire helped cause the meltdown in the first place. War has a history of causing financial and economic calamities. It does so directly by almost always causing inflation too much money chasing too few goods. During wartime, governments usually commandeer resources from the private sector into the government realm to fund the fighting. This action leaves shortages of resources to make consumer goods and their components, therefore pushing prices up governments often times print money to fund the war, thus adding to the amount of money chasing the smaller number of consumer goods. Such “make-believe” wealth has funded many U.S. wars We have seen that war ultimately causes the creation of both economic problems and nefarious government financial institutions that cause those difficulties. And of course, the modern day U.S. Empire also creates such economic maladies and wars that allow those institutions to wreak havoc on the economy. The Fed caused the current collapse in the real estate credit market, which has led to a more general global financial and economic meltdown, by earlier flooding the market with excess credit. That money went into real estate, thus creating an artificial bubble that eventually came crashing down in 2008. But what caused the Fed to vastly expand credit? To prevent a potential economic calamity after 9/11 and soothe jitters surrounding the risky and unneeded U.S. invasion of Iraq Greenspan began a series of interest rate cuts that vastly increased the money supply the interest rate cuts culminated in the extraordinary policy of lowering the federal funds rate Much of this excess money ended up creating the real estate bubble that eventually caused the meltdown. So the causal arrow goes from these imperial behaviors—and blowback there from—to increases in the money supply to prevent related economic slowdown, which in turn caused even worse eventual financial and economic calamities. These may be indirect effects of empire, but they cannot be ignored. Get rid of the overseas empire because we can no longer afford it, especially when it is partly responsible for the economic distress that is making us poorer.
the U.S. Empire helped cause the meltdown War has a history of causing economic calamities. It does so by causing inflation During wartime, governments usually commandeer resources from the private sector to fund the fighting. This leaves shortages of resources to make consumer goods and their components, pushing prices up governments print money to fund the war, adding to the amount of money chasing the smaller number of consumer goods. war causes the creation of economic problems The Fed caused the current collapse in the real estate credit market, which has led to a more general global financial and economic meltdown, by flooding the market with excess credit. the causal arrow goes from these imperial behaviors—and blowback to increases in the money supply to prevent related economic slowdown, which caused even worse eventual financial calamities
A few—and only a few—prescient commentators have questioned whether the U.S. can sustain its informal global empire in the wake of the most severe economic crisis since World War II. And the simultaneous quagmires in Iraq and Afghanistan are leading more and more opinion leaders and taxpayers to this question. But the U.S. Empire helped cause the meltdown in the first place. War has a history of causing financial and economic calamities. It does so directly by almost always causing inflation—that is, too much money chasing too few goods. During wartime, governments usually commandeer resources from the private sector into the government realm to fund the fighting. This action leaves shortages of resources to make consumer goods and their components, therefore pushing prices up. Making things worse, governments often times print money to fund the war, thus adding to the amount of money chasing the smaller number of consumer goods. Such “make-believe” wealth has funded many U.S. wars. For example, the War of 1812 had two negative effects on the U.S. financial system. First, in 1814, the federal government allowed state-chartered banks to suspend payment in gold and silver to their depositors. In other words, according Tom J. DiLorenzo in Hamilton’s Curse, the banks did not have to hold sufficient gold and silver reserves to cover their loans. This policy allowed the banks to loan the federal government more money to fight the war. The result was an annual inflation rate of 55 percent in some U.S. cities. The government took this route of expanding credit during wartime because no U.S. central bank existed at the time. Congress, correctly questioning The Bank of the United States’ constitutionality, had not renewed its charter upon expiration in 1811. But the financial turmoil caused by the war led to a second pernicious effect on the financial system—the resurrection of the bank in 1817 in the form of the Second Bank of the United States. Like the first bank and all other government central banks in the future, the second bank flooded the market with new credit. In 1818, this led to excessive real estate speculation and a consequent bubble. The bubble burst during the Panic of 1819, which was the first recession in the nation’s history. Sound familiar? Although President Andrew Jackson got rid of the second bank in the 1830s and the U.S. economy generally flourished with a freer banking system until 1913, at that time yet another central bank—this time the Federal Reserve System—rose from the ashes. We have seen that war ultimately causes the creation of both economic problems and nefarious government financial institutions that cause those difficulties. And of course, the modern day U.S. Empire also creates such economic maladies and wars that allow those institutions to wreak havoc on the economy. The Fed caused the current collapse in the real estate credit market, which has led to a more general global financial and economic meltdown, by earlier flooding the market with excess credit. That money went into real estate, thus creating an artificial bubble that eventually came crashing down in 2008. But what caused the Fed to vastly expand credit? To prevent a potential economic calamity after 9/11 and soothe jitters surrounding the risky and unneeded U.S. invasion of Iraq, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan began a series of interest rate cuts that vastly increased the money supply. According to Thomas E. Woods, Jr. in Meltdown, the interest rate cuts culminated in the extraordinary policy of lowering the federal funds rate (the rate at which banks lend to one another overnight, which usually determines other interest rates) to only one percent for an entire year (from June 2003 to June 2004). Woods notes that more money was created between 2000 and 2007 than in the rest of U.S. history. Much of this excess money ended up creating the real estate bubble that eventually caused the meltdown. Ben Bernanke, then a Fed governor, was an ardent advocate of this easy money policy, which as Fed Chairman he has continued as his solution to an economic crisis he helped create using the same measures. Of course, according to Osama bin Laden, the primary reasons for the 9/11 attacks were U.S. occupation of Muslim lands and U.S. propping up of corrupt dictators there. And the invasion of Iraq was totally unnecessary because there was never any connection between al Qaeda or the 9/11 attacks and Saddam Hussein, and even if Saddam had had biological, chemical, or even nuclear weapons, the massive U.S. nuclear arsenal would have likely deterred him from using them on the United States. So the causal arrow goes from these imperial behaviors—and blowback there from—to increases in the money supply to prevent related economic slowdown, which in turn caused even worse eventual financial and economic calamities. These may be indirect effects of empire, but they cannot be ignored. Get rid of the overseas empire because we can no longer afford it, especially when it is partly responsible for the economic distress that is making us poorer.
5,102
<h4>Heg causes economic collapse</h4><p><strong>Eland, 09</strong> – Senior Fellow and Director of the Center on Peace and Liberty at the Independent Institute (Ivan, 5/11/09, “How the U.S. Empire Contributed to the Economic Crisis”, http://www.independent.org/newsroom/article.asp?id=2498<u><strong>, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p></u></strong>A few—and <u><strong>only a few</u></strong>—<u><strong>prescient commentators have questioned whether the U.S. can sustain its informal global empire in the wake of the most severe economic crisis since World War II</u></strong>. And the simultaneous quagmires in Iraq and Afghanistan are leading more and more opinion leaders and taxpayers to this question. But <u><strong><mark>the U.S. Empire helped cause the meltdown</mark> in the first place. <mark>War has a history of causing</mark> financial and <mark>economic calamities. It does so </mark>directly <mark>by</mark> almost always <mark>causing inflation</u></strong></mark>—that is, <u><strong>too much money chasing too few goods. <mark>During wartime, governments usually commandeer resources from the private sector</mark> into the government realm <mark>to fund the fighting. This</mark> action <mark>leaves shortages of resources to make consumer goods and their components,</mark> therefore <mark>pushing prices up</u></strong></mark>. Making things worse, <u><strong><mark>governments</mark> often times <mark>print money to fund the war,</mark> thus<mark> adding to the amount of money chasing the smaller number of consumer goods.</mark> Such “make-believe” wealth has funded many U.S. wars</u></strong>. For example, the War of 1812 had two negative effects on the U.S. financial system. First, in 1814, the federal government allowed state-chartered banks to suspend payment in gold and silver to their depositors. In other words, according Tom J. DiLorenzo in Hamilton’s Curse, the banks did not have to hold sufficient gold and silver reserves to cover their loans. This policy allowed the banks to loan the federal government more money to fight the war. The result was an annual inflation rate of 55 percent in some U.S. cities. The government took this route of expanding credit during wartime because no U.S. central bank existed at the time. Congress, correctly questioning The Bank of the United States’ constitutionality, had not renewed its charter upon expiration in 1811. But the financial turmoil caused by the war led to a second pernicious effect on the financial system—the resurrection of the bank in 1817 in the form of the Second Bank of the United States. Like the first bank and all other government central banks in the future, the second bank flooded the market with new credit. In 1818, this led to excessive real estate speculation and a consequent bubble. The bubble burst during the Panic of 1819, which was the first recession in the nation’s history. Sound familiar? Although President Andrew Jackson got rid of the second bank in the 1830s and the U.S. economy generally flourished with a freer banking system until 1913, at that time yet another central bank—this time the Federal Reserve System—rose from the ashes. <u><strong>We have seen that <mark>war</mark> ultimately <mark>causes the creation of</mark> both <mark>economic problems</mark> and nefarious government financial institutions that cause those difficulties. And of course, the modern day U.S. Empire also creates such economic maladies and wars that allow those institutions to wreak havoc on the economy. <mark>The Fed caused the current collapse in the real estate credit market, which has led to a more general global financial and economic meltdown, by</mark> earlier <mark>flooding the market with excess credit.</mark> That money went into real estate, thus creating an artificial bubble that eventually came crashing down in 2008. But what caused the Fed to vastly expand credit? To prevent a potential economic calamity after 9/11 and soothe jitters surrounding the risky and unneeded U.S. invasion of Iraq</u></strong>, Fed Chairman Alan <u><strong>Greenspan began a series of interest rate cuts that vastly increased the money supply</u></strong>. According to Thomas E. Woods, Jr. in Meltdown, <u><strong>the interest rate cuts culminated in the extraordinary policy of lowering the federal funds rate </u></strong>(the rate at which banks lend to one another overnight, which usually determines other interest rates) to only one percent for an entire year (from June 2003 to June 2004). Woods notes that more money was created between 2000 and 2007 than in the rest of U.S. history. <u><strong>Much of this excess money ended up creating the real estate bubble that eventually caused the meltdown. </u></strong>Ben Bernanke, then a Fed governor, was an ardent advocate of this easy money policy, which as Fed Chairman he has continued as his solution to an economic crisis he helped create using the same measures. Of course, according to Osama bin Laden, the primary reasons for the 9/11 attacks were U.S. occupation of Muslim lands and U.S. propping up of corrupt dictators there. And the invasion of Iraq was totally unnecessary because there was never any connection between al Qaeda or the 9/11 attacks and Saddam Hussein, and even if Saddam had had biological, chemical, or even nuclear weapons, the massive U.S. nuclear arsenal would have likely deterred him from using them on the United States. <u><strong>So <mark>the causal arrow goes from these imperial behaviors—and blowback</mark> there from—<mark>to increases in the money supply to prevent related economic slowdown, which</mark> in turn <mark>caused even worse eventual financial</mark> and economic <mark>calamities</mark>. These may be indirect effects of empire, but they cannot be ignored. Get rid of the overseas empire because we can no longer afford it, especially when it is partly responsible for the economic distress that is making us poorer.</p></u></strong>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
284,107
6
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,015
Can’t solve food shocks – political reforms are a prerequisite.
Tipson 12 ]
Tipson 12 [Frederick, special advisor to the Center for Science,Technology and Peacebuilding at the U.S. Institute of Peace, where hewas a 2011-12 Jennings Randolph Senior Fellow. He worked previously for the UN Development Programme, Microsoft, the MarkleFoundation, the Council on Foreign Relations, Hongkong Telecom,AT&T, the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, and the University ofVirginia School of Law. Global Food Insecurity and "Political Malnutrition," June 2012, Number 7, German Marshall Fund Connections, http://www.gmfus.org/wp-content/blogs.dir/1/files_mf/1339595984Tipson_GlobalFoodInsecurity_Jun12.pdf]
conditions that affect ag productivity depend on “public goods” that effective governments facilitate Political capacity becomes the “gating factor” in determining how ag reform can be undertaken. Even the best combinations of seeds, irrigation, fertilizer, and crop rotation will not succeed without the political underpinnings that enable their implementation. principal impediments to increased productivity are not technical or economic but political — problems of land tenure, water access, ethnic hostility, community organization, or corruption. Up against these broader challenges, even the best extension services can only go so far. Without addressing political factors, the prospects for substantial improvements can be severely limited.
conditions that affect ag productivity depend on “public goods” that effective governments facilitate Political capacity becomes the “gating factor” in determining how ag reform can be undertaken. Even the best combinations of seeds, irrigation, fertilizer, and crop rotation will not succeed without the political underpinnings that enable their implementation. principal impediments to increased productivity are not technical or economic but political — problems of land tenure, water access, ethnic hostility, community organization, or corruption. Up against these broader challenges, even the best extension services can only go so far. Without addressing political factors, the prospects for substantial improvements can be severely limited.
All farming, like all politics (so the saying goes), is local. The conditions that affect agricultural productivity begin with the water, climate, soil, diet, community and family structure, land tenure system, and other localized factors that account for the distinctive farming cultures of particular locales. But they also depend on those “public goods” that effective governments facilitate, including regional infrastructure, reliable land transfer systems, available credit options, and some minimum level of public order — not to mention, in the best cases, schools, clinics, and municipal services. Unfortunately, under the strain of population growth and economic competition, it is exactly these kinds of political support systems that are lacking in many of the communities that need them most. Political capacity therefore often becomes the “gating factor” in determining how ambitious an agricultural reform agenda can be undertaken. Even the best combinations of seeds, irrigation, fertilizer, and crop rotation will not succeed in enhancing yields and resilience without the political underpinnings (and “readiness” to change) 4 that enable their implementation. One promising approach for increasing local political capacity is to expand and supplement the resources and capabilities of “agricultural extension” agencies. The traditional channels for technical assistance to farmers have centered around extension agents, who are generally employees of local, provincial, or national governments, but who may also be experts employed by suppliers, international development agencies, or NGOs. The ideal agent has the knowledge and skills to assist local farmers in increasing their productivity and reducing their risk of crop or financial failure. Drawing on the latest science to improve crop varieties, create safer fertilizers and pesticides, reduce losses both before and after harvests, and apply more productive farming methods, extension services may be the best hope for achieving the scale of increases necessary to feed the planet. In many locations, however, the principal impediments to increased productivity and profitability are not technical or economic but political — problems of land tenure, water access, ethnic hostility, community organization, or corruption. Up against these broader challenges, even the best extension services can only go so far. Without progress in addressing the political factors, the prospects for substantial improvements in agricultural performance can be severely limited.
2,576
<h4>Can’t solve food shocks – political reforms are a prerequisite.</h4><p><u><strong>Tipson 12</u></strong> [Frederick, special advisor to the Center for Science,Technology and Peacebuilding at the U.S. Institute of Peace, where hewas a 2011-12 Jennings Randolph Senior Fellow. He worked previously for the UN Development Programme, Microsoft, the MarkleFoundation, the Council on Foreign Relations, Hongkong Telecom,AT&T, the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, and the University ofVirginia School of Law. Global Food Insecurity and "Political Malnutrition," June 2012, Number 7, German Marshall Fund Connections, http://www.gmfus.org/wp-content/blogs.dir/1/files_mf/1339595984Tipson_GlobalFoodInsecurity_Jun12.pdf<u><strong><mark>]</p><p></u></strong></mark>All farming, like all politics (so the saying goes), is local. The <u><mark>conditions that affect ag</u></mark>ricultural <u><mark>productivity</u></mark> begin with the water, climate, soil, diet, community and family structure, land tenure system, and other localized factors that account for the distinctive farming cultures of particular locales. But they also <u><mark>depend on</u></mark> those <u><mark>“public goods” that effective governments facilitate</u></mark>, including regional infrastructure, reliable land transfer systems, available credit options, and some minimum level of public order — not to mention, in the best cases, schools, clinics, and municipal services. Unfortunately, under the strain of population growth and economic competition, it is exactly these kinds of political support systems that are lacking in many of the communities that need them most. <u><mark>Political capacity</u></mark> therefore often <u><mark>becomes the “gating factor” in determining how</u></mark> ambitious an <u><mark>ag</u></mark>ricultural <u><mark>reform</u></mark> agenda <u><mark>can be undertaken. Even the best combinations of seeds, irrigation, fertilizer, and crop rotation will not succeed</u></mark> in enhancing yields and resilience <u><mark>without the political underpinnings</u></mark> (and “readiness” to change) 4 <u><mark>that enable their implementation.</u></mark> One promising approach for increasing local political capacity is to expand and supplement the resources and capabilities of “agricultural extension” agencies. The traditional channels for technical assistance to farmers have centered around extension agents, who are generally employees of local, provincial, or national governments, but who may also be experts employed by suppliers, international development agencies, or NGOs. The ideal agent has the knowledge and skills to assist local farmers in increasing their productivity and reducing their risk of crop or financial failure. Drawing on the latest science to improve crop varieties, create safer fertilizers and pesticides, reduce losses both before and after harvests, and apply more productive farming methods, extension services may be the best hope for achieving the scale of increases necessary to feed the planet. In many locations, however, the <u><mark>principal impediments to increased productivity</u></mark> and profitability <u><mark>are not technical or economic but <strong>political</strong> — problems of land tenure, water access, ethnic hostility, community organization, or corruption. Up against these broader challenges, even the best extension services can <strong>only go so far.</strong> Without</u></mark> progress in <u><mark>addressing</u></mark> the <u><mark>political factors, the prospects for substantial improvements</u></mark> in agricultural performance <u><mark>can be <strong>severely limited.</p></u></strong></mark>
1nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,533
2
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,016
Heg causes terrorism
Sapolsky, 09
Sapolsky, 09 – Professor of Public Policy at MIT (Harvey, Fall 2009, “Restraining Order: For Strategic Modesty”, http://www.worldaffairsjournal.org/articles/2009-Fall/full-Sapolsky-etal-Fall-2009.html, KONTOPOULOS)
restraint distinguishes terrorists who attack the U S from those who do not. We should work with states around the world to combat all terrorists The U.S. government should share information on suspected terrorists track their movements freeze their bank accounts, arrest them and encourage other nations’ counterterrorism efforts. Terrorists who target America and its citizens are another matter a restraint strategy would employ all of the above policy tools while pressuring countries to act against these organizations within their own borders. If a host country is unable or unwilling to hunt terrorists who attack America, the United States itself should act declaring war on terrorists who do not target Americans invites obscure violent groups around the world to make us their enemies. A lack of discrimination in choosing whom to attack also strengthens terrorists by granting them recognition and encourages alliances between otherwise separate terror groups. Our enemies are those who attack Americans and those who shelter them American participation in the political conflicts in the Islamic world makes the U S a target of the terrorists involved in those conflicts, and American involvement feeds the conspiracy theories that make supposed evildoers in Washington the excuse for all that goes wrong in the Middle East we should model democracy rather than insisting that others adopt it. the blowback from cooperation with law enforcement and intelligence agencies will be much less severe than that generated by the current American strategy
restraint distinguishes terrorists who attack the U S from those who do not. We should work with states around the world to combat all terrorists a restraint strategy would employ policy tools while pressuring countries to act against these organizations within their own borders. declaring war on terrorists who do not target Americans invites violent groups to make us their enemies. American participation in political conflicts makes the U S a target blowback will be much less severe than the current American strategy
The restraint strategy distinguishes terrorists who attack the United States from those who do not. We should work with states around the world to combat all terrorists—those who intentionally target noncombatants. The U.S. government should share information on suspected terrorists with other states, track their movements across borders, freeze their bank accounts, arrest them when they enter U.S. territory, and encourage other nations’ counterterrorism efforts. Terrorists who target America and its citizens are another matter. In pursuing them, a restraint strategy would employ all of the above policy tools while also pressuring countries to act against these organizations within their own borders. If a host country is unable or unwilling to hunt terrorists who attack America, the United States itself should act. That could include covert action directed at the terrorists, air strikes, small-scale raids, or in extreme circumstances an invasion. By contrast, declaring war on terrorists who do not target Americans invites obscure violent groups around the world to make us their enemies. A lack of discrimination in choosing whom to attack also strengthens terrorists by granting them recognition and encourages alliances between otherwise separate terror groups. Our enemy today, for instance, is not Islam, not Islamism, not Islamic fundamentalism, not Wahabism, not Salafists, and not even jihadists, per se. Our enemies are those who attack Americans and those who shelter them. Most jihadists are fighting their local governments. In the long term, their struggle will probably fail. But their defeat will have to come at the hands of their compatriots, not from the liberal forces led by the United States. American participation in the political conflicts in the Islamic world makes the United States a target of the terrorists involved in those conflicts, and American involvement feeds the conspiracy theories that make supposed evildoers in Washington the excuse for all that goes wrong in the Middle East. Non-intervention in Middle Eastern politics should not be regarded as appeasement, but as a key component of counterterrorism. In the rare circumstances in which the United States needs to invade or even occupy part of the Muslim world, as in Afghanistan, the U.S. military should diminish its footprint and limit its stay. The United States should not shrink from stating that we believe that liberal democracy is a good form of government, but we should model democracy rather than insisting that others adopt it. Though we should not be mute in the face of egregious human rights violations, Americans should stop telling people in the Muslim world how to run their countries. Overseas, foreign intelligence organizations and policemen collect the most useful counterterrorism intelligence and do most of the work apprehending and interrogating terrorists, because they have local contacts and language skills. The United States should continue to provide intelligence support, particularly technical support, to these foreign counterterrorist agencies. Such cooperation may occasionally cause the kind of blowback that a policy of restraint seeks to avoid, but in cases like Pakistan’s, where the terrorist threat is high enough, the benefit of intelligence cooperation outweighs this cost. In any case, the blowback from cooperation with law enforcement and intelligence agencies will be much less severe than that generated by the current American strategy with its emphasis on military force and occupation. The principal military role in counterterrorism should be the use of special operations forces to assist foreign governments in attacking anti-American terrorists. In some circumstances, U.S. special forces might direct air strikes or directly attack terrorist facilities when local forces are unable or unwilling to do so. But locals should take the lead.
3,904
<h4>Heg causes terrorism</h4><p><strong>Sapolsky, 09</strong> – Professor of Public Policy at MIT (Harvey, Fall 2009, “Restraining Order: For Strategic Modesty”, http://www.worldaffairsjournal.org/articles/2009-Fall/full-Sapolsky-etal-Fall-2009.html, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p>The <u><strong><mark>restraint</u></strong></mark> strategy <u><strong><mark>distinguishes terrorists who attack the U</u></strong></mark>nited <u><strong><mark>S</u></strong></mark>tates <u><strong><mark>from those who do not. We should work with states around the world to combat all terrorists</u></strong></mark>—those who intentionally target noncombatants. <u><strong>The U.S. government should share information on suspected terrorists</u></strong> with other states, <u><strong>track their movements</u></strong> across borders, <u><strong>freeze</u></strong> <u><strong>their bank accounts, arrest them</u></strong> when they enter U.S. territory, <u><strong>and encourage other nations’ counterterrorism efforts. Terrorists who target America and its citizens are another matter</u></strong>. In pursuing them, <u><strong><mark>a restraint strategy would employ</mark> all of the above <mark>policy tools while</u></strong></mark> also <u><strong><mark>pressuring countries to act against these organizations within their own borders.</mark> If a host country is unable or unwilling to hunt terrorists who attack America, the United States itself should act</u></strong>. That could include covert action directed at the terrorists, air strikes, small-scale raids, or in extreme circumstances an invasion. By contrast, <u><strong><mark>declaring war on terrorists who do not target Americans invites</mark> obscure <mark>violent groups</mark> around the world <mark>to make us their enemies.</mark> A lack of discrimination in choosing whom to attack also strengthens terrorists by granting them recognition and encourages alliances between otherwise separate terror groups.</u></strong> Our enemy today, for instance, is not Islam, not Islamism, not Islamic fundamentalism, not Wahabism, not Salafists, and not even jihadists, per se. <u><strong>Our enemies are those who attack Americans and those who shelter them</u></strong>. Most jihadists are fighting their local governments. In the long term, their struggle will probably fail. But their defeat will have to come at the hands of their compatriots, not from the liberal forces led by the United States. <u><strong><mark>American participation in</mark> the <mark>political conflicts</mark> in the Islamic world <mark>makes the U</u></strong></mark>nited <u><strong><mark>S</u></strong></mark>tates <u><strong><mark>a target</mark> of the terrorists involved in those conflicts, and American involvement feeds the conspiracy theories that make supposed evildoers in Washington the excuse for all that goes wrong in the Middle East</u></strong>. Non-intervention in Middle Eastern politics should not be regarded as appeasement, but as a key component of counterterrorism. In the rare circumstances in which the United States needs to invade or even occupy part of the Muslim world, as in Afghanistan, the U.S. military should diminish its footprint and limit its stay. The United States should not shrink from stating that we believe that liberal democracy is a good form of government, but <u><strong>we should model democracy rather than insisting that others adopt it.</u></strong> Though we should not be mute in the face of egregious human rights violations, Americans should stop telling people in the Muslim world how to run their countries. Overseas, foreign intelligence organizations and policemen collect the most useful counterterrorism intelligence and do most of the work apprehending and interrogating terrorists, because they have local contacts and language skills. The United States should continue to provide intelligence support, particularly technical support, to these foreign counterterrorist agencies. Such cooperation may occasionally cause the kind of blowback that a policy of restraint seeks to avoid, but in cases like Pakistan’s, where the terrorist threat is high enough, the benefit of intelligence cooperation outweighs this cost. In any case, <u><strong>the <mark>blowback</mark> from cooperation with law enforcement and intelligence agencies <mark>will be much less severe than</mark> that generated by <mark>the current American strategy</mark> </u></strong>with its emphasis on military force and occupation. The principal military role in counterterrorism should be the use of special operations forces to assist foreign governments in attacking anti-American terrorists. In some circumstances, U.S. special forces might direct air strikes or directly attack terrorist facilities when local forces are unable or unwilling to do so. But locals should take the lead.</p>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
98,360
6
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,017
It’s inevitable—defense cuts
Donnelly et. Al 12
Donnelly et. Al 12- *Resident Fellow and Co-Director of the Marilyn Ware Center for Security Studies at the American Enterprise Institute, **Resident Scholar and Co-Director of the Marily Ware Center for Security Studies and Director of the Program on American Citizenship at the American Enterprise Institute and Ph.D. from the University of Chicago, AND ***Resident Fellow at the Marilyn Ware Center for Security Studies at the American Enterprise Insitute (*Thomas, **Gary J., AND **Mackenzie, 5/7/12, "Defending Defense: Sequestration Must Be Stopped", http://www.aei.org/article/foreign-and-defense-policy/defense/defending-defense-sequestration-must-be-stopped/, KONTOPOULOS)
America is nearing a decisive moment. Unless Congress acts to change current law, automatic sequestration cuts will slash future spending on national defense Combined with the cuts already put forward America’s military will see its budget drop Panetta warned sequestration will be “devastating,” yielding “[t]he smallest ground forces since 1940,” “a fleet of fewer than 230 ships, the smallest since 1915,” and “[t]he smallest tactical fighter force in the history of the Air Force.” Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff told Congress that the sequester’s reductions create “very high risk” to national security. these cuts effects will be felt almost immediately — by units preparing to fight in Afghanistan and operate elsewhere in the world. "[S]equestration leaves three places to go to get the money: operations, maintenance and training. That’s the definition of a hollow force.” There will be the inevitable effects of sequestration on America’s defense industrial base The impact on industry would be devastating, with a significant disruption of programs and initiatives, facility closures and substantial additional personnel reductions that would severely impact advanced manufacturing operations, erode engineering expertise, and accelerate the loss of skills and knowledge, directly undermining a key provision of our new national security strategy
America is nearing a decisive moment sequestration will be “devastating,” yielding “[t]he smallest ground forces since 1940,” “a fleet of fewer than 230 ships, the smallest since 1915,” and “[t]he smallest tactical fighter force in the history of the Air Force.” reductions create “very high risk” to national security. these cuts effects will be felt almost immediately There will be the effects of sequestration on America’s defense industrial base The impact would be devastating, with significant disruption undermining a key provision of our new national security strategy
America is nearing a decisive moment. Unless Congress acts to change current law, automatic sequestration cuts will slash future spending on national defense across-the-board by over $500 billion beginning early next year. Combined with the $487 billion in cuts already put forward by the President in February, America’s military will see its budget drop on average by $100 billion annually over the next decade. As Secretary of Defense Leon Panetta warned lawmakers in a November 2011 letter, sequestration will be “devastating,” yielding “[t]he smallest ground forces since 1940,” “a fleet of fewer than 230 ships, the smallest level since 1915,” and “[t]he smallest tactical fighter force in the history of the Air Force.” General Martin Dempsey, Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff, bluntly told Congress that the sequester’s mandated reductions create “very high risk” to national security. Although these cuts will not be implemented until January 2013, their effects will be felt almost immediately — by units preparing to fight in Afghanistan and operate elsewhere in the world. As General Dempsey has pointed out, "[S]equestration leaves me three places to go to get the money: operations, maintenance and training. That’s the definition of a hollow force.” There will be the inevitable effects of sequestration on America’s defense industrial base as well. As outgoing Lockheed Martin CEO Bob Stevens recently remarked: “The impact on industry would be devastating, with a significant disruption of ongoing programs and initiatives, facility closures and substantial additional personnel reductions that would severely impact advanced manufacturing operations, erode engineering expertise, and accelerate the loss of skills and knowledge, directly undermining a key provision of our new national security strategy, which is to preserve the industrial base, not dismantle it."
1,888
<h4>It’s inevitable—defense cuts</h4><p><strong>Donnelly et. Al 12</strong>- *Resident Fellow and Co-Director of the Marilyn Ware Center for Security Studies at the American Enterprise Institute, **Resident Scholar and Co-Director of the Marily Ware Center for Security Studies and Director of the Program on American Citizenship at the American Enterprise Institute and Ph.D. from the University of Chicago, AND ***Resident Fellow at the Marilyn Ware Center for Security Studies at the American Enterprise Insitute (*Thomas, **Gary J., AND **Mackenzie, 5/7/12, "Defending Defense: Sequestration Must Be Stopped", http://www.aei.org/article/foreign-and-defense-policy/defense/defending-defense-sequestration-must-be-stopped/, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p><u><strong><mark>America is nearing a decisive moment</mark>. Unless Congress acts to change current law, automatic sequestration cuts will slash future spending on national defense</u></strong> across-the-board by over $500 billion beginning early next year. <u><strong>Combined with the</u></strong> $487 billion in <u><strong>cuts already put forward</u></strong> by the President in February, <u><strong>America’s military will see its budget drop</u></strong> on average by $100 billion annually over the next decade. As Secretary of Defense Leon <u><strong>Panetta warned</u></strong> lawmakers in a November 2011 letter, <u><strong><mark>sequestration will be “devastating,” yielding “[t]he smallest ground forces since 1940,” “a fleet of fewer than 230 ships, the smallest</u></strong></mark> level <u><strong><mark>since 1915,” and “[t]he smallest tactical fighter force in the history of the Air Force.”</u></strong></mark> General Martin Dempsey, <u><strong>Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff</u></strong>, bluntly <u><strong>told Congress that the sequester’s</u></strong> mandated <u><strong><mark>reductions create “very high risk” to national security.</mark> </u></strong>Although <u><strong><mark>these cuts</u></strong></mark> will not be implemented until January 2013, their <u><strong><mark>effects will be felt almost immediately</mark> — by units preparing to fight in Afghanistan and operate elsewhere in the world.</u></strong> As General Dempsey has pointed out, <u><strong>"[S]equestration leaves</u></strong> me <u><strong>three places to go to get the money: operations, maintenance and training. That’s the definition of a hollow force.”</u></strong> <u><strong><mark>There will be the</mark> inevitable <mark>effects of sequestration on America’s defense industrial base</u></strong></mark> as well. As outgoing Lockheed Martin CEO Bob Stevens recently remarked: “<u><strong><mark>The impact</mark> on industry <mark>would be devastating, with</mark> a <mark>significant disruption</mark> of</u></strong> ongoing <u><strong>programs and initiatives, facility closures and substantial additional personnel reductions that would severely impact advanced manufacturing operations, erode engineering expertise, and accelerate the loss of skills and knowledge, directly <mark>undermining a key provision of our new national security strategy</u></strong></mark>, which is to preserve the industrial base, not dismantle it."</p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,534
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,018
Hegemony destroys effective institutions global public goods.
Ikenberry et al 9 - , State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE
Ikenberry et al 9 - G. John Ikenberry is a professor of politics and international affairs at Princeton University, Michael Mastanduno is a professor of government and associate dean for social sciences at Dartmouth College, William C. Wohlforth is a professor of government at Dartmouth College, “Unipolarity, State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE
The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo leading states “will attempt to change the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, institutions, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions Jervis argues that unipolarity offers powerful structural incentives for the leading state to be revisionist. These include the absence of countervailing power, the tendency for both the interests and the fears of the leading state to increase as its relative capabilities increase, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are reinforced by particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—the sense after the attacks of September 11, 2001, that the world could and must be transformed and the enduring and widespread belief that international peace and cooperation will be sustained only when all other important states are democratic. We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole to pursue more parochial interests even at the expense of a stable international order. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, its efforts are likely to be perceived by less powerful states as hypocritical attempts to mask the actual pursuit of private goods.
leading states “will change institutions unipolarity offers powerful incentives to be revisionist. absence of countervailing power, tendency for interests and the fears of the state to increase as capabilities increase reinforced by the sense after September 11 the world must be transformed and the widespread belief peace will be only when all states are democratic We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods to pursue parochial interests at the expense of a stable international order the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others its efforts are perceived as hypocritical attempts to mask private goods
Unipolarity and Revisionism: Is the Unipole a Satisfied State? The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo.17 In War and Change in World Politics, Robert Gilpin argued that leading states “will attempt to change the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs.”18 In the quarter century since that book’s publication, international relations scholars have never seriously debated whether the “expected net gain” of systemic revisionism might be positive for the United States. It is hardly surprising that scholars set aside the question of revising the territorial status quo—it is hard to imagine plausible arguments for the utility of large-scale conquest in an age of nuclear weapons and economic globalization. But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, institutions, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions. Why has there been no scholarly debate on whether the United States might seek to revise that aspect of the system? In the 1980s, to be sure, the question did not seem relevant. Scholars believed that the United States was in relative decline, so the costs of changing the system were simply assumed to be high, and a U.S. preference for the status quo appeared obvious. The transition from bipolarity to unipolarity arguably represented a dramatic power shift in favor of the United States, altering Gilpin’s equation toward revisionism. Yet the question of whether, as a new unipole, the United States might adopt a more revisionist stance has not figured centrally in international relations research. The reason was a key assumption built into almost all research on hegemonic stability and power transition theory: that the leading state in any international system is bound to be satisfied. Hence, research on the origins of satisfaction and revisionism is soverwhelmingly about subordinate states, not the dominant state.19 [End Page 12] Robert Jervis’s article in this issue demonstrates that this assumption is no longer tenable. While the case can be made that a unipole—particularly one that achieved this status in an international system already strongly shaped by its power and preferences—might rationally opt for conservatism,20 international relations scholarship is rich with hypotheses proposing that the opposite is equally if not more likely. Jervis argues that unipolarity offers powerful structural incentives for the leading state to be revisionist. These include the absence of countervailing power, the tendency for both the interests and the fears of the leading state to increase as its relative capabilities increase, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are reinforced by particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—the sense after the attacks of September 11, 2001, that the world could and must be transformed and the enduring and widespread belief that international peace and cooperation will be sustained only when all other important states are democratic. The structural and contingent features of contemporary unipolarity point plausibly in the direction of a revisionist unipole, one simultaneously powerful, fearful, and opportunistic. Unipolarity and the Provision of Public Goods Public or collective goods may be consumed by multiple actors without those actors necessarily having to pay the full costs of producing them. The classic theoretical insight is that if enough actors follow their rational self-interest and choose to free ride on the efforts of others, public goods will be underproduced or not produced at all.21 Overcoming the free-rider problem therefore requires cooperation among self-interested actors.22 A good part of the ir literature, in particular that associated with hegemonic stability theory, hypothesizes that cooperation in international relations requires the leadership of a dominant state.23 [End Page 13] Given its preponderance of economic and military resources, the dominant state has the ability to bear a disproportionate share of the costs of providing international collective goods such as an open world economy or a stable security order. The dominant state has an interest in bearing those costs because it benefits disproportionately from promoting systemwide outcomes that reflect its values and interests. During the cold war the United States took on the responsibilities that Kindleberger argued were needed to promote international economic stability, such as serving as an open market of last resort and allowing the use of its currency for exchange and reserve purposes. International economic stability among the Western powers reinforced their security alliance against the Soviet Union. The United States also bore a disproportionate share of the direct costs of Western alliance security. The Soviet Union, on its side of the international divide, ultimately shouldered disproportionate alliance costs as well.24 Waltz took the argument a step further, arguing that in the bipolar system the United States and the Soviet Union may have been adversaries but, as the two dominant powers, shared a mutual interest in system stability, an interest that prompted them to cooperate in providing public goods such as nuclear nonproliferation.25 Hedley Bull makes a similar point in his classic study of the international system as a society of states.26 How might the shift from a bipolar to a unipolar system affect the inclination of the now singularly dominant state to provide international public goods? Two hypotheses arise, with contradictory behavioral expectations. First, we might expect a unipole to take on an even greater responsibility for the provision of international public goods. The capabilities of a unipole relative to other major states are greater than those of either dominant power in a bipolar structure. The unipole’s incentive should be stronger as well, since it now has the opportunity to influence international outcomes globally, not just in its [End Page 14] particular subsystem. We should expect the unipole to try to “lock in” a durable international order that reflects its interests and values.27 A second hypothesis, however, suggests the opposite. We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole to pursue more parochial interests even at the expense of a stable international order. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. Two of the contributions below address these issues. Michael Mastanduno’s analysis of the global political economy shows that the dominant state will be both system maker and privilege taker—it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. It enlists the cooperation of other states and seeks, with varying degrees of success, to force adjustment burdens upon them. Jervis suggests that because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, its efforts are likely to be perceived by less powerful states as hypocritical attempts to mask the actual pursuit of private goods.
7,664
<h4>Hegemony destroys effective institutions global public goods. </h4><p><u><strong><mark>Ikenberry et al 9</u> -</strong></mark> G. John Ikenberry is a professor of politics and international affairs at Princeton University, Michael Mastanduno is a professor of government and associate dean for social sciences at Dartmouth College, William C. Wohlforth is a professor of government at Dartmouth College, “Unipolarity<u><strong>, State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE</p><p></u></strong>Unipolarity and Revisionism: Is the Unipole a Satisfied State? <u><strong>The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo</u></strong>.17 In War and Change in World Politics, Robert Gilpin argued that <u><strong><mark>leading states “will</mark> attempt to <mark>change</mark> the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs</u></strong>.”18 In the quarter century since that book’s publication, international relations scholars have never seriously debated whether the “expected net gain” of systemic revisionism might be positive for the United States. It is hardly surprising that scholars set aside the question of revising the territorial status quo—it is hard to imagine plausible arguments for the utility of large-scale conquest in an age of nuclear weapons and economic globalization. <u><strong>But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, <mark>institutions</mark>, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions</u></strong>. Why has there been no scholarly debate on whether the United States might seek to revise that aspect of the system? In the 1980s, to be sure, the question did not seem relevant. Scholars believed that the United States was in relative decline, so the costs of changing the system were simply assumed to be high, and a U.S. preference for the status quo appeared obvious. The transition from bipolarity to unipolarity arguably represented a dramatic power shift in favor of the United States, altering Gilpin’s equation toward revisionism. Yet the question of whether, as a new unipole, the United States might adopt a more revisionist stance has not figured centrally in international relations research. The reason was a key assumption built into almost all research on hegemonic stability and power transition theory: that the leading state in any international system is bound to be satisfied. Hence, research on the origins of satisfaction and revisionism is soverwhelmingly about subordinate states, not the dominant state.19 [End Page 12] Robert Jervis’s article in this issue demonstrates that this assumption is no longer tenable. While the case can be made that a unipole—particularly one that achieved this status in an international system already strongly shaped by its power and preferences—might rationally opt for conservatism,20 international relations scholarship is rich with hypotheses proposing that the opposite is equally if not more likely.<u><strong> Jervis argues that <mark>unipolarity offers powerful </mark>structural <mark>incentives </mark>for the leading state<mark> to be revisionist. </mark>These include the <mark>absence of countervailing power, </mark>the <mark>tendency for </mark>both the <mark>interests and the fears of the </mark>leading <mark>state to increase as</mark> its relative <mark>capabilities increase</mark>, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are <mark>reinforced by </mark>particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—<mark>the sense after </mark>the attacks of <mark>September 11</mark>, 2001, that <mark>the world </mark>could and <mark>must be transformed and the </mark>enduring and <mark>widespread belief </mark>that international <mark>peace </mark>and cooperation <mark>will</mark> <mark>be </mark>sustained <mark>only when all </mark>other important <mark>states are democratic</mark>.</u></strong> The structural and contingent features of contemporary unipolarity point plausibly in the direction of a revisionist unipole, one simultaneously powerful, fearful, and opportunistic. Unipolarity and the Provision of Public Goods Public or collective goods may be consumed by multiple actors without those actors necessarily having to pay the full costs of producing them. The classic theoretical insight is that if enough actors follow their rational self-interest and choose to free ride on the efforts of others, public goods will be underproduced or not produced at all.21 Overcoming the free-rider problem therefore requires cooperation among self-interested actors.22 A good part of the ir literature, in particular that associated with hegemonic stability theory, hypothesizes that cooperation in international relations requires the leadership of a dominant state.23 [End Page 13] Given its preponderance of economic and military resources, the dominant state has the ability to bear a disproportionate share of the costs of providing international collective goods such as an open world economy or a stable security order. The dominant state has an interest in bearing those costs because it benefits disproportionately from promoting systemwide outcomes that reflect its values and interests. During the cold war the United States took on the responsibilities that Kindleberger argued were needed to promote international economic stability, such as serving as an open market of last resort and allowing the use of its currency for exchange and reserve purposes. International economic stability among the Western powers reinforced their security alliance against the Soviet Union. The United States also bore a disproportionate share of the direct costs of Western alliance security. The Soviet Union, on its side of the international divide, ultimately shouldered disproportionate alliance costs as well.24 Waltz took the argument a step further, arguing that in the bipolar system the United States and the Soviet Union may have been adversaries but, as the two dominant powers, shared a mutual interest in system stability, an interest that prompted them to cooperate in providing public goods such as nuclear nonproliferation.25 Hedley Bull makes a similar point in his classic study of the international system as a society of states.26 How might the shift from a bipolar to a unipolar system affect the inclination of the now singularly dominant state to provide international public goods? Two hypotheses arise, with contradictory behavioral expectations. First, we might expect a unipole to take on an even greater responsibility for the provision of international public goods. The capabilities of a unipole relative to other major states are greater than those of either dominant power in a bipolar structure. The unipole’s incentive should be stronger as well, since it now has the opportunity to influence international outcomes globally, not just in its [End Page 14] particular subsystem. We should expect the unipole to try to “lock in” a durable international order that reflects its interests and values.27 A second hypothesis, however, suggests the opposite. <u><strong><mark>We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods</mark> despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole <mark>to pursue </mark>more <mark>parochial interests </mark>even <mark>at the expense of a stable international order</mark>. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that <mark>the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others</mark>, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. </u></strong>Two of the contributions below address these issues. Michael Mastanduno’s analysis of the global political economy shows that the dominant state will be both system maker and privilege taker—<u><strong>it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. </u></strong>It enlists the cooperation of other states and seeks, with varying degrees of success, to force adjustment burdens upon them. Jervis suggests that <u><strong>because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, <mark>its efforts are </mark>likely to be <mark>perceived </mark>by less powerful states <mark>as hypocritical attempts to mask </mark>the actual pursuit of <mark>private goods</mark>.</p></u></strong>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
292,657
5
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,019
Decline causes peaceful retrenchment—prolonging hegemony makes a stable transition less likely
MacDonald, 11
MacDonald, 11 - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Williams College (Paul K, Spring 2011, "Graceful Decline?: The Surprising Success of Great Power Retrenchment", International Security, Vol. 35, No. 4, UTD McDermitt Library, KONTOPOULOS)
Our findings are directly relevant to an impending great power transition between China and the U S Many scholars foresee major conflict during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition Contrary to these predictions, our analysis suggests grounds for optimism. Based on the historical track record the U S should be able to retrench In the next few years, the U S is ripe to overhaul its military shift burdens to its allies, and decrease costly international commitments. It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes than the average great power and settle these disputes more amicably. Some might view this fearing the erosion of U.S. credibility Yet our analysis suggests retrenchment need not signal weakness Holding on to expensive commitments for the sake of reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble Some observers dispute argu that hegemonic transitions are more conflict prone there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this hegemonic powers should find it easier to manage acute relative decline Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability which threatens grave harm to any state that tries to cross them they are no longer the top target for balancing coalitions and they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation hegemonic powers should be able to identify and eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities or exciting domestic populations the empirical record supports these conclusions periods of hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone similar factors may cushion the impending Sino-American transition Both are large secure continental great powers, a fact that mitigates potential geopolitical competition the U S will experience a "moderate" decline Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal. The U S would still possess of a third of the share of great power GDP and would have little to gain from provoking a crisis over a peripheral issue China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy it is unclear how Beijing could consolidate or expand its advantageous position through confrontation
Our findings are relevant to power transition between China and the U S Many scholars foresee conflict analysis suggests grounds for optimism the U S is ripe to overhaul its military and decrease international commitments It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes and settle these more amicably retrenchment need not signal weakness. Holding on to commitments for reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble Some argu hegemonic transitions are conflict prone there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability, which threatens any state that tries them hegemonic powers eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities the empirical record supports these conclusions hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone The U S would have little to gain from provoking a crisis China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness
Our findings are directly relevant to what appears to be an impending great power transition between China and the United States. Estimates of economic performance vary, but most observers expect Chinese GDP to surpass U.S. GDP sometime in the next decade or two.91 This prospect has generated considerable concern. Many scholars foresee major conflict during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition. Echoing Gilpin and Copeland, John Mearsheimer sees the crux of the issue as irreconcilable goals: China wants to be America's superior and the United States wants no peer competitors. In his words, "[N]o amount [End Page 40] of goodwill can ameliorate the intense security competition that sets in when an aspiring hegemon appears in Eurasia."92 Contrary to these predictions, our analysis suggests some grounds for optimism. Based on the historical track record of great powers facing acute relative decline, the United States should be able to retrench in the coming decades. In the next few years, the United States is ripe to overhaul its military, shift burdens to its allies, and work to decrease costly international commitments. It is likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes than the average great power and to settle these disputes more amicably. Some might view this prospect with apprehension, fearing the steady erosion of U.S. credibility. Yet our analysis suggests that retrenchment need not signal weakness. Holding on to exposed and expensive commitments simply for the sake of one's reputation is a greater geopolitical gamble than withdrawing to cheaper, more defensible frontiers. Some observers might dispute our conclusions, arguing that hegemonic transitions are more conflict prone than other moments of acute relative decline. We counter that there are deductive and empirical reasons to doubt this argument. Theoretically, hegemonic powers should actually find it easier to manage acute relative decline. Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability, which threatens grave harm to any state that tries to cross them. Further, they are no longer the top target for balancing coalitions, and recovering hegemons may be influential because they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation. In addition, hegemonic powers, almost by definition, possess more extensive overseas commitments; they should be able to more readily identify and eliminate extraneous burdens without exposing vulnerabilities or exciting domestic populations. We believe the empirical record supports these conclusions. In particular, periods of hegemonic transition do not appear more conflict prone than those of acute decline. The last reversal at the pinnacle of power was the Anglo-American transition, which took place around 1872 and was resolved without armed confrontation. The tenor of that transition may have been influenced by a number of factors: both states were democratic maritime empires, the United States was slowly emerging from the Civil War, and Great Britain could likely coast on a large lead in domestic capital stock. Although China and the United [End Page 41] States differ in regime type, similar factors may work to cushion the impending Sino-American transition. Both are large, relatively secure continental great powers, a fact that mitigates potential geopolitical competition.93 China faces a variety of domestic political challenges, including strains among rival regions, which may complicate its ability to sustain its economic performance or engage in foreign policy adventurism.94 Most important, the United States is not in free fall. Extrapolating the data into the future, we anticipate the United States will experience a "moderate" decline, losing from 2 to 4 percent of its share of great power GDP in the five years after being surpassed by China sometime in the next decade or two.95 Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline relative to China, the incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal. The United States would still possess upwards of a third of the share of great power GDP, and would have little to gain from provoking a crisis over a peripheral issue. Conversely, China has few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness.96 Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy, in addition to the critical role played by the dollar as a global reserve currency, it is unclear how Beijing could hope to consolidate or expand its increasingly advantageous position through direct confrontation.
4,515
<h4>Decline causes <u>peaceful retrenchment</u>—<u>prolonging</u> hegemony makes a <u>stable transition</u> less likely </h4><p><strong>MacDonald, 11</strong> - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Williams College (Paul K, Spring 2011, "Graceful Decline?: The Surprising Success of Great Power Retrenchment", International Security, Vol. 35, No. 4, UTD McDermitt Library, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p><u><mark>Our findings are</mark> directly <mark>relevant to</u></mark> what appears to be <u><strong>an impending great <mark>power transition</u></strong> <u>between China and the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates. Estimates of economic performance vary, but most observers expect Chinese GDP to surpass U.S. GDP sometime in the next decade or two.91 This prospect has generated considerable concern. <u><mark>Many scholars foresee</mark> major <mark>conflict</mark> during a Sino-U.S. ordinal transition</u>. Echoing Gilpin and Copeland, John Mearsheimer sees the crux of the issue as irreconcilable goals: China wants to be America's superior and the United States wants no peer competitors. In his words, "[N]o amount [End Page 40] of goodwill can ameliorate the intense security competition that sets in when an aspiring hegemon appears in Eurasia."92 <u>Contrary to these predictions, our <mark>analysis suggests</u></mark> some <u><strong><mark>grounds for optimism</mark>.</u></strong> <u>Based on the historical track record</u> of great powers facing acute relative decline, <u>the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates <u>should be able to</u> <u>retrench</u> in the coming decades. <u><strong>In the next few years,</u></strong> <u><mark>the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u><mark>is ripe to overhaul its military</u></mark>, <u>shift burdens to its allies, <mark>and</u></mark> work to <u><mark>decrease</mark> costly <mark>international commitments</mark>.</u> <u><mark>It is</u> <u><strong>likely to initiate and become embroiled in fewer militarized disputes</u></strong></mark> <u>than the average great power <mark>and</u></mark> to <u><strong><mark>settle these</mark> disputes <mark>more amicably</mark>.</u></strong> <u>Some might view this</u> prospect with apprehension, <u>fearing the</u> steady <u><strong>erosion of U.S. credibility</u></strong>. <u>Yet our analysis suggests</u> that <u><strong><mark>retrenchment need not signal weakness</u></strong>. <u><strong>Holding on to</u></strong></mark> exposed and <u>expensive <strong><mark>commitments</mark> </u></strong>simply <u><mark>for</mark> the sake of</u> one's <u><mark>reputation is a</u> <u><strong>greater geopolitical gamble</u></strong></mark> than withdrawing to cheaper, more defensible frontiers. <u><mark>Some</mark> observers</u> might <u>dispute</u> our conclusions, <u><mark>argu</u></mark>ing <u>that</u> <u><mark>hegemonic transitions are</mark> more <mark>conflict prone</u></mark> than other moments of acute relative decline. We counter that <u><mark>there are</u> <u><strong>deductive and empirical reasons</u></strong> <u>to doubt this</u></mark> argument. Theoretically, <u>hegemonic powers should</u> actually <u>find it easier to</u> <u>manage acute relative decline</u>. <u><mark>Fallen hegemons still have formidable capability</u>, <u>which</u> <u><strong>threatens</mark> grave harm</u></strong> <u>to <mark>any state that tries</mark> to cross <mark>them</u></mark>. Further, <u>they are</u> <u>no longer the top target for balancing coalitions</u>, <u>and</u> recovering hegemons may be influential because <u>they can play a pivotal role in alliance formation</u>. In addition, <u><mark>hegemonic powers</u></mark>, almost by definition, possess more extensive overseas commitments; they <u>should be able to</u> more readily <u>identify and <mark>eliminate extraneous burdens</u> <u><strong>without exposing vulnerabilities</u></strong></mark> <u>or exciting domestic populations</u>. We believe <u><mark>the empirical record supports these conclusions</u></mark>. In particular, <u>periods of <mark>hegemonic transition</u> <u><strong>do not appear more conflict prone</u></strong></mark> than those of acute decline. The last reversal at the pinnacle of power was the Anglo-American transition, which took place around 1872 and was resolved without armed confrontation. The tenor of that transition may have been influenced by a number of factors: both states were democratic maritime empires, the United States was slowly emerging from the Civil War, and Great Britain could likely coast on a large lead in domestic capital stock. Although China and the United [End Page 41] States differ in regime type, <u>similar factors may</u> work to <u>cushion the impending Sino-American transition</u>. <u>Both are large</u>, relatively <u>secure continental great powers, a fact that</u> <u>mitigates potential geopolitical competition</u>.93 China faces a variety of domestic political challenges, including strains among rival regions, which may complicate its ability to sustain its economic performance or engage in foreign policy adventurism.94 Most important, the United States is not in free fall. Extrapolating the data into the future, we anticipate <u>the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates <u>will</u> <u><strong>experience a "moderate" decline</u></strong>, losing from 2 to 4 percent of its share of great power GDP in the five years after being surpassed by China sometime in the next decade or two.95 <u>Given the relatively gradual rate of U.S. decline</u> relative to China, the <u><strong>incentives for either side to run risks by courting conflict are minimal.</u></strong> <u><mark>The U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u>would still possess</u> upwards <u>of a third of the share of great power GDP</u>, <u>and <mark>would have</u> <u><strong>little to gain from provoking a crisis</u></strong></mark> <u>over a peripheral issue</u>. Conversely, <u><mark>China has</u> <u><strong>few incentives to exploit U.S. weakness</u></strong></mark>.96 <u>Given the importance of the U.S. market to the Chinese economy</u>, in addition to the critical role played by the dollar as a global reserve currency, <u>it is unclear how Beijing could</u> hope to <u>consolidate or expand its</u> increasingly <u>advantageous position through</u> direct <u>confrontation</u>.</p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
97,153
117
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,020
Extinction.
DC 4
DC 4 – Magazine for Development and Cooperation, funded by Germany’s Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development, Where Markets Fail, March, http://www.inwent.org/E+Z/content/archive-eng/03-2004/edit_art1.html
public goods at the global level. They include the control of dangerous diseases, fair rules to govern international trade, protection of the atmosphere and of biodiversity, peace and security, as well as a stable finance system. Only multilateral coordination can handle deficits that arise globally , the unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current multilateral system we are dealing with correctly defined issues of humankind’s welfare and survival. The converging global society must meet enormous challenges – and that implies that governments have to pursue strategies of cross-border cooperation The challenges of globalisation, however, will not be mastered with individual bilateral projects – no matter how successful they might turn out.
public goods at the global level include control of diseases, fair rules to govern trade protection of the atmosphere and biodiversity peace as well as a stable finance system unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current system we are dealing with issues of humankind’s survival governments have to pursue cross-border cooperation challenges will not be mastered with individual projects no matter how successful
There are also public goods at the global level. They include the control of dangerous diseases, fair rules to govern international trade, protection of the atmosphere and of biodiversity, peace and security, as well as a stable finance system. Only multilateral coordination can handle deficits that arise globally. In political and conceptual terms, an International Task Force on Global Public Goods is working on getting a clearer grip of humankind’s shared interests. The aim is to improve the capacity for action at intergovernmental and supranational levels. The German Development Ministry supports the Task Force (Heidemarie Wieczorek-Zeul, p. 100). The UNDP Director who has drawn international attention to the concept of public goods emphasises the useful impact it might have on multilateral politics (interview with Inge Kaul, p. 104). However, the unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current multilateral system (Dirk Messner, p. 111). Moreover, the debate does not, of course, take place in a power vacuum. The question is how to make the Global Public Goods agenda palatable for developing countries. Many of them have so far experienced multilateral politics subjected to orders from the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund and as wallflowers in the World Trade Organisation rather than as partners with equal rights (Mariama Williams, p. 113). Without doubt, a utopian element of hope marks the debate on Global Public Goods. However, its core of the – economically defined – public interest is brilliantly rational. After all, economics is originally the science of the intelligent use of resources. Unfortunately, economics jargon is far too often abused for non-sense rhetoric with the intention of making political cases seem irrefutable. Citizens then become customers, public administrations are turned into management agencies, and matters of public interest are reduced to objects of narrow-minded bean-counting. This is not so in the case of Global Public Goods. Here we are dealing with correctly defined issues of humankind’s welfare and survival. The very fact that the concept has not yet been made operational in political terms makes the debate about Global Public Goods all the more relevant. The converging global society must meet enormous challenges – and that implies that governments have to pursue strategies of cross-border cooperation. It may be impossible to check what happens with every single German tax euro in a multilateral policy context and, indeed, the negotiations are prone to be more complicated and time-consuming than in the case of bilateral agreements. The challenges of globalisation, however, will not be mastered with individual bilateral projects – no matter how successful they might turn out.
2,824
<h4>Extinction. </h4><p><u><strong>DC 4</u></strong> – Magazine for Development and Cooperation, funded by Germany’s Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development, Where Markets Fail, March, http://www.inwent.org/E+Z/content/archive-eng/03-2004/edit_art1.html</p><p>There are also <u><strong><mark>public goods at the global level</mark>. They <mark>include </mark>the <mark>control of </mark>dangerous <mark>diseases, fair rules to govern </mark>international <mark>trade</mark>, <mark>protection of the atmosphere and </mark>of <mark>biodiversity</mark>, <mark>peace </mark>and security, <mark>as well as a stable finance system</mark>. Only multilateral coordination can handle deficits that arise globally</u></strong>. In political and conceptual terms, an International Task Force on Global Public Goods is working on getting a clearer grip of humankind’s shared interests. The aim is to improve the capacity for action at intergovernmental and supranational levels. The German Development Ministry supports the Task Force (Heidemarie Wieczorek-Zeul, p. 100). The UNDP Director who has drawn international attention to the concept of public goods emphasises the useful impact it might have on multilateral politics (interview with Inge Kaul, p. 104). However<u><strong>, the <mark>unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current </mark>multilateral <mark>system</u></strong> </mark>(Dirk Messner, p. 111). Moreover, the debate does not, of course, take place in a power vacuum. The question is how to make the Global Public Goods agenda palatable for developing countries. Many of them have so far experienced multilateral politics subjected to orders from the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund and as wallflowers in the World Trade Organisation rather than as partners with equal rights (Mariama Williams, p. 113). Without doubt, a utopian element of hope marks the debate on Global Public Goods. However, its core of the – economically defined – public interest is brilliantly rational. After all, economics is originally the science of the intelligent use of resources. Unfortunately, economics jargon is far too often abused for non-sense rhetoric with the intention of making political cases seem irrefutable. Citizens then become customers, public administrations are turned into management agencies, and matters of public interest are reduced to objects of narrow-minded bean-counting. This is not so in the case of Global Public Goods. Here <u><strong><mark>we are dealing with </mark>correctly defined <mark>issues of humankind’s</mark> welfare and <mark>survival</mark>. </u></strong>The very fact that the concept has not yet been made operational in political terms makes the debate about Global Public Goods all the more relevant. <u><strong>The converging global society must meet enormous challenges – and that implies that <mark>governments have to pursue </mark>strategies of <mark>cross-border cooperation</u></strong></mark>. It may be impossible to check what happens with every single German tax euro in a multilateral policy context and, indeed, the negotiations are prone to be more complicated and time-consuming than in the case of bilateral agreements. <u><strong>The <mark>challenges </mark>of globalisation, however, <mark>will not be mastered with individual </mark>bilateral <mark>projects </mark>– <mark>no matter how successful </mark>they might turn out.</p></u></strong>
2NC
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
430,535
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,021
Best data proves unipolar systems are substantially more war-prone than multipolar alternatives
Monteiro, 12
Monteiro, 12 - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Yale University (Nuno P., Winter 2012, “Unrest Assured Why Unipolarity is Not Peaceful”, http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/ISEC_a_00064, KONTOPOULOS)
How well does the argument that unipolar systems are peaceful account for the first two decades of unipolarity since the end of the Cold War? Unipolarity is the most conflict prone of all the systems, according to at least two important criteria: the percentage of years that great powers spend at war and the incidence of war involving great powers. In multipolarity, 18 percent of great power years were spent at war. In bipolarity, the ratio is 16 percent In unipolarity, however, a remarkable 59 percent of great power years until now were spent at war. This is by far the highest percentage in all three systems during periods of multipolarity and bipolarity the probability that war involving a great power would break out in any given year was 4.2 percent and 3.4 percent. Under unipolarity, it is 18 more than four times higher These figures provide no evidence that unipolarity is peaceful
Unipolarity is the most conflict prone of all systems, according to percentage of years great powers spend at war and the incidence of war involving great powers. In multipolarity, 18 percent of great power years were at war In unipolarity 59 percent This is by far the highest during multipolarity the probability war involving a great power would break out was 4 percent Under unipolarity, it is 18
How well, then, does the argument that unipolar systems are peaceful account for the first two decades of unipolarity since the end of the Cold War? Table 1 presents a list of great powers divided into three periods: 1816 to 1945, multipolarity; 1946 to 1989, bipolarity; and since 1990, unipolarity.46 Table 2 presents summary data about the incidence of war during each of these periods. Unipolarity is the most conflict prone of all the systems, according to at least two important criteria: the percentage of years that great powers spend at war and the incidence of war involving great powers. In multipolarity, 18 percent of great power years were spent at war. In bipolarity, the ratio is 16 percent. In unipolarity, however, a remarkable 59 percent of great power years until now were spent at war. This is by far the highest percentage in all three systems. Furthermore, during periods of multipolarity and bipolarity, the probability that war involving a great power would break out in any given year was, respectively, 4.2 percent and 3.4 percent. Under unipolarity, it is 18.2 percent—or more than four times higher.47 These figures provide no evidence that unipolarity is peaceful.48
1,196
<h4>Best data proves unipolar systems are substantially more war-prone than multipolar alternatives </h4><p><strong>Monteiro, 12</strong> - Assistant Professor of Political Science at Yale University (Nuno P., Winter 2012, “Unrest Assured Why Unipolarity is Not Peaceful”, http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/ISEC_a_00064, KONTOPOULOS)</p><p><u>How well</u>, then, <u>does the argument that unipolar systems are peaceful account for the first two decades of unipolarity since the end of the Cold War?</u> Table 1 presents a list of great powers divided into three periods: 1816 to 1945, multipolarity; 1946 to 1989, bipolarity; and since 1990, unipolarity.46 Table 2 presents summary data about the incidence of war during each of these periods. <u><strong><mark>Unipolarity is the most conflict prone of all</mark> the <mark>systems, </strong>according to</mark> at least two important criteria<strong>: the <mark>percentage of years</mark> that <mark>great powers spend at war</strong> and the <strong>incidence of war involving great powers</strong>.<strong> </strong>In multipolarity,</u> <u>18 percent of great power years were</mark> spent <mark>at war</mark>.</u> <u>In bipolarity, the ratio is 16 percent</u>. <u><mark>In unipolarity</mark>, however<strong>, a remarkable <mark>59 percent</mark> of great power years until now were spent at war</strong>.<strong> </strong><mark>This is</u> <u>by far the highest</mark> percentage in all three systems</u>. Furthermore, <u><mark>during</mark> periods of <mark>multipolarity</mark> and bipolarity</u>, <u><mark>the probability</mark> that <mark>war involving a great power would break out</mark> in any given year <mark>was</u></mark>, respectively, <u><mark>4</mark>.2<strong> <mark>percent</mark> </strong>and 3.4 percent<strong>. <mark>Under unipolarity, it is 18</u></strong></mark>.2 percent—or <u>more than<strong> four times higher</u></strong>.47 <u>These figures provide</u> <u><strong>no evidence that unipolarity is peaceful</u></strong>.48</p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
16,080
81
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,022
We control time frame and magnitude – deal failure draws in global powers and goes nuclear within months
PressTV 13
PressTV 13
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in months should the world powers fail to reach a nuclear deal with Iran If the talks fail then there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran before Obama leaves office The United States could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other and those are the kinds of conditions that can lead to miscalculation we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons failure in talks with Iran could lead to war
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in months should the world powers fail to reach a deal with Iran If the talks fail there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran The U S could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other those conditions can lead to miscalculation
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail, 11/13/13, http://www.presstv.ir/detail/2013/11/13/334544/global-nuclear-war-likely-if-iran-talks-fail/ A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in the coming months should the world powers fail to reach a nuclear deal with Iran, an American analyst says.¶ “If the talks fail, if the agreements being pursued are not successfully carried forward and implemented, then there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran before [US President Barack] Obama leaves office and that’s a very great danger that no one can underestimate the importance of,” senior editor at the Executive Intelligence Review Jeff Steinberg told Press TV on Wednesday. ¶ “The United States could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other and those are the kinds of conditions that can lead to miscalculation and general roar,” Steinberg said. ¶ “So the danger in this situation is that if these talks don’t go forward, we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months and years and that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons,” he warned. ¶ The warning came one day after the White House told Congress not to impose new sanctions against Tehran because failure in talks with Iran could lead to war.
1,431
<h4><strong>We control time frame and magnitude – deal failure draws in global powers and goes nuclear within months </h4><p>PressTV 13</p><p><u></strong><mark>Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail</u></mark>, 11/13/13, http://www.presstv.ir/detail/2013/11/13/334544/global-nuclear-war-likely-if-iran-talks-fail/</p><p><u><mark>A <strong>global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in </u></strong></mark>the coming<u><strong><mark> months should the world powers fail to reach a</mark> nuclear <mark>deal with Iran</u></strong></mark>, an American analyst says.¶ “<u><mark>If the talks fail</u></mark>, if the agreements being pursued are not successfully carried forward and implemented, <u>then <mark>there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran</mark> before</u> [US President Barack] <u>Obama leaves office</u> and that’s a very great danger that no one can underestimate the importance of,” senior editor at the Executive Intelligence Review Jeff Steinberg told Press TV on Wednesday. ¶ “<u><mark>The U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates <mark>could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other</mark> and <mark>those</mark> are the kinds of <mark>conditions</mark> that <mark>can <strong>lead to miscalculation</u></strong></mark> and general roar,” Steinberg said. ¶ “So the danger in this situation is that if these talks don’t go forward, <u>we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months</u> and years and <u>that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons</u>,” he warned. ¶ The warning came one day after the White House told Congress not to impose new sanctions against Tehran because <u>failure in talks with Iran could lead to war</u>.</p>
1NR
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
188,942
22
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,023
Hegemony destroys effective institutions global public goods.
Ikenberry et al 9 - G. John Ikenberry is a professor of politics and international affairs at Princeton University, Michael Mastanduno is a professor of government and associate dean for social sciences at Dartmouth College, William C. Wohlforth is a professor of government at Dartmouth College, “Unipolarity, State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE
Ikenberry et al 9 - G. John Ikenberry is a professor of politics and international affairs at Princeton University, Michael Mastanduno is a professor of government and associate dean for social sciences at Dartmouth College, William C. Wohlforth is a professor of government at Dartmouth College, “Unipolarity, State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE
The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo leading states “will attempt to change the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, institutions, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions Jervis argues that unipolarity offers powerful structural incentives for the leading state to be revisionist. These include the absence of countervailing power, the tendency for both the interests and the fears of the leading state to increase as its relative capabilities increase, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are reinforced by particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—the sense after the attacks of September 11, 2001, that the world could and must be transformed and the enduring and widespread belief that international peace and cooperation will be sustained only when all other important states are democratic. We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole to pursue more parochial interests even at the expense of a stable international order. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, its efforts are likely to be perceived by less powerful states as hypocritical attempts to mask the actual pursuit of private goods.
leading states “will change institutions unipolarity offers powerful incentives to be revisionist. absence of countervailing power, tendency for interests and the fears of the state to increase as capabilities increase reinforced by the sense after September 11 the world must be transformed and the widespread belief peace will be only when all states are democratic We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods to pursue parochial interests at the expense of a stable international order the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others its efforts are perceived as hypocritical attempts to mask private goods
Unipolarity and Revisionism: Is the Unipole a Satisfied State? The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo.17 In War and Change in World Politics, Robert Gilpin argued that leading states “will attempt to change the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs.”18 In the quarter century since that book’s publication, international relations scholars have never seriously debated whether the “expected net gain” of systemic revisionism might be positive for the United States. It is hardly surprising that scholars set aside the question of revising the territorial status quo—it is hard to imagine plausible arguments for the utility of large-scale conquest in an age of nuclear weapons and economic globalization. But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, institutions, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions. Why has there been no scholarly debate on whether the United States might seek to revise that aspect of the system? In the 1980s, to be sure, the question did not seem relevant. Scholars believed that the United States was in relative decline, so the costs of changing the system were simply assumed to be high, and a U.S. preference for the status quo appeared obvious. The transition from bipolarity to unipolarity arguably represented a dramatic power shift in favor of the United States, altering Gilpin’s equation toward revisionism. Yet the question of whether, as a new unipole, the United States might adopt a more revisionist stance has not figured centrally in international relations research. The reason was a key assumption built into almost all research on hegemonic stability and power transition theory: that the leading state in any international system is bound to be satisfied. Hence, research on the origins of satisfaction and revisionism is soverwhelmingly about subordinate states, not the dominant state.19 [End Page 12] Robert Jervis’s article in this issue demonstrates that this assumption is no longer tenable. While the case can be made that a unipole—particularly one that achieved this status in an international system already strongly shaped by its power and preferences—might rationally opt for conservatism,20 international relations scholarship is rich with hypotheses proposing that the opposite is equally if not more likely. Jervis argues that unipolarity offers powerful structural incentives for the leading state to be revisionist. These include the absence of countervailing power, the tendency for both the interests and the fears of the leading state to increase as its relative capabilities increase, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are reinforced by particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—the sense after the attacks of September 11, 2001, that the world could and must be transformed and the enduring and widespread belief that international peace and cooperation will be sustained only when all other important states are democratic. The structural and contingent features of contemporary unipolarity point plausibly in the direction of a revisionist unipole, one simultaneously powerful, fearful, and opportunistic. Unipolarity and the Provision of Public Goods Public or collective goods may be consumed by multiple actors without those actors necessarily having to pay the full costs of producing them. The classic theoretical insight is that if enough actors follow their rational self-interest and choose to free ride on the efforts of others, public goods will be underproduced or not produced at all.21 Overcoming the free-rider problem therefore requires cooperation among self-interested actors.22 A good part of the ir literature, in particular that associated with hegemonic stability theory, hypothesizes that cooperation in international relations requires the leadership of a dominant state.23 [End Page 13] Given its preponderance of economic and military resources, the dominant state has the ability to bear a disproportionate share of the costs of providing international collective goods such as an open world economy or a stable security order. The dominant state has an interest in bearing those costs because it benefits disproportionately from promoting systemwide outcomes that reflect its values and interests. During the cold war the United States took on the responsibilities that Kindleberger argued were needed to promote international economic stability, such as serving as an open market of last resort and allowing the use of its currency for exchange and reserve purposes. International economic stability among the Western powers reinforced their security alliance against the Soviet Union. The United States also bore a disproportionate share of the direct costs of Western alliance security. The Soviet Union, on its side of the international divide, ultimately shouldered disproportionate alliance costs as well.24 Waltz took the argument a step further, arguing that in the bipolar system the United States and the Soviet Union may have been adversaries but, as the two dominant powers, shared a mutual interest in system stability, an interest that prompted them to cooperate in providing public goods such as nuclear nonproliferation.25 Hedley Bull makes a similar point in his classic study of the international system as a society of states.26 How might the shift from a bipolar to a unipolar system affect the inclination of the now singularly dominant state to provide international public goods? Two hypotheses arise, with contradictory behavioral expectations. First, we might expect a unipole to take on an even greater responsibility for the provision of international public goods. The capabilities of a unipole relative to other major states are greater than those of either dominant power in a bipolar structure. The unipole’s incentive should be stronger as well, since it now has the opportunity to influence international outcomes globally, not just in its [End Page 14] particular subsystem. We should expect the unipole to try to “lock in” a durable international order that reflects its interests and values.27 A second hypothesis, however, suggests the opposite. We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole to pursue more parochial interests even at the expense of a stable international order. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. Two of the contributions below address these issues. Michael Mastanduno’s analysis of the global political economy shows that the dominant state will be both system maker and privilege taker—it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. It enlists the cooperation of other states and seeks, with varying degrees of success, to force adjustment burdens upon them. Jervis suggests that because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, its efforts are likely to be perceived by less powerful states as hypocritical attempts to mask the actual pursuit of private goods.
7,664
<h4>Hegemony destroys effective institutions global public goods. </h4><p><u><strong><mark>Ikenberry et al 9</u> -<u></mark> G. John Ikenberry is a professor of politics and international affairs at Princeton University, Michael Mastanduno is a professor of government and associate dean for social sciences at Dartmouth College, William C. Wohlforth is a professor of government at Dartmouth College, “Unipolarity, State Behavior, and Systemic Consequences”, World Politics, 61.1, Jan, MUSE</p><p></u></strong>Unipolarity and Revisionism: Is the Unipole a Satisfied State? <u><strong>The stability of any international system depends significantly on the degree to which the major powers are satisfied with the status quo</u></strong>.17 In War and Change in World Politics, Robert Gilpin argued that <u><strong><mark>leading states “will</mark> attempt to <mark>change</mark> the international system if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs</u></strong>.”18 In the quarter century since that book’s publication, international relations scholars have never seriously debated whether the “expected net gain” of systemic revisionism might be positive for the United States. It is hardly surprising that scholars set aside the question of revising the territorial status quo—it is hard to imagine plausible arguments for the utility of large-scale conquest in an age of nuclear weapons and economic globalization. <u><strong>But the territorial status quo is only a part of what Gilpin meant by “international system.” The other part comprises the rules, <mark>institutions</mark>, and standards of legitimacy that frame daily interactions</u></strong>. Why has there been no scholarly debate on whether the United States might seek to revise that aspect of the system? In the 1980s, to be sure, the question did not seem relevant. Scholars believed that the United States was in relative decline, so the costs of changing the system were simply assumed to be high, and a U.S. preference for the status quo appeared obvious. The transition from bipolarity to unipolarity arguably represented a dramatic power shift in favor of the United States, altering Gilpin’s equation toward revisionism. Yet the question of whether, as a new unipole, the United States might adopt a more revisionist stance has not figured centrally in international relations research. The reason was a key assumption built into almost all research on hegemonic stability and power transition theory: that the leading state in any international system is bound to be satisfied. Hence, research on the origins of satisfaction and revisionism is soverwhelmingly about subordinate states, not the dominant state.19 [End Page 12] Robert Jervis’s article in this issue demonstrates that this assumption is no longer tenable. While the case can be made that a unipole—particularly one that achieved this status in an international system already strongly shaped by its power and preferences—might rationally opt for conservatism,20 international relations scholarship is rich with hypotheses proposing that the opposite is equally if not more likely.<u><strong> Jervis argues that <mark>unipolarity offers powerful </mark>structural <mark>incentives </mark>for the leading state<mark> to be revisionist. </mark>These include the <mark>absence of countervailing power, </mark>the <mark>tendency for </mark>both the <mark>interests and the fears of the </mark>leading <mark>state to increase as</mark> its relative <mark>capabilities increase</mark>, and the psychological tendency to worry more about the future to the extent the present situation is desirable. Jervis also suggests that these structural incentives are <mark>reinforced by </mark>particular features of the American approach to unipolarity—<mark>the sense after </mark>the attacks of <mark>September 11</mark>, 2001, that <mark>the world </mark>could and <mark>must be transformed and the </mark>enduring and <mark>widespread belief </mark>that international <mark>peace </mark>and cooperation <mark>will</mark> <mark>be </mark>sustained <mark>only when all </mark>other important <mark>states are democratic</mark>.</u></strong> The structural and contingent features of contemporary unipolarity point plausibly in the direction of a revisionist unipole, one simultaneously powerful, fearful, and opportunistic. Unipolarity and the Provision of Public Goods Public or collective goods may be consumed by multiple actors without those actors necessarily having to pay the full costs of producing them. The classic theoretical insight is that if enough actors follow their rational self-interest and choose to free ride on the efforts of others, public goods will be underproduced or not produced at all.21 Overcoming the free-rider problem therefore requires cooperation among self-interested actors.22 A good part of the ir literature, in particular that associated with hegemonic stability theory, hypothesizes that cooperation in international relations requires the leadership of a dominant state.23 [End Page 13] Given its preponderance of economic and military resources, the dominant state has the ability to bear a disproportionate share of the costs of providing international collective goods such as an open world economy or a stable security order. The dominant state has an interest in bearing those costs because it benefits disproportionately from promoting systemwide outcomes that reflect its values and interests. During the cold war the United States took on the responsibilities that Kindleberger argued were needed to promote international economic stability, such as serving as an open market of last resort and allowing the use of its currency for exchange and reserve purposes. International economic stability among the Western powers reinforced their security alliance against the Soviet Union. The United States also bore a disproportionate share of the direct costs of Western alliance security. The Soviet Union, on its side of the international divide, ultimately shouldered disproportionate alliance costs as well.24 Waltz took the argument a step further, arguing that in the bipolar system the United States and the Soviet Union may have been adversaries but, as the two dominant powers, shared a mutual interest in system stability, an interest that prompted them to cooperate in providing public goods such as nuclear nonproliferation.25 Hedley Bull makes a similar point in his classic study of the international system as a society of states.26 How might the shift from a bipolar to a unipolar system affect the inclination of the now singularly dominant state to provide international public goods? Two hypotheses arise, with contradictory behavioral expectations. First, we might expect a unipole to take on an even greater responsibility for the provision of international public goods. The capabilities of a unipole relative to other major states are greater than those of either dominant power in a bipolar structure. The unipole’s incentive should be stronger as well, since it now has the opportunity to influence international outcomes globally, not just in its [End Page 14] particular subsystem. We should expect the unipole to try to “lock in” a durable international order that reflects its interests and values.27 A second hypothesis, however, suggests the opposite. <u><strong><mark>We should expect a unipolar power to underproduce public goods</mark> despite its preponderant capabilities. The fact that it is unthreatened by peer competitors and relatively unconstrained by other states creates incentives for the unipole <mark>to pursue </mark>more <mark>parochial interests </mark>even <mark>at the expense of a stable international order</mark>. The fact that it is extraordinarily powerful means that <mark>the unipole will be more inclined to force adjustment costs on others</mark>, rather than bear disproportionate burdens itself. </u></strong>Two of the contributions below address these issues. Michael Mastanduno’s analysis of the global political economy shows that the dominant state will be both system maker and privilege taker—<u><strong>it will seek simultaneously to provide public goods and to exploit its advantageous structural position for parochial gain. </u></strong>It enlists the cooperation of other states and seeks, with varying degrees of success, to force adjustment burdens upon them. Jervis suggests that <u><strong>because the unipole has wide discretion in determining the nature and the extent of the goods provided, <mark>its efforts are </mark>likely to be <mark>perceived </mark>by less powerful states <mark>as hypocritical attempts to mask </mark>the actual pursuit of <mark>private goods</mark>.</p></u></strong>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
292,657
5
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,024
Turns terror
Brookes 07,
Brookes 07, National security affairs senior fellow, 07 (Peter, 4-2-07, “Iran Emboldened: Tehran Seeks to Dominate Middle East Politics”, DOA: 10-10-13, http://www.heritage.org/research/commentary/2007/04/iran-emboldened-tehran-seeks-to-dominate-middle-east-politics, llc)
According to the State Department, Iran continues to be the world's most active state sponsor of terrorism Iran's Ministry of Intelligence and Security and Revolutionary Guard Corps support terrorist groups with funding, training and weapons. Tehran may fund Hezbollah to 100 million per year Hezbollah fired as many as 10,000 Iran-supplied rockets and missiles Hezbollah is threatening to topple Lebanon's government Iran has made a number of not-so-veiled threats that it would deploy its irregular forces and terrorist allies against the U.S This is likely not an idle threat It is almost without question that Tehran sees its ability to hold U.S. interests at risk across the globe as leverage against American military action over its nuclear program or meddling in Iraq Iran could transfer nuclear capability to a Hezbollah-dominated government The insurgency's recent use of chlorine gas is evidence of a terrorist group's willingness to employ WMD.
Iran continues to be the world's sponsor of terrorism Iran's Ministry of Intelligence support terrorist groups Tehran fund Hezbollah to topple Lebanon This is not an idle threat Tehran sees its ability to hold U.S. interests at risk across the globe as leverage against American action Iran could transfer nuclear capability use of chlorine is evidence of willingness to employ WMD
According to the U.S. State Department, Iran continues to be the world's most active state sponsor of terrorism. At the request of senior Iranian leadership, Iran's Ministry of Intelligence and Security (MOIS) and Islamic Revolutionary Guard Corps (IRGC) support Palestinian terrorist groups such as Hamas, Palestinian Islamic Jihad, the al Aqsa Martyrs Brigade and the Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine-General Command with funding, training and weapons. Hezbollah - a Lebanese Shiite terrorist group - is a particular favorite. In fact, Iran established Hezbollah to parry Israel's 1982 invasion of Lebanon. Tehran may fund Hezbollah to the tune of $100 million per year. Last summer, Tehran's military support for Hezbollah was evident. Iran likely gave Hezbollah the green light to ambush an Israeli patrol and kidnap soldiers, which ultimately kicked off the monthlong conflict. In the ensuing days, Hezbollah indiscriminately fired as many as 10,000 Iran-supplied rockets and missiles into Israel. In addition, many were stunned when a C-802 cruise missile struck an Israeli naval vessel off the coast of Lebanon. While the shooter was never identified, the Chinese C-802 is in Iran's inventory. It could have been fired by either Hezbollah or the IRGC. Today, Hezbollah, with Iranian and Syrian support, is threatening to topple Lebanon's democratically elected government unless it is given additional cabinet seats - potentially giving it veto power over Beirut's decisions. Iran would love to add Lebanon to Syria as a client state in its effort to form an arc of Iranian influence across the region. Iran has made a number of not-so-veiled threats that it would deploy its irregular forces and terrorist allies against the U.S. and American interests, if necessary. This is likely not an idle threat. American blood is already on the hands of Iran and its terrorist proxies as a result of the 1983 Beirut Marine barracks attack and the 1996 Khobar Towers bombing in Saudi Arabia, and in Iraq today. It is almost without question that Tehran sees its ability to hold U.S. interests at risk across the globe - including in the U.S. - as leverage against American military action over its nuclear program or meddling in Iraq. Perhaps the most frightening scenario is that Iran might transfer weapons of mass destruction capability to a terrorist ally. While this is risky behavior, it is a possibility. Iran could transfer nuclear capability to a Hezbollah-dominated government in Lebanon, or a Hamas-led Palestinian Authority, significantly increasing the threat to Israeli security. Osama bin Laden has not been shy about his desire for WMD or al-Qaida's readiness to use them. The insurgency's recent use of chlorine gas in Iraq is evidence of a terrorist group's willingness to employ WMD.
2,813
<h4>Turns terror </h4><p><strong>Brookes 07,</strong> National security affairs senior fellow, 07</p><p>(Peter, 4-2-07, “Iran Emboldened: Tehran Seeks to Dominate Middle East Politics”, DOA: 10-10-13, http://www.heritage.org/research/commentary/2007/04/iran-emboldened-tehran-seeks-to-dominate-middle-east-politics, llc)</p><p><u>According to the</u> U.S. <u>State Department, <strong><mark>Iran continues to be the world's</mark> most active state <mark>sponsor of terrorism</u></strong></mark>. At the request of senior Iranian leadership, <u><mark>Iran's Ministry of Intelligence</mark> and Security</u> (MOIS) <u>and</u> Islamic <u>Revolutionary Guard Corps</u> (IRGC) <u><mark>support</u></mark> Palestinian <u><mark>terrorist groups</u></mark> such as Hamas, Palestinian Islamic Jihad, the al Aqsa Martyrs Brigade and the Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine-General Command <u>with funding, training and weapons.</u> Hezbollah - a Lebanese Shiite terrorist group - is a particular favorite. In fact, Iran established Hezbollah to parry Israel's 1982 invasion of Lebanon. <u><mark>Tehran</mark> may <mark>fund Hezbollah</mark> to</u> the tune of $<u>100 million per year</u>. Last summer, Tehran's military support for Hezbollah was evident. Iran likely gave Hezbollah the green light to ambush an Israeli patrol and kidnap soldiers, which ultimately kicked off the monthlong conflict. In the ensuing days, <u>Hezbollah</u> indiscriminately <u>fired as many as 10,000 Iran-supplied rockets and missiles</u> into Israel. In addition, many were stunned when a C-802 cruise missile struck an Israeli naval vessel off the coast of Lebanon. While the shooter was never identified, the Chinese C-802 is in Iran's inventory. It could have been fired by either Hezbollah or the IRGC. Today, <u>Hezbollah</u>, with Iranian and Syrian support, <u>is threatening <mark>to topple Lebanon</mark>'s </u>democratically elected <u>government</u> unless it is given additional cabinet seats - potentially giving it veto power over Beirut's decisions. Iran would love to add Lebanon to Syria as a client state in its effort to form an arc of Iranian influence across the region. <u>Iran has made a number of not-so-veiled threats that it would deploy its irregular forces and terrorist allies against the U.S</u>. and American interests, if necessary. <u><mark>This is</mark> likely <mark>not an idle threat</u></mark>. American blood is already on the hands of Iran and its terrorist proxies as a result of the 1983 Beirut Marine barracks attack and the 1996 Khobar Towers bombing in Saudi Arabia, and in Iraq today. <u>It is almost without question that <mark>Tehran sees its ability to hold U.S. interests at risk across the globe</u></mark> - including in the U.S. - <u><mark>as leverage against American </mark>military <mark>action</mark> over its nuclear program or meddling in Iraq</u>. Perhaps the most frightening scenario is that Iran might transfer weapons of mass destruction capability to a terrorist ally. While this is risky behavior, it is a possibility. <u><mark>Iran could transfer nuclear capability</mark> to a Hezbollah-dominated government</u> in Lebanon, or a Hamas-led Palestinian Authority, significantly increasing the threat to Israeli security. Osama bin Laden has not been shy about his desire for WMD or al-Qaida's readiness to use them. <u>The insurgency's recent <mark>use of chlorine</mark> gas</u> in Iraq <u><mark>is evidence of</mark> a terrorist group's <mark>willingness to employ WMD</mark>.</u><strong> </p></strong>
1NR
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
171,452
7
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,025
Extinction. DC 4 – Magazine for Development and Cooperation, funded by Germany’s Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development, Where Markets Fail, March, http://www.inwent.org/E+Z/content/archive-eng/03-2004/edit_art1.html
DC 4
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Extinction. </h4><p><u><strong>DC 4</u></strong> – Magazine for Development and Cooperation, funded by Germany’s Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development, Where Markets Fail, March, http://www.inwent.org/E+Z/content/archive-eng/03-2004/edit_art1.html</p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,536
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,026
Aggressive actions toward Iran heighten the risk of Iran strikes—Israel would perceive support
McConnell 13 Scott, Founding Editor, The American Conservative; PhD, History, Columbia University; “Schumer-Menendez-Kirk Open the Back Door to War” The American Conservative
McConnell 13 Scott, Founding Editor, The American Conservative; PhD, History, Columbia University; “Schumer-Menendez-Kirk Open the Back Door to War” The American Conservative; December 20, 2013; http://www.theamericanconservative.com/schumer-menendez-kirk-open-the-back-door-to-war/
Schumer and Menendez (N.J.) have joined Kirk (Ill.) in placing a ticking bomb under Obama The bill requires the U S to “stand with Israel” in the event Netanyahu decides to start a war with Iran. The purpose of the bill is to scuttle diplomacy with Tehran, the bill “outsources any decision about resort to military action to the government of Israel, by These are the two central points. Netanyahu wants war with Iran, but he doesn’t want to fight it by himself. Schumer, Menendez, and Kirk hope to compel the United States to step in and finish the job after Israel throws the first punch. even if such a war were just (which it isn’t), the aftermath with blood There is no realistic scenario under which Iran’s government is going abandon entirely its nuclear program Their resolution is a backdoor to war
Schumer and Menendez joined Kirk placing a ticking bomb under Obama The bill requires the U S to “stand with Israel” in the event Netanyahu decides to start a war with Iran the bill “outsources any decision about military action to Israel Netanyahu wants war with Iran, but he doesn’t want to fight it by himself Schumer, Menendez, and Kirk hope to compel the United States to step in and finish the job Their resolution is a backdoor to war
Democrats Charles Schumer (N.Y.) and Robert Menendez (N.J.) have joined Republican Mark Kirk (Ill.) in placing a ticking bomb under President Obama’s Christmas tree. The bomb is an AIPAC-sponsored bill that commits the United States to stop Iran from enriching any uranium at all, and also requires the United States to “stand with Israel” in the event Netanyahu decides, for reasons of “self-defense,” to start a war with Iran. The purpose of the bill is transparent: to scuttle the P5+1 (U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Russia, and China) diplomacy with Tehran, because it is well known to everyone concerned that Iran is not going to abandon completely a nuclear energy program underway since the Shah was in power. Gary Sick, the Columbia University Iran expert, has posted on his website an open letter to Schumer, noting that the bill seeks to “remove any negotiating authority from the U.S. government by specifying in advance the terms of an impossible settlement.” Further, Sick observes, the bill “outsources any decision about resort to military action to the government of Israel, by committing the United States in advance to support any military action by Israel.” These are the two central points. Netanyahu wants war with Iran, but he doesn’t want to fight it by himself. Schumer, Menendez, and Kirk hope to compel the United States to step in and finish the job after Israel throws the first punch. But even if such a war were just (which it isn’t), or even if we had allies besides Israel (which we wouldn’t), the aftermath of such a war ends most likely (as the former hawk Kenneth Pollack argues in his exhaustive analysis “Unthinkable“) with an American occupation of Iran. At a cost in blood and treasure many times the invasion of Iraq. There is no realistic scenario under which Iran’s government is going abandon entirely its nuclear program. Schumer, Kirk, and Menendez know this perfectly well. Their resolution is a backdoor to war. They just don’t have the courage, as yet, to say so.
2,013
<h4>Aggressive actions toward Iran heighten the risk of Iran strikes—Israel would perceive support</h4><p><strong>McConnell 13 Scott, Founding Editor, The American Conservative; PhD, History, Columbia University; “Schumer-Menendez-Kirk Open the Back Door to War” The American Conservative<u></strong>; December 20, 2013; http://www.theamericanconservative.com/schumer-menendez-kirk-open-the-back-door-to-war/</p><p></u>Democrats Charles <u><mark>Schumer</u></mark> (N.Y.) <u><mark>and</mark> </u>Robert<u> <mark>Menendez</mark> (N.J.) have <mark>joined</mark> </u>Republican<u> </u>Mark<u> <mark>Kirk</mark> (Ill.) in <mark>placing a ticking bomb under</mark> </u>President <u><mark>Obama</u></mark>’s Christmas tree. <u><mark>The</u></mark> bomb is an AIPAC-sponsored <u><mark>bill</u></mark> that commits the United States to stop Iran from enriching any uranium at all, and also <u><mark>requires the</u> <u>U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u><mark>to “stand with Israel” in the event Netanyahu decides</u></mark>, for reasons of “self-defense,” <u><mark>to start a war with Iran</mark>.</u> <u>The purpose of the bill is</u> transparent: <u>to scuttle</u> the P5+1 (U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Russia, and China) <u>diplomacy with Tehran,</u> because it is well known to everyone concerned that Iran is not going to abandon completely a nuclear energy program underway since the Shah was in power. Gary Sick, the Columbia University Iran expert, has posted on his website an open letter to Schumer, noting that the bill seeks to “remove any negotiating authority from the U.S. government by specifying in advance the terms of an impossible settlement.” Further, Sick observes, <u><mark>the bill “outsources any decision about</mark> resort to <mark>military action to</mark> the government of <mark>Israel</mark>, by</u> committing the United States in advance to support any military action by Israel.” <u>These are the two central points. <mark>Netanyahu wants war with Iran, but he doesn’t want to fight it by himself</mark>. <mark>Schumer, Menendez, and Kirk hope to compel the United States to step in and finish the job</mark> after Israel throws the first punch.</u> But <u>even if such a war were just (which it isn’t),</u> or even if we had allies besides Israel (which we wouldn’t), <u>the aftermath</u> of such a war ends most likely (as the former hawk Kenneth Pollack argues in his exhaustive analysis “Unthinkable“) <u>with</u> an American occupation of Iran. At a cost in <u>blood</u> and treasure many times the invasion of Iraq. <u>There is no realistic scenario under which Iran’s government is going abandon entirely its nuclear program</u>. Schumer, Kirk, and Menendez know this perfectly well. <u><mark>Their resolution is a backdoor to war</u><strong></mark>. They just don’t have the courage, as yet, to say so.</p></strong>
1NR
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
430,537
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,027
There are also public goods at the global level. They include the control of dangerous diseases, fair rules to govern international trade, protection of the atmosphere and of biodiversity, peace and security, as well as a stable finance system. Only multilateral coordination can handle deficits that arise globally. In political and conceptual terms, an International Task Force on Global Public Goods is working on getting a clearer grip of humankind’s shared interests. The aim is to improve the capacity for action at intergovernmental and supranational levels. The German Development Ministry supports the Task Force (Heidemarie Wieczorek-Zeul, p. 100). The UNDP Director who has drawn international attention to the concept of public goods emphasises the useful impact it might have on multilateral politics (interview with Inge Kaul, p. 104). However, the unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current multilateral system (Dirk Messner, p. 111). Moreover, the debate does not, of course, take place in a power vacuum. The question is how to make the Global Public Goods agenda palatable for developing countries. Many of them have so far experienced multilateral politics subjected to orders from the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund and as wallflowers in the World Trade Organisation rather than as partners with equal rights (Mariama Williams, p. 113). Without doubt, a utopian element of hope marks the debate on Global Public Goods. However, its core of the – economically defined – public interest is brilliantly rational. After all, economics is originally the science of the intelligent use of resources. Unfortunately, economics jargon is far too often abused for non-sense rhetoric with the intention of making political cases seem irrefutable. Citizens then become customers, public administrations are turned into management agencies, and matters of public interest are reduced to objects of narrow-minded bean-counting. This is not so in the case of Global Public Goods. Here we are dealing with correctly defined issues of humankind’s welfare and survival. The very fact that the concept has not yet been made operational in political terms makes the debate about Global Public Goods all the more relevant. The converging global society must meet enormous challenges – and that implies that governments have to pursue strategies of cross-border cooperation. It may be impossible to check what happens with every single German tax euro in a multilateral policy context and, indeed, the negotiations are prone to be more complicated and time-consuming than in the case of bilateral agreements
Science diplomacy high now
Science diplomacy high now
“science diplomacy” concept it has been defined as ¶ “the use and application of science cooperation to help build bridges and enhance relationships ¶ between and amongst societies, with a particular interest in working in areas where there might ¶ not be other mechanisms for engagement at an official level.”1¶ In the United States, this policy ¶ shift has been reflected notably by the appointment of science envoys resuming a ¶ dialogue with Middle East, Africa, and Asia and offering opportunities The new global landscape of science is more distributed and networked he United States needs to look around at such linkages scientific advances ropelled not just by individuals but increasingly by overlapping, fluid, networks of scientists These networks frequently extend across and beyond research intensive institutions Networks of scientists are already being supported, by the NSF and through HESN) undertaken by USAID HESN is building diverse international, teams to tackle significant development challenges, Investments in the life sciences pay off in three broad areas, observe MIT President Hockfield. They improve human health. They foster industries addressing a wide range of challenges. And they further human understanding of systems NIH) has invested about $4 per American per year in cardiovascular research. That investment has helped reduce the rate of death from heart disease and stroke by more than half Similar advances have produced benefits throughout medicine Greater understanding of the role of tumor necrosis factor in inflammatory disease has led to antibody treatments If we as a country hadn’t made the investment in the basic science, in the understanding of retroviruses, we would probably still today have a rapidly expanding global AIDS epidemic Continued basic research into fundamental biological processes could yield a wealth of new medical advances Yet biotech crops are today being on 20 percent of and the percentage is projected to double as new crops are introduced and countries like India and China move toward full adoption of the technology This is the most rapidly adopted new technology in the history of agriculture , it is really just the beginning.” life sciences answer fundamental questions biological systems are found in the oceans, new tools have become available to explore the oceans These technologies have revealed the oceans
science diplomacy In the U S this policy has been reflected by the appointment of science envoys resuming a ¶ dialogue with Middle East, Africa, and Asia and offering opportunities The new global landscape of science is networked Networks of scientists are already being supported by t NSF and HESN) undertaken by USAID HESN is building diverse international, teams to tackle significant development challenge Investments in the life sciences pay off in human health. industries And human understanding of systems NIH invested in cardiovascular research. That helped reduce the rate of death from heart disease by half Similar advances produced benefits throughout medicine If we as a country hadn’t made investment in basic science we would still have expanding AIDS Continued basic research could yield new advances biotech crops are on 20 percent of and projected to double as new countries like India and China move toward full adoption new tools have become available to explore the oceans
French Ministry of Global Affairs 13 http://www.france-science.org/IMG/pdf/science-diplomacy-for-france-2013.pdf, “Science Diplomacy for France, 2013, French Ministry of Global Affairs France, who for many decades has viewed scientific cooperation as contributing to the ¶ dialogue between peoples and a means of developing and strengthening national excellence, ¶ sees her approach bolstered by the emergence of the “science diplomacy” concept. Developed in ¶ the United States and widely disseminated in the English-speaking world, it has been defined as ¶ “the use and application of science cooperation to help build bridges and enhance relationships ¶ between and amongst societies, with a particular interest in working in areas where there might ¶ not be other mechanisms for engagement at an official level.”1¶ In the United States, this policy ¶ shift has been reflected notably by the appointment of science envoys tasked with resuming a ¶ dialogue with the elites in the Muslim world (Middle East, Africa, and South-East Asia) and offering ¶ them opportunities 2. Networks and funding now Colglazier and Lyons 14 – E. William Colglazier is the science and technology adviser to the U.S. secretary of state. Elizabeth E. Lyons is a senior adviser in the U.S. Department of State’s Office of the Science and Technology Adviser and its Bureau of Oceans and International Environmental and Scientific Affairs. She is on detail with support from the National Science Foundation to the Department of State. (E. William, Elizabeth E., 2014, “The United States Looks to the Global Science, Technology, and Innovation Horizon”, Science and Diplomacy, http://www.sciencediplomacy.org/perspective/2014/united-states-looks-global-science-technology-and-innovation-horizon)//sb Looking around: The new global landscape of science is more distributed and networked—the United States needs to look around at such linkages. Many scientific advances are now propelled not just by individuals working within individual labs, but increasingly by overlapping, fluid, and largely self-organizing networks of scientists, engineers, technologists, and entrepreneurs. These networks frequently extend across and beyond research intensive institutions. Networks of scientists are already being supported, for example, by the National Science Foundation (NSF) Research Coordination Networks and through initiatives such as the Higher Education Solutions Network (HESN) undertaken by the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID). HESN is building diverse, often international, teams to tackle significant development challenges, making more information on development projects available domestically and internationally, and tying together people and results for stronger impact. biotech inevitable globally and solves all their impacts Their Author NAS 8 (National Academy of Sciences, “The Role of the Life Sciences in Transforming America's Future Summary of a Workshop” December 3, 2008, Board on Life Sciences Division on Earth and Life Studies, National Research Council) //trepka The Promise of the Biological Sciences Investments in the life sciences pay off in three broad areas, observed Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) President Susan Hockfield. They improve human health. They foster industries that boost the economy while addressing a wide range of environmental, energy, health, and agricultural challenges. And they further human understanding of some of the most fascinating systems in the universe. ¶ Improving Human Health ¶ The biological sciences have enabled most of the world’s population to enjoy higher living standards and longer life spans than ever before, said National Academies President Ralph Cicerone. New understanding of the links between disease and sanitation, the role trace nutrients play in health, and the potential of vaccines and antibiotics, among many other research results, have improved the lives of people everywhere. The progress made in combating heart disease is a prime example of the payoffs from investment in the life sciences, said Hockfield. Over the past 30 years, the National Institutes of Health (NIH) has invested about $4 per American per year in cardiovascular research. That investment has helped reduce the rate of death from heart disease and stroke by more than half. Knowledge of cholesterol metabolism led to the development of the drugs known as statins, which have reduced heart attacks and strokes. The development of drug-eluting stents has enabled physicians to open occluded blood vessels. Study of receptors on the surface of nerve cells has led to new beta blockers that are being used to treat hypertension and heart disease. Similar advances have produced benefits throughout medicine, observed Thomas Cech, President of the Howard Hughes Medical Institute, and Harold Varmus, President of the Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center. Greater understanding of the role of tumor necrosis factor in inflammatory disease has led to antibody treatments that have changed the lives of many people with rheumatoid arthritis. Materials science is producing spare parts for bones, arteries, and other tissues and organs. Basic research into retroviruses motivated by their role in some cancers built the base of understanding that proved critical in first identifying the cause of the AIDS epidemic and then developing drugs to control the disease. “If we as a country hadn’t made the investment in the basic science, in the understanding of retroviruses, we would probably still today have a rapidly expanding global AIDS epidemic,” Cech said. Continued basic research into fundamental biological processes could yield a wealth of new medical advances. ¶ Investigations of bacterial genetics could provide new treatments for infectious diseases, including diseases caused by microbes that have evolved mechanisms to evade existing treatments. Bioengineered stem cells could provide regulated insulin secretion in people with diabetes, for example, or repair severed spinal cord nerves. Study of chronic diseases such as cancer, heart disease, and mental illness, which now account for the bulk ¶ 3 of health care costs, could lead to personalized treatments that reflect a disease’s unique characteristics in each individual. However, the translation of basic research findings to applications is not always straightforward or quick, Cech observed. Even where understanding of biological processes is extensive, vast amounts of work must be done, often by people in different disciplines and sectors working collaboratively, to apply new knowledge in medicine. The life sciences have applications in areas that range far beyond human health. Life-science based approaches could contribute to advances in many industries, from energy production and pollution remediation, to clean manufacturing and the production of new biologically inspired materials. In fact, biological systems could provide the basis for new products, services and industries that we cannot yet imagine. Microbes are already producing biofuels and could, through further research, provide a major component of future energy supplies. Marine and terrestrial organisms extract carbon dioxide from the atmosphere, which suggests that biological systems could be used to help manage climate change. Study of the complex systems encountered in biology is ¶ producing insights into similarly interconnected networks encountered in many other areas of science – and vice versa. Take agriculture as an example. The agricultural biotechnology industry is just a little more than a decade old, said Robert Fraley, Executive Vice President and Chief Technology Officer at Monsanto – the first bioengineered crop, a soybean seed with a gene providing tolerance for a common herbicide, was launched in 1996. Yet biotechnology crops are today being planted on 20 percent of the world’s farmland, and the percentage is projected to double as new crops are introduced and countries like India and China move toward full adoption of the technology. “This is the most rapidly adopted new technology in the history of agriculture,” Fraley said. The ability to introduce multiple genes into an ever-expanding array of crops has not only increased yields but has produced significant environmental benefits. By altering the characteristics of crops, agricultural biotechnology has made it possible for farmers to use fewer pesticides and other chemicals. Fewer trips through the fields on tractors mean less greenhouse gas emissions and reduced compaction of soils. Furthermore, the revolution in agricultural biotechnology has just begun, Fraley said. Within a few years, agricultural companies will be selling seeds with ten or more introduced genes. Crops can be modified to improve human health; for example, soybeans have been genetically modified to produce healthy rather than unhealthy fatty acids. Future crops will need far less water, a crucial consideration as climate change alters rainfall patterns and groundwater aquifers are depleted. As Fraley said, “As much as we have seen happen in the last decade, it is really just the beginning.” The life sciences can answer some of the most fundamental, interesting, and difficult questions that human beings can ask. How did the great diversity of living things come to be? How do cells function on a molecular level? What is the role of life in changing the surface of the earth? Consider this last question, said James Collins, who is currently on leave from Arizona State University to serve as Assistant Director for Biological Sciences at the National Science Foundation. According to a recent estimate, of the approximately 4,300 types of minerals on the earth, about 3,000 are the products of biological processes. The evolution of life “put earth under new management,” Collins said. Understanding the future state of the planet will require understanding the biological systems that have shaped the planet. Many of these biological systems are found in the oceans, which cover 70 percent of the earth’s surface and have a crucial impact on weather, climate, and the composition of the atmosphere. In the past decade, new tools have become available to explore the microbial processes that drive the chemistry of the oceans, observed David Kingsbury, Chief Program Officer for Science at the Gordon and Betty Moore Foundation. These technologies have revealed that a large proportion of the planet’s genetic diversity resides in the oceans. In addition, many organisms in the oceans readily exchange genes, creating evolutionary forces that can have global effects. The oceans are currently under great stress, Kingsbury pointed out. Nutrient runoff from agriculture is helping to create huge and expanding “dead zones” where oxygen levels are too low to sustain life. Toxic algal blooms are occurring with higher frequency in areas where they have not been seen in the past. Exploitation of ocean resources is disrupting ecological balances that have formed over many millions of years. Human-induced changes in the chemistry of the atmosphere are changing the chemistry of the oceans, with potentially catastrophic consequences. “If we are not careful, we are not going to have a sustainable planet to live on,” said Kingsbury. Only by understanding the basic biological processes at work in the oceans can humans live sustainably on earth.
11,459
<h4>There are also <u><mark>public goods at the global level</mark>. They <mark>include </mark>the <mark>control of </mark>dangerous <mark>diseases, fair rules to govern </mark>international <mark>trade</mark>, <mark>protection of the atmosphere and </mark>of <mark>biodiversity</mark>, <mark>peace </mark>and security, <mark>as well as a stable finance system</mark>. Only multilateral coordination can handle deficits that arise globally</u>. In political and conceptual terms, an International Task Force on Global Public Goods is working on getting a clearer grip of humankind’s shared interests. The aim is to improve the capacity for action at intergovernmental and supranational levels. The German Development Ministry supports the Task Force (Heidemarie Wieczorek-Zeul, p. 100). The UNDP Director who has drawn international attention to the concept of public goods emphasises the useful impact it might have on multilateral politics (interview with Inge Kaul, p. 104). However<u>, the <mark>unfulfilled need for international coordination is evidence of the weaknesses of the current </mark>multilateral <mark>system</u> </mark>(Dirk Messner, p. 111). Moreover, the debate does not, of course, take place in a power vacuum. The question is how to make the Global Public Goods agenda palatable for developing countries. Many of them have so far experienced multilateral politics subjected to orders from the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund and as wallflowers in the World Trade Organisation rather than as partners with equal rights (Mariama Williams, p. 113). Without doubt, a utopian element of hope marks the debate on Global Public Goods. However, its core of the – economically defined – public interest is brilliantly rational. After all, economics is originally the science of the intelligent use of resources. Unfortunately, economics jargon is far too often abused for non-sense rhetoric with the intention of making political cases seem irrefutable. Citizens then become customers, public administrations are turned into management agencies, and matters of public interest are reduced to objects of narrow-minded bean-counting. This is not so in the case of Global Public Goods. Here <u><mark>we are dealing with </mark>correctly defined <mark>issues of humankind’s</mark> welfare and <mark>survival</mark>. </u>The very fact that the concept has not yet been made operational in political terms makes the debate about Global Public Goods all the more relevant. <u>The converging global society must meet enormous challenges – and that implies that <mark>governments have to pursue </mark>strategies of <mark>cross-border cooperation</u><strong></mark>. It may be impossible to check what happens with every single German tax euro in a multilateral policy context and, indeed, the negotiations are prone to be more complicated and time-consuming than in the case of bilateral agreements</h4><p>Science diplomacy high now </p><p>French Ministry of Global Affairs 13 </strong>http://www.france-science.org/IMG/pdf/science-diplomacy-for-france-2013.pdf, “Science Diplomacy for France, 2013, French Ministry of Global Affairs</p><p>France, who for many decades has viewed scientific cooperation as contributing to the ¶ dialogue between peoples and a means of developing and strengthening national excellence, ¶ sees her approach bolstered by the emergence of the<u> “<mark>science diplomacy</mark>” concept</u>. Developed in ¶ the United States and widely disseminated in the English-speaking world, <u>it has been defined as ¶ “the use and application of science cooperation to help build bridges and enhance relationships ¶ between and amongst societies, with a particular interest in working in areas where there might ¶ not be other mechanisms for engagement at an official level.”1¶ <mark>In the U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates, <mark>this policy</mark> ¶ shift <mark>has been reflected</mark> notably <mark>by the appointment of science envoys</u></mark> tasked with <u><mark>resuming a ¶ dialogue with</u></mark> the elites in the Muslim world (<u><mark>Middle East, Africa, and </u></mark>South-East<u><mark> Asia</u></mark>) <u><mark>and offering </u></mark>¶ them <u><mark>opportunities</u><strong></mark> 2. </p><p></strong>Networks and funding now</p><p><strong>Colglazier </strong>and Lyons<strong> 14</strong> – E. William Colglazier is the science and technology adviser to the U.S. secretary of state. Elizabeth E. Lyons is a senior adviser in the U.S. Department of State’s Office of the Science and Technology Adviser and its Bureau of Oceans and International Environmental and Scientific Affairs. She is on detail with support from the National Science Foundation to the Department of State. (E. William, Elizabeth E., 2014, “The United States Looks to the Global Science, Technology, and Innovation Horizon”, Science and Diplomacy, http://www.sciencediplomacy.org/perspective/2014/united-states-looks-global-science-technology-and-innovation-horizon)//sb</p><p>Looking around: <u><mark>The new global landscape of science is</mark> more distributed and <mark>networked</u></mark>—t<u>he United States needs to look around at such linkages</u>. Many <u>scientific</u> <u>advances</u> are now p<u>ropelled not just by individuals</u> working within individual labs, <u>but increasingly by overlapping, fluid, </u>and largely self-organizing <u><strong>networks of scientists</u></strong>, engineers, technologists, and entrepreneurs. <u><strong>These networks frequently extend across and beyond research intensive institutions</u></strong>. <u><mark>Networks of scientists are already being supported</mark>, </u>for example, <u><mark>by t</mark>he</u> National Science Foundation (<u><mark>NSF</u></mark>) Research Coordination Networks <u><mark>and</mark> through</u> initiatives such as the Higher Education Solutions Network (<u><mark>HESN)</u> <u>undertaken</u> <u>by</u></mark> the U.S. Agency for International Development (<u><mark>USAID</u></mark>). <u><strong><mark>HESN is building diverse</u></strong></mark>, often <u><strong><mark>international, teams to tackle significant development challenge</mark>s,</u></strong> <strong>making more information on development projects available domestically and internationally, and tying together people and results for stronger impact.</p><p>biotech inevitable globally and solves all their impacts</p><p>Their Author NAS 8</strong> <strong>(National Academy of Sciences, “The Role of the Life Sciences in Transforming America's Future Summary of a Workshop” December 3, 2008, Board on Life Sciences Division on Earth and Life Studies, National Research Council) </strong>//trepka</p><p>The Promise of the Biological Sciences <u><mark>Investments in the life sciences pay off in</mark> three broad areas, observe</u>d Massachusetts Institute of Technology (<u>MIT</u>) <u>President</u> Susan <u>Hockfield. They improve <mark>human <strong>health</strong>.</mark> They foster <strong><mark>industries</u></strong></mark> that boost the economy while <u>addressing a wide range of</u> environmental, energy, health, and agricultural <u>challenges. <mark>And</mark> they further <mark>human understanding of</u></mark> some of the most fascinating <u><strong><mark>systems</u></strong></mark> in the universe. ¶ Improving Human Health ¶ The biological sciences have enabled most of the world’s population to enjoy higher living standards and longer life spans than ever before, said National Academies President Ralph Cicerone. New understanding of the links between disease and sanitation, the role trace nutrients play in health, and the potential of vaccines and antibiotics, among many other research results, have improved the lives of people everywhere. The progress made in combating heart disease is a prime example of the payoffs from investment in the life sciences, said Hockfield. Over the past 30 years, the National Institutes of Health (<u><mark>NIH</mark>) has <mark>invested</mark> about $4 per American per year <mark>in cardiovascular research. That</mark> investment has <mark>helped reduce the rate of death from heart disease</mark> and stroke <mark>by</mark> more than <mark>half</u></mark>. Knowledge of cholesterol metabolism led to the development of the drugs known as statins, which have reduced heart attacks and strokes. The development of drug-eluting stents has enabled physicians to open occluded blood vessels. Study of receptors on the surface of nerve cells has led to new beta blockers that are being used to treat hypertension and heart disease. <u><mark>Similar advances </mark>have <mark>produced benefits <strong>throughout medicine</u></strong></mark>, observed Thomas Cech, President of the Howard Hughes Medical Institute, and Harold Varmus, President of the Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center. <u>Greater understanding of the role of tumor necrosis factor in inflammatory disease has led to antibody treatments</u> that have changed the lives of many people with rheumatoid arthritis. Materials science is producing spare parts for bones, arteries, and other tissues and organs. Basic research into retroviruses motivated by their role in some cancers built the base of understanding that proved critical in first identifying the cause of the AIDS epidemic and then developing drugs to control the disease. “<u><mark>If we as a country hadn’t made</mark> the <mark>investment in</mark> the <mark>basic science</mark>, in the understanding of retroviruses, <mark>we would</mark> probably <mark>still</mark> today <mark>have</mark> a rapidly <mark>expanding</mark> global <mark>AIDS</mark> epidemic</u>,” Cech said. <u><strong><mark>Continued basic research</strong></mark> into fundamental biological processes <mark>could yield</mark> a wealth of <mark>new</mark> medical <mark>advances</u></mark>. ¶ Investigations of bacterial genetics could provide new treatments for infectious diseases, including diseases caused by microbes that have evolved mechanisms to evade existing treatments. Bioengineered stem cells could provide regulated insulin secretion in people with diabetes, for example, or repair severed spinal cord nerves. Study of chronic diseases such as cancer, heart disease, and mental illness, which now account for the bulk ¶ 3 of health care costs, could lead to personalized treatments that reflect a disease’s unique characteristics in each individual. However, the translation of basic research findings to applications is not always straightforward or quick, Cech observed. Even where understanding of biological processes is extensive, vast amounts of work must be done, often by people in different disciplines and sectors working collaboratively, to apply new knowledge in medicine. The life sciences have applications in areas that range far beyond human health. Life-science based approaches could contribute to advances in many industries, from energy production and pollution remediation, to clean manufacturing and the production of new biologically inspired materials. In fact, biological systems could provide the basis for new products, services and industries that we cannot yet imagine. Microbes are already producing biofuels and could, through further research, provide a major component of future energy supplies. Marine and terrestrial organisms extract carbon dioxide from the atmosphere, which suggests that biological systems could be used to help manage climate change. Study of the complex systems encountered in biology is ¶ producing insights into similarly interconnected networks encountered in many other areas of science – and vice versa. Take agriculture as an example. The agricultural biotechnology industry is just a little more than a decade old, said Robert Fraley, Executive Vice President and Chief Technology Officer at Monsanto – the first bioengineered crop, a soybean seed with a gene providing tolerance for a common herbicide, was launched in 1996. <u>Yet <mark>biotech</u></mark>nology<u><mark> crops are</mark> today being </u>planted<u><mark> on 20 percent of </u></mark>the world’s farmland,<u><mark> and</mark> the percentage is <strong><mark>projected to double </strong>as <strong>new</mark> crops are introduced and <mark>countries like India and China move toward full adoption</mark> </strong>of the technology</u>. “<u>This is the most rapidly adopted new technology in the history of agriculture</u>,” Fraley said. The ability to introduce multiple genes into an ever-expanding array of crops has not only increased yields but has produced significant environmental benefits. By altering the characteristics of crops, agricultural biotechnology has made it possible for farmers to use fewer pesticides and other chemicals. Fewer trips through the fields on tractors mean less greenhouse gas emissions and reduced compaction of soils. Furthermore, the revolution in agricultural biotechnology has just begun, Fraley said. Within a few years, agricultural companies will be selling seeds with ten or more introduced genes. Crops can be modified to improve human health; for example, soybeans have been genetically modified to produce healthy rather than unhealthy fatty acids. Future crops will need far less water, a crucial consideration as climate change alters rainfall patterns and groundwater aquifers are depleted. As Fraley said, “As much as we have seen happen in the last decade<u>, it is really just the beginning.” </u>The <u>life sciences</u> can <u>answer</u> some of the most <u>fundamental</u>, interesting, and difficult <u>questions</u> that human beings can ask. How did the great diversity of living things come to be? How do cells function on a molecular level? What is the role of life in changing the surface of the earth? Consider this last question, said James Collins, who is currently on leave from Arizona State University to serve as Assistant Director for Biological Sciences at the National Science Foundation. According to a recent estimate, of the approximately 4,300 types of minerals on the earth, about 3,000 are the products of biological processes. The evolution of life “put earth under new management,” Collins said. Understanding the future state of the planet will require understanding the biological systems that have shaped the planet. Many of these <u>biological systems are found in the oceans,</u> which cover 70 percent of the earth’s surface and have a crucial impact on weather, climate, and the composition of the atmosphere. In the past decade, <u><strong><mark>new tools</strong> have become available to explore </u></mark>the microbial processes that drive the chemistry of<u> <strong><mark>the oceans</u></strong></mark>, observed David Kingsbury, Chief Program Officer for Science at the Gordon and Betty Moore Foundation. <u>These technologies have revealed</u> that a large proportion of the planet’s genetic diversity resides in <u>the oceans</u>. In addition, many organisms in the oceans readily exchange genes, creating evolutionary forces that can have global effects. The oceans are currently under great stress, Kingsbury pointed out. Nutrient runoff from agriculture is helping to create huge and expanding “dead zones” where oxygen levels are too low to sustain life. Toxic algal blooms are occurring with higher frequency in areas where they have not been seen in the past. Exploitation of ocean resources is disrupting ecological balances that have formed over many millions of years. Human-induced changes in the chemistry of the atmosphere are changing the chemistry of the oceans, with potentially catastrophic consequences. “If we are not careful, we are not going to have a sustainable planet to live on,” said Kingsbury. Only by understanding the basic biological processes at work in the oceans can humans live sustainably on earth.<strong> </p></strong>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
48,764
331
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,028
US support for a first strike increases Israeli aggression exponentially. Absent US support, Israel won’t risk attack
Giraldi 12
Giraldi 12 Philip, executive director, Council for the National Interest; former CIA officer; PhD, European History, University of London; “Entangled With Israel” The American Conservative; September 3, 2012; http://www.theamericanconservative.com/articles/entangled-with-israel/
Israel’s attempt to steer American foreign policy has been nowhere more evident than in the sustained campaign to move the U S in the direction of war with Iran, Israel is essentially demanding a commitment from Washington to attack Iran unless the issue of Iran’s ability to enrich uranium is resolved through negotiation or through Iranian surrender of that right Israel knows it cannot successfully attack Iran unilaterally and must have the United States along to do the heavy lifting. . If Israel obtains a virtual commitment from the United States to go to w it would mean enjoying the benefits of having a powerful patron to do its fighting without any obligation in return A guarantee from Washington for Israel’s security which still permits unilateral action by Netanyahu is reminiscent of the entangling arrangements that led to World War I. If the United States commits to unconditional support for an Israeli attack on Iran, it will be a surrender of one of the defining attributes of national sovereignty: the power to choose when and where to go to war A guarantee precludes any consideration that the United States might actually have an overriding national interest to avoid a war. It denies that the United States should be able to exercise complete sovereignty over the issue of Iran, and it also freezes the status quo, as if new ways of looking at the problem of the Iranian nuclear program could not evolve over the next few months. Washington should make no commitment to anyone about what it will do vis-à-vis Iran We have no eternal allies, and we have no perpetual enemies. Our interests are eternal and perpetual, and those interests it is our duty to follow
Israel’s attempt to steer American foreign policy has been evident in the sustained campaign to move the U S the direction of war with Iran Israel is demanding a commitment from Washington to attack Israel knows it cannot successfully attack Iran unilaterally and must have the U S to do the heavy lifting. If Israel obtains a commitment from the U S to go to war it would mean enjoying the benefits of a powerful patron to fight without any obligation in return A guarantee is reminiscent of the entangling arrangements that led to World War I.
Israel’s attempt to steer American foreign policy has been nowhere more evident than in the sustained campaign to move the United States in the direction of war with Iran,a war that serves no American interest unless one believes that Tehran is willing to spend billions of dollars to develop a nuclear weapon only to hand off the result to a terrorist group. The most recent overtures by the Israeli government have pushed the United States to make a declaration that negotiations with Iran have failed and will not be continued. For Israel, this is a necessary first step towards an American military intervention, as failed negotiations mean there is no way out of the impasse but by war, if the Iranians do not unilaterally concede on every disputed point. Two recent op-eds have elaborated the argument, promoting the necessity of convincing the Israelis that the United States is absolutely serious about using military force against Iran if the Iranians seek to retain any capacity to enrich uranium. One might note in passing that this new red line, sometimes also called the abstract “capability” to create a nuclear weapon, has been achieved by moving the goal posts back considerably. At one time Iran was threatened with a military response if it actually acquired a nuclear weapon (which is still the official position of the Obama administration), but earlier benchmarks within that policy saying that enrichment should not exceed 20 percent or that the enrichment should not take place on Iranian soil have been abandoned in favor of what now amounts to zero tolerance. Those who note that Iran, which is a signatory to the Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty and is under IAEA inspection, has a clear legal right to enrich uranium for peaceful purposes have been ignored in favor of those who believe that Iran is somehow a special case. On August 17, the Washington Post and The New York Times featured op-eds explaining why the United States must do more to convince Israel not to attack Iran this year. Amos Yadlin, a former head of Israel’s military intelligence who is believed to be close to the country’s political leadership, argued in the Post that Obama must basically convince the Israelis that he will use force against Iran if sanctions do not convince the country’s leadership to abandon enrichment of nuclear fuel. Over at the Times, Dennis Ross, a former senior U.S. diplomat who has been described as Israel’s lawyer, made pretty much the same arguments. Both advocated giving Israel refueling tankers and special munitions that would enable an attack on Iran to be more effective, thereby widening the window of opportunity for sanctions to work, in light of Israeli arguments that hardened Iranian sites might soon be invulnerable to attack. Ross advocates giving Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu effectively a blank check, asking him what he will need to attack Iran and granting the Israeli government commitments for a full range of U.S. military support. Both Yadlin and Ross argue that it is necessary to create the conditions for Israel to delay a possible attack until 2013. As Yadlin puts it, “if the United States wants Israel to give sanctions and diplomacy more time, Israelis must know that they will not be left high and dry if these options fail.” Assuming that Ross and Yadlin are speaking for the Israeli government, which is almost certainly the case, Israel is essentially demanding a commitment from Washington to attack Iran unless the issue of Iran’s ability to enrich uranium is resolved through negotiation or through Iranian surrender of that right. In return, Israel will not attack Iran before the American election. So in effect, Washington would be promising to fight a war later if Israel does not start one now. Israel knows it cannot successfully attack Iran unilaterally and must have the United States along to do the heavy lifting. It also knows that the threat to attack Iran before the election is a powerful weapon, with neither Mitt Romney nor Barack Obama welcoming such a potentially game-changing diversion from their debate on the economy and jobs. Critics like Arnaud de Borchgrave have correctly noted that many former generals and intelligence officers in the United States and Israel have, in fact, decided that the basic premise is wrong. Iran does not pose a threat that could not be contained even if it does some day make the political decision to obtain a crude nuclear device. Launching a new war in the Middle East to prevent it from doing so would create “mayhem” throughout the region, guarantee a breakdown in Egypt-Israel relations, and create a perfect breeding ground for the civil war in Syria to spill out and lead to turmoil among all of its neighbors. American ships in the Persian Gulf would be attacked, unrest in Bahrain would turn to revolution, and the Palestinians would stage a new intifada. Israel would be bombarded from Lebanon and from Iran. Gas prices would soar, economic recovery would stall worldwide, and European nations now struggling to deal with unprecedented unemployment levels would watch the eurozone collapse before the rage of hundreds of thousands protesters in the streets. Americans would again become the targets of international terrorism. And there is another serious objection to going along with the Israeli government’s thinking. Israel is by its own volition not an ally of the United States in any technical sense because alliances are troublesome things that require rules of engagement and reciprocity, limiting the partners’ ability to act independently. If Israel obtains a virtual commitment from the United States to go to war in 2013, it would mean enjoying the benefits of having a powerful patron to do its fighting without any obligation in return, beyond delaying unilateral military action until a more suitable time. A guarantee from Washington for Israel’s security which still permits unilateral action by Netanyahu is all too reminiscent of the entangling arrangements that led to World War I. The fact that the murder of an Austrian Archduke in the Balkans led to a world war that killed tens of millions was due to promises not unlike what Israel is demanding today. If the United States commits to unconditional support for an Israeli attack on Iran, it will be a surrender of one of the defining attributes of national sovereignty: the power to choose when and where to go to war. Amos Yadlin suggests at one point that President Obama go to Congress and get approval in advance to take military action “to prevent Iran’s acquisition of a military nuclear capability.” Such a pre-approval for war certainly raises constitutional issues, but it also creates a virtual casus belli because Iran already has the “capability” to enrich uranium for potential military uses. A guarantee precludes any consideration that the United States might actually have an overriding national interest to avoid a war. It denies that the United States should be able to exercise complete sovereignty over the issue of Iran, and it also freezes the status quo, as if new ways of looking at the problem of the Iranian nuclear program could not evolve over the next few months. Washington should make no commitment to anyone about what it will do vis-à-vis Iran in 2013 no matter what inducements are offered. As the 19th-century British Prime Minister Lord Palmerston put it, “We have no eternal allies, and we have no perpetual enemies. Our interests are eternal and perpetual, and those interests it is our duty to follow.” Let America’s actual interests dictate U.S. foreign policy.
7,624
<h4><strong>US support for a first strike increases Israeli aggression exponentially. Absent US support, Israel won’t risk attack</h4><p>Giraldi 12 <u></strong>Philip, executive director, Council for the National Interest; former CIA officer; PhD, European History, University of London; “Entangled With Israel” The American Conservative; September 3, 2012; http://www.theamericanconservative.com/articles/entangled-with-israel/</p><p><mark>Israel’s attempt to steer American foreign policy has been</mark> nowhere more <mark>evident</mark> than <mark>in the sustained campaign to move the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u>in <mark>the direction of war with Iran</mark>,</u>a war that serves no American interest unless one believes that Tehran is willing to spend billions of dollars to develop a nuclear weapon only to hand off the result to a terrorist group. The most recent overtures by the Israeli government have pushed the United States to make a declaration that negotiations with Iran have failed and will not be continued. For Israel, this is a necessary first step towards an American military intervention, as failed negotiations mean there is no way out of the impasse but by war, if the Iranians do not unilaterally concede on every disputed point. Two recent op-eds have elaborated the argument, promoting the necessity of convincing the Israelis that the United States is absolutely serious about using military force against Iran if the Iranians seek to retain any capacity to enrich uranium. One might note in passing that this new red line, sometimes also called the abstract “capability” to create a nuclear weapon, has been achieved by moving the goal posts back considerably. At one time Iran was threatened with a military response if it actually acquired a nuclear weapon (which is still the official position of the Obama administration), but earlier benchmarks within that policy saying that enrichment should not exceed 20 percent or that the enrichment should not take place on Iranian soil have been abandoned in favor of what now amounts to zero tolerance. Those who note that Iran, which is a signatory to the Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty and is under IAEA inspection, has a clear legal right to enrich uranium for peaceful purposes have been ignored in favor of those who believe that Iran is somehow a special case. On August 17, the Washington Post and The New York Times featured op-eds explaining why the United States must do more to convince Israel not to attack Iran this year. Amos Yadlin, a former head of Israel’s military intelligence who is believed to be close to the country’s political leadership, argued in the Post that Obama must basically convince the Israelis that he will use force against Iran if sanctions do not convince the country’s leadership to abandon enrichment of nuclear fuel. Over at the Times, Dennis Ross, a former senior U.S. diplomat who has been described as Israel’s lawyer, made pretty much the same arguments. Both advocated giving Israel refueling tankers and special munitions that would enable an attack on Iran to be more effective, thereby widening the window of opportunity for sanctions to work, in light of Israeli arguments that hardened Iranian sites might soon be invulnerable to attack. Ross advocates giving Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu effectively a blank check, asking him what he will need to attack Iran and granting the Israeli government commitments for a full range of U.S. military support. Both Yadlin and Ross argue that it is necessary to create the conditions for Israel to delay a possible attack until 2013. As Yadlin puts it, “if the United States wants Israel to give sanctions and diplomacy more time, Israelis must know that they will not be left high and dry if these options fail.” Assuming that Ross and Yadlin are speaking for the Israeli government, which is almost certainly the case, <u><mark>Israel is</mark> essentially <mark>demanding a commitment from Washington to attack</mark> Iran unless the issue of Iran’s ability to enrich uranium is resolved through negotiation or through Iranian surrender of that right</u>. In return, Israel will not attack Iran before the American election. So in effect, Washington would be promising to fight a war later if Israel does not start one now. <u><mark>Israel knows it cannot successfully attack Iran unilaterally and must have the U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates along <mark>to do the heavy lifting. </u></mark>It also knows that the threat to attack Iran before the election is a powerful weapon, with neither Mitt Romney nor Barack Obama welcoming such a potentially game-changing diversion from their debate on the economy and jobs. Critics like Arnaud de Borchgrave have correctly noted that many former generals and intelligence officers in the United States and Israel have, in fact, decided that the basic premise is wrong. Iran does not pose a threat that could not be contained even if it does some day make the political decision to obtain a crude nuclear device. Launching a new war in the Middle East to prevent it from doing so would create “mayhem” throughout the region, guarantee a breakdown in Egypt-Israel relations, and create a perfect breeding ground for the civil war in Syria to spill out and lead to turmoil among all of its neighbors. American ships in the Persian Gulf would be attacked, unrest in Bahrain would turn to revolution, and the Palestinians would stage a new intifada. Israel would be bombarded from Lebanon and from Iran. Gas prices would soar, economic recovery would stall worldwide, and European nations now struggling to deal with unprecedented unemployment levels would watch the eurozone collapse before the rage of hundreds of thousands protesters in the streets. Americans would again become the targets of international terrorism. And there is another serious objection to going along with the Israeli government’s thinking. Israel is by its own volition not an ally of the United States in any technical sense because alliances are troublesome things that require rules of engagement and reciprocity, limiting the partners’ ability to act independently<u>. <mark>If Israel obtains a</mark> virtual <mark>commitment from the U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates <mark>to go to w</u>ar</mark> in 2013, <u><mark>it would mean enjoying the benefits of</mark> having <mark>a powerful patron</mark> <mark>to</mark> do its <mark>fight</mark>ing <mark>without any obligation in return</u></mark>, beyond delaying unilateral military action until a more suitable time. <u><mark>A guarantee</mark> from Washington for Israel’s security which still permits unilateral action by Netanyahu <mark>is</u></mark> all too <u><mark>reminiscent</u> <u>of the entangling arrangements that led to World War I.</u></mark> The fact that the murder of an Austrian Archduke in the Balkans led to a world war that killed tens of millions was due to promises not unlike what Israel is demanding today. <u>If the United States commits to unconditional support for an Israeli attack on Iran, it will be a surrender of one of the defining attributes of national sovereignty: the power to choose when and where to go to war</u>. Amos Yadlin suggests at one point that President Obama go to Congress and get approval in advance to take military action “to prevent Iran’s acquisition of a military nuclear capability.” Such a pre-approval for war certainly raises constitutional issues, but it also creates a virtual casus belli because Iran already has the “capability” to enrich uranium for potential military uses. <u>A guarantee precludes any consideration that the United States might actually have an overriding national interest to avoid a war.</u> <u>It denies that the United States should be able to exercise complete sovereignty over the issue of Iran, and it also freezes the status quo, as if new ways of looking at the problem of the Iranian nuclear program could not evolve over the next few months.</u> <u>Washington should make no commitment to anyone about what it will do vis-à-vis Iran</u> in 2013 no matter what inducements are offered. As the 19th-century British Prime Minister Lord Palmerston put it, “<u>We have no eternal allies, and we have no perpetual enemies. Our interests are eternal and perpetual, and those interests it is our duty to follow</u>.” Let America’s actual interests dictate U.S. foreign policy.</p>
1NR
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
430,538
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,029
4—Framing determines policy effectiveness --- 90% of policy errors emerge from the flawed and deterministic lens of security.
Lowth 2011
Lowth 2011
A frame is ‘a perspective from which a problematic situation can be made sense of’ Framing shapes perceptions, and influences thinking and behaviour The re-framing of issues is also potentially transformative.6 Much mistaken thinking and associated flawed behaviour is attributed, with authority, to mis-perception: ‘Around 90% of errors in thinking ... arise from errors of perception The ways in which problems are articulated and interpreted, in terms of their essential ‘form or origin’, fundamentally affects the strategies developed to resolve them The process of framing influences strategic thinking because it shapes a priori understanding, organisation and explanation: ‘Problems arise as much from the meaning that people involved give them as from the facts of the situation’ The language of security is similarly evocative, partial and inherently political The theory of securitization within international relations – the use of the term ‘security’ to elevate an issue above and beyond normal politics – is remarkably similar to that of framing: The distinguishing feature of securitization is a specific rhetorical structure ... the staging of existential issues as of supreme priority Both the generic process of framing and the specific example of securitization: ‘construct discourses through which the world comes to be perceived’ Starting from the premise that: ‘By saying the word [security], something is done this matters A conscious process of de-securitization can re-frame thinking (with potentially beneficial results). The increasing breadth of affairs portrayed as ‘security issues’ – food, water, the environment, as well as energy – makes it imperative, in an ‘era of security obsessionism’ for policy makers and strategists to appreciate the cognitive influence of securitization Designating an issue as a matter of security is not just a theoretical question but caries ‘real-world’ significance
Framing shapes perceptions, and influences thinking and behaviour The re-framing of issues is transformative Much mistaken thinking is attributed to mis-perception: ‘Around 90% of errors in thinking arise from errors of perception A conscious process of de-securitization can re-frame thinking The increasing breadth of affairs portrayed as ‘security issues’ an ‘era of security obsessionism’ for policy makers and strategists Designating an issue as a matter of security caries ‘real-world’ significance’
Colonel R. G., British Army, ‘Securitization’ and its effect on Strategic Thinking, SEAFORD HOUSE PAPER, Royal Defense Studies A frame is ‘a perspective from which a problematic situation can be made sense of’.4 Framing sets a particular context. It shapes perceptions, and influences thinking and behaviour (Haider-Markel et al, 2006; Bradley, 2011).5 The re-framing of issues (ie. ‘reinterpreting their meaning and re-perceiving the situation’ (ibid)) is also potentially transformative.6 Much mistaken thinking and associated flawed behaviour is attributed, with authority, to mis-perception: ‘Around 90% of errors in thinking ... arise from errors of perception (Carr, 2010:5).7 Indeed some afford perceptions not just a primary but an exclusive explanatory role: ‘Perception is all there is’ (Peters and Austin, 1994:71). The ways in which problems are articulated and interpreted, in terms of their essential ‘form or origin’, fundamentally affects the strategies developed to resolve them (Goffman, 1986:10). The process of framing influences strategic thinking because it shapes a priori understanding, organisation and explanation: ‘Problems arise as much from the meaning that people involved give them as from the facts of the situation’ (Martin, 2002:28). Framed thinking is inherently convergent, focused and directed as if by a lens, but the process is neither objective nor universal; it varies between individuals and communities, and alters over time. Framing involves (re)definition. Words are critical and their impact, albeit invariably subconscious, can be profound: ‘There is nothing outside the text’ (Derrida, 1976:158). The cognitive linguist George Lakoff challenged his students not to think of an elephant – but none could avoid doing so. The word alone created an irresistible frame: Every word, like elephant, evokes a frame, which can be an image or other kinds of knowledge ... the word is defined relative to that frame (Lakoff, 2004:3). Framing is more than just associative, however; it also tends to be partial: When the word tax is added to relief, the result is a metaphor: Taxation is an affliction, the person who takes it away is a hero, and anyone who tries to stop him is a bad guy. This is a frame ... made up of ideas, like affliction and hero (ibid). Moreover, framing – as a form of linguistic construction – can be purposefully partial: Framing is about language that fits your worldview, [but] it is not just language. Ideas are primary — and the language carries those ideas, evokes those ideas (ibid). The language of security is similarly evocative, partial and inherently political. The theory of securitization within international relations – the use of the term ‘security’ to elevate an issue above and beyond normal politics – is remarkably similar to that of framing: The distinguishing feature of securitization is a specific rhetorical structure ... the staging of existential issues as of supreme priority. The process ... a speech-act ... causes the actor to operate in a different mode than he would have otherwise (Buzan et al, 1998:26,30). Both the generic process of framing and the specific example of securitization: ‘construct discourses through which the world comes to be perceived’ (Henry, 2002:68). They are both potentially powerful forms of sense-making. And yet, curiously, the two are seldom connected explicitly.8 Debates about securitisation are conducted within the milieu of security studies; they tend to focus on how issues become characterised as threats, rather than on the ramifications. Those concerned about framing, on the other hand, operating principally within psychology and its fields of application (behavioural sciences, sociology, media studies etc) tend to address much more keenly the cognitive implications, especially the creation of alternative world views, the colouring of perceptions, and associated influences on decision-making. This paper draws upon both fields of research to explore the framing effect of securitization on strategic thinking.9 Starting from the premise that: ‘By saying the word [security], something is done’ (Wæver, 1995:55), it is argued that: − (A part of) what securitization – as a form of discourse – ‘does’, is frame − In the context of strategy, this matters (so strategists should be aware). thinking. − A conscious process of de-securitization can re-frame thinking (with potentially beneficial results). The increasing breadth of affairs portrayed as ‘security issues’ – food, water, the environment, as well as energy – makes it imperative, in an ‘era of security obsessionism’ (Charrett, 2009:11), for policy makers and strategists to appreciate the cognitive influence of securitization. However, while both framing and securitization are periodically characterised as negative, this dissertation makes no such judgment – either in general, or in relation to European energy supply. The intention here is to demonstrate instead that securitization does frame strategic thinking, and that this matters: ‘Designating an issue as a matter of security is not just a theoretical question but caries ‘real-world’ significance’ (Hough, 2004:14).
5,180
<h4><strong>4—<u>Framing determines policy effectiveness</u> --- 90% of policy errors emerge from the flawed and deterministic lens of security. </h4><p>Lowth 2011</p><p></strong>Colonel R. G., British Army, ‘Securitization’ and its effect on Strategic Thinking, SEAFORD HOUSE PAPER, Royal Defense Studies</p><p><u>A frame is ‘a perspective from which a problematic situation can be made sense of’</u>.4 <u><mark>Framing</u></mark> sets a particular context. It <u><mark>shapes perceptions, and influences thinking and behaviour</u></mark> (Haider-Markel et al, 2006; Bradley, 2011).5 <u><mark>The re-framing of issues</u></mark> (ie. ‘reinterpreting their meaning and re-perceiving the situation’ (ibid)) <u><mark>is</mark> also potentially <mark>transformative</mark>.6 <mark>Much mistaken thinking</mark> and associated flawed behaviour <mark>is attributed</mark>, with authority, <mark>to mis-perception: ‘Around 90% of errors in thinking</mark> ... <mark>arise from errors of perception</u></mark> (Carr, 2010:5).7 Indeed some afford perceptions not just a primary but an exclusive explanatory role: ‘Perception is all there is’ (Peters and Austin, 1994:71). <u>The ways in which problems are articulated and interpreted, in terms of their essential ‘form or origin’, fundamentally affects the strategies developed to resolve them</u> (Goffman, 1986:10). <u>The process of framing influences strategic thinking because it shapes a priori understanding, organisation and explanation: ‘Problems arise as much from the meaning that people involved give them as from the facts of the situation’</u> (Martin, 2002:28). Framed thinking is inherently convergent, focused and directed as if by a lens, but the process is neither objective nor universal; it varies between individuals and communities, and alters over time. Framing involves (re)definition. Words are critical and their impact, albeit invariably subconscious, can be profound: ‘There is nothing outside the text’ (Derrida, 1976:158). The cognitive linguist George Lakoff challenged his students not to think of an elephant – but none could avoid doing so. The word alone created an irresistible frame: Every word, like elephant, evokes a frame, which can be an image or other kinds of knowledge ... the word is defined relative to that frame (Lakoff, 2004:3). Framing is more than just associative, however; it also tends to be partial: When the word tax is added to relief, the result is a metaphor: Taxation is an affliction, the person who takes it away is a hero, and anyone who tries to stop him is a bad guy. This is a frame ... made up of ideas, like affliction and hero (ibid). Moreover, framing – as a form of linguistic construction – can be purposefully partial: Framing is about language that fits your worldview, [but] it is not just language. Ideas are primary — and the language carries those ideas, evokes those ideas (ibid). <u>The language of security is similarly evocative, partial and inherently political</u>. <u>The theory of securitization within international relations – the use of the term ‘security’ to elevate an issue above and beyond normal politics – is remarkably similar to that of framing: The distinguishing feature of securitization is a specific rhetorical structure ... the staging of existential issues as of supreme priority</u>. The process ... a speech-act ... causes the actor to operate in a different mode than he would have otherwise (Buzan et al, 1998:26,30). <u>Both the generic process of framing and the specific example of securitization: ‘construct discourses through which the world comes to be perceived’</u> (Henry, 2002:68). They are both potentially powerful forms of sense-making. And yet, curiously, the two are seldom connected explicitly.8 Debates about securitisation are conducted within the milieu of security studies; they tend to focus on how issues become characterised as threats, rather than on the ramifications. Those concerned about framing, on the other hand, operating principally within psychology and its fields of application (behavioural sciences, sociology, media studies etc) tend to address much more keenly the cognitive implications, especially the creation of alternative world views, the colouring of perceptions, and associated influences on decision-making. This paper draws upon both fields of research to explore the framing effect of securitization on strategic thinking.9 <u>Starting from the premise that: ‘By saying the word [security], something is done</u>’ (Wæver, 1995:55), it is argued that: − (A part of) what securitization – as a form of discourse – ‘does’, is frame − In the context of strategy, <u>this matters</u> (so strategists should be aware). thinking. − <u><mark>A conscious process of de-securitization can re-frame thinking</mark> (with potentially beneficial results). <mark>The increasing breadth of</mark> <mark>affairs portrayed as ‘security issues’</mark> – food, water, the environment, as well as energy – makes it imperative, in <mark>an ‘era of security obsessionism’</u></mark> (Charrett, 2009:11), <u><mark>for</mark> <mark>policy makers and strategists</mark> to appreciate the cognitive influence of securitization</u>. However, while both framing and securitization are periodically characterised as negative, this dissertation makes no such judgment – either in general, or in relation to European energy supply. The intention here is to demonstrate instead that securitization does frame strategic thinking, and that this matters: ‘<u><mark>Designating an issue as a matter of security </mark>is not just a theoretical question but <mark>caries ‘real-world’ significance</u>’</mark> (Hough, 2004:14).</p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
430,539
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,030
Israel won’t attack without US support – extremely sensitive to US concerns
Zanotti et al 12
Zanotti et al 12 (Jim Zanotti, Coordinator Specialist in Middle Eastern Affairs. Israel: Possible Military Strike Against Iran’s Nuclear Facilities. CRS. http://www.fas.org/sgp/crs/mideast/R42443.pdf)
policymakers in the Obama Administration and Congress regarding an attack. Not surprisingly, Israeli leaders are extremely sensitive to U.S. views for a variety of reasons, including but not limited to: • Strong U.S.-Israel relations dating back to when the United States was the first country to recognize Israel upon its declaration of statehood in May 1948; • Robust ongoing military and security cooperation, including significant U.S. arms sales and other forms of support; and • Trade ties and important bilateral economic and scientific cooperation.141 Israeli leaders’ perspectives about the possible effects of a strike on U.S. political and material assistance , possible negative security consequences for the United States from a potential Iranian retaliation, and the probability of future U.S. military action to prevent a nuclear-armed Iran may, among other considerations, influence the Israeli decisionmaking process An Israeli journalist wrote in March 2012 that Israel did not ask permission when it acted to prevent Saddam Hussein and Bashar al Asad from obtaining nuclear weapons, but that “the [Obama] administration can credibly counter that in neither case did Israeli unilateralism threaten to draw America into an armed conflict, as it does now.”142 According to three Israeli analysts (including two former officials) mentioned above: Even after the withdrawal of its troops from Iraq, the U.S. remains extremely exposed to Iranian retaliation—either directly against its forces in the area or by Iran’s attempting to ignite a broader conflict in the region—so an Israeli strike would harm U.S. interests in the region and would place many U.S. lives at risk. And while in an election year America’s political reaction to such a strike may be mitigated by domestic political considerations, the reaction of the U.S. defense community to an Israeli military strike might be extremely negative, as such an action might be seen as representing Israeli insensitivity to and disregard of U.S. priorities and concerns.143 Some reports have speculated that an Israeli decision to attack, if it occurs, could come before the U.S. presidential election in November 2012, with one Israeli report stating, “A second-term president, not constrained by electoral necessities, will be able to apply a lot more pressure on the Israeli government not to attack.”144 Separate from the question of whether the United States might support an Israeli strike on Iran, Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by how they anticipate the United States would respond after an attack, including in the event of retaliation by Iran and its allies. Although the United States does not have a formal treaty obligation to defend Israel in the event it is attacked, successive Administrations have either stated or implied that the United States would act to protect Israel’s security if it were endangered—including by Iran—and have worked with Congress to ensure and bolster Israel’s “qualitative military edge” over regional security threats.145
Israeli leaders are extremely sensitive to U.S. views for a variety of reasons Strong U.S.-Israel relations Robust ongoing military and security cooperation Trade ties bilateral economic and scientific cooperation Israeli perspectives about the effects of a strike on U.S. political and material assistance possible negative security consequences the U.S. remains extremely exposed to Iranian retaliation Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by how they anticipate the U St would respond after an attack,
Despite the reference by Defense Minister Barak to the possible need for “overt or tacit support, particularly from America” before approving an Israel strike, it is unclear to what extent Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by the stated positions and anticipated responses of U.S. policymakers in the Obama Administration and Congress regarding an attack. Not surprisingly, Israeli leaders are extremely sensitive to U.S. views for a variety of reasons, including but not limited to: • Strong U.S.-Israel relations dating back to when the United States was the first country to recognize the provisional Jewish government as the de facto government of Israel upon its declaration of statehood in May 1948; • Robust ongoing military and security cooperation, including significant U.S. arms sales and other forms of support; and • Trade ties and important bilateral economic and scientific cooperation.141 Israeli leaders’ perspectives about the possible effects of a strike on U.S. political and material assistance to Israel, possible negative security consequences for the United States from a potential Iranian retaliation, and the probability of future U.S. military action to prevent a nuclear-armed Iran may, among other considerations, influence the Israeli decisionmaking process An Israeli journalist wrote in March 2012 that Israel did not ask permission when it acted to prevent Saddam Hussein and Bashar al Asad from obtaining nuclear weapons, but that “the [Obama] administration can credibly counter that in neither case did Israeli unilateralism threaten to draw America into an armed conflict, as it does now.”142 According to three Israeli analysts (including two former officials) mentioned above: Even after the withdrawal of its troops from Iraq, the U.S. remains extremely exposed to Iranian retaliation—either directly against its forces in the area or by Iran’s attempting to ignite a broader conflict in the region—so an Israeli strike would harm U.S. interests in the region and would place many U.S. lives at risk. And while in an election year America’s political reaction to such a strike may be mitigated by domestic political considerations, the reaction of the U.S. defense community to an Israeli military strike might be extremely negative, as such an action might be seen as representing Israeli insensitivity to and disregard of U.S. priorities and concerns.143 Some reports have speculated that an Israeli decision to attack, if it occurs, could come before the U.S. presidential election in November 2012, with one Israeli report stating, “A second-term president, not constrained by electoral necessities, will be able to apply a lot more pressure on the Israeli government not to attack.”144 Separate from the question of whether the United States might support an Israeli strike on Iran, Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by how they anticipate the United States would respond after an attack, including in the event of retaliation by Iran and its allies. Although the United States does not have a formal treaty obligation to defend Israel in the event it is attacked, successive Administrations have either stated or implied that the United States would act to protect Israel’s security if it were endangered—including by Iran—and have worked with Congress to ensure and bolster Israel’s “qualitative military edge” over regional security threats.145
3,525
<h4><u>Israel won’t attack without US support – extremely sensitive to US concerns</h4><p></u><strong>Zanotti et al 12<u></strong> (</u>Jim Zanotti, Coordinator Specialist in Middle Eastern Affairs. Israel: Possible Military Strike Against<u> Iran’s Nuclear Facilities. CRS. http://www.fas.org/sgp/crs/mideast/R42443.pdf)</p><p></u>Despite the reference by Defense Minister Barak to the possible need for “overt or tacit support, particularly from America” before approving an Israel strike, it is unclear to what extent Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by the stated positions and anticipated responses of U.S.<u> policymakers in the Obama Administration and Congress regarding an attack. Not surprisingly, <mark>Israeli leaders are <strong>extremely sensitive</strong> to U.S. views for a variety of reasons</mark>, including but not limited to: • <mark>Strong U.S.-Israel relations</mark> dating back to when the United States was the first country to recognize </u>the provisional Jewish government as the de facto government of <u> Israel upon its declaration of statehood in May 1948; • <strong><mark>Robust ongoing military and security cooperation</strong></mark>, including significant U.S. arms sales and other forms of support; and • <strong><mark>Trade ties</strong> </mark>and important <strong><mark>bilateral economic and scientific cooperation</strong></mark>.141 <mark>Israeli </mark>leaders’ <mark>perspectives about the </mark>possible <mark>effects of a strike on U.S. political and material assistance</mark> </u>to Israel<u>, <mark>possible negative security consequences</mark> for the United States from a potential Iranian retaliation, and the probability of future U.S. military action to prevent a nuclear-armed Iran may, among other considerations, influence the Israeli decisionmaking process An Israeli journalist wrote in March 2012 that Israel did not ask permission when it acted to prevent Saddam Hussein and Bashar al Asad from obtaining nuclear weapons, but that “the [Obama] administration can credibly counter that in neither case did Israeli unilateralism threaten to draw America into an armed conflict, as it does now.”142 According to three Israeli analysts (including two former officials) mentioned above: Even after the withdrawal of its troops from Iraq, <mark>the U.S. remains extremely exposed to Iranian retaliation</mark>—either directly against its forces in the area or by Iran’s attempting to ignite a broader conflict in the region—so an Israeli strike would harm U.S. interests in the region and would place many U.S. lives at risk. And while in an election year America’s political reaction to such a strike may be mitigated by domestic political considerations, the reaction of the U.S. defense community to an Israeli military strike might be extremely negative, as such an action might be seen as representing Israeli insensitivity to and disregard of U.S. priorities and concerns.143 Some reports have speculated that an Israeli decision to attack, if it occurs, could come before the U.S. presidential election in November 2012, with one Israeli report stating, “A second-term president, not constrained by electoral necessities, will be able to apply a lot more pressure on the Israeli government not to attack.”144 Separate from the question of whether the United States might support an Israeli strike on Iran, <mark>Israeli decisionmakers might be influenced by how they anticipate the U</mark>nited <mark>St</mark>ates <mark>would respond after an attack,</mark> including in the event of retaliation by Iran and its allies. Although the United States does not have a formal treaty obligation to defend Israel in the event it is attacked, successive Administrations have either stated or implied that the United States would act to protect Israel’s security if it were endangered—including by Iran—and have worked with Congress to ensure and bolster Israel’s “qualitative military edge” over regional security threats.145</p></u>
1NR
adv 1
AT: Solves Global Institutions
430,540
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,031
This is not just defense. Their reliance on security suffers from serial policy failure – and the attendant endless production of new threats to be countered creates an endless politics of war
09
Dillon and Reed 09 (IR professor @ Lancaster University; Lecturer @ King’s College London, “The Liberal Way of Killing: Killing to Make Live”)
The liberal way of rule and war has become the preparedness to make war on whatever threatens life’s capacity to live the emergency of its emergence societies are increasingly ruled by fear; elites are governed by the very grid of intelligibility furnished by the account of life as an emergency of emergence this is not a condition that can be resolved simply by ‘throwing the rascals out’) this complex adaptive emergent life exists in the permanent state of emergence. Its politics of security and war now revolve around this state of emergency Politics becomes subject to the urgent and compelling political economy, the logistical and technical dynamics, of war. You cannot, however, debate emergency. You can only interrogate the futile demand it makes on you,
The liberal way of war has thus become the preparedness to make war on whatever threatens life’s capacity to live the emergency of its emergence this complex adaptive emergent life exists now revolve around this state of emergency Politics becomes subject to the urgent and compelling political economy, the logistical and technical dynamics, of war You cannot, however, debate emergency. You can only interrogate the futile demand it makes on you,
There is, third, the additional critical attribute of contingency. It is this feature which does not merely add governing through contingency to the political rationalities and governmental technologies of contemporary liberal rule. It lends its own distinctive infection to them; one which has had a profound impact on the nature of liberal rule and war in relation, especially, to its current hyperbolicization of security and its newly problematized and proliferating accounts of dangers, threats and enemies. For if the biopolitical imperative is that of making life live, the martial expression of that imperative, the drive to liberal war, is preparedness to make war on the enemies of life. The biopoltiical imperative to make life live finds its expression today, however in making life live the emergency of its emergence; for that is what species life is now said to be. The liberal way of rule and war has thus become the preparedness to make war on whatever threatens life’s capacity to live the emergency of its emergence. For allied to the radical contingency of species existence is an account of species existence as a life of continuous complex adaptation and emergence. From the perspective of security and war, in particular, such a pluripotent life, characterized by its continuously unfolding potential, is a life that is continuously becoming-dangerous to itself, and to other life forms. Such danger is not merely actual; because life itself, here has become not merely actual. The emphasis in the problematization of danger which accompanies such a politics of life itself therefore also shifts dramatically from the actual to the virtual. Only this explains the astonishing degree to which the historically secure lives of the Atlantic basin have come to construe themselves, politically, as radically endangered by as many unknown as there are unknowable dangers; a point regularly and frankly admitted, officially, from terror to health mandarins, nationally and internationally. Many have observed that the societies of the Atlantic basin are now increasingly ruled by fear; that there is a politics of fear. But they interpret this politics of fear in political naïve ways, as the outcome of deliberate machination by political and economic elites. They may well be correct to some degree. But what is perfectly evident, also, is that the elites themselves are governed by the very grid of intelligibility furnished by the account of life as an emergency of emergence. It is not simply a matter, therefore, of leaders playing on fears. The leadership itself is in the grip of a conjugation of government and rule whose very generative principle of formation is permanent emergency. In other words, fear is no longer simply an affect open to regular manipulation by leadership cadres. It is, but it is not only that, and not even most importantly that. More importantly (because this is not a condition that can be resolved simply by ‘throwing the rascals out’) in the permanent emergency of emergence, fear becomes a generative principle of formation for rule. The emergency of emergence therefore poses a found crisis in western understandings of the political, and in the hopes and expectations invested in political as opposed to other forms of life. Given the wealth and given the vast military preponderance in weapons of mass destruction and other forms of global deployed military capabilities of the societies of the Atlantic basin, notably, of course, the United States, this poses a world crisis as well. In short, then, this complex adaptive emergent life exists in the permanent state of emergence. Its politics of security and war, which is to say its very foundational politics of rule as well, now revolve around this state of emergency. Here, that in virtue of which a ‘we’ comes to belong together, its very generative principle of formation (our shorthand definition of politics), has become this emergency. What happens, we also therefore ask of the biopoliticization of rule, when emergency becomes the generative principle of formation of community and rule? Our answer has already been given. Politics becomes subject to the urgent and compelling political economy, the logistical and technical dynamics, of war. No longer a ‘we’ in virtue of abiding by commonly agreed rules of government, it becomes a ‘we’ formed by abiding by commonly agreed rules of government, it becomes a ‘we’ formed by the rule of the emergency itself; and that is where the political crisis, the crisis of the political itself is that a ‘we’ can belong together not only in terms of agreeing to abide by the rule of its generative principles of formation but also by the willingness to keep the nature of operation of those generative principles of formation under common deliberative scrutiny. You cannot, however, debate emergency. You can only interrogate the futile demand it makes on you, and all the episteme challenges it poses, acceding to those demands according both to how well you can come to know them, and how well you have also adapted you affects to suffering them, or perish. The very exigencies of emergency thus militate profoundly against the promise of ‘politics’ as it has been commonly understood in the western tradition; not simply as a matter of rule, but as a matter of self-rule in which it was possible to debate the nature of the self in terms of the good for and of the self. Note, also, how much the very idea of the self has disappeared from view in this conflation of life with species life. The only intelligence, the only self-knowledge, the only culture which qualifies in the permanence of this emergency is the utilitarian and instrumental technologies said to be necessary to endure it. We have been here before in the western tradition and we have experienced the challenges of this condition as tyranny (Arendt 1968). The emergency of emergence, the generative principle of formation, the referential matrix of contemporary biopolitics globally, is a newly formed, pervasive and insidiously complex, soft totalitarian regime of power relations made all the more difficult to contest precisely because, governing through the contingent emergency of emergence, it is a governing through the transactional freedoms of contingency
6,296
<h4>This is not just defense. Their reliance on security suffers from serial policy failure – and the attendant endless production of new threats to be countered creates an endless politics of war</h4><p><u>Dillon and Reed <strong>09</u></strong> (IR professor @ Lancaster University; Lecturer @ King’s College London, “The Liberal Way of Killing: Killing to Make Live”)</p><p>There is, third, the additional critical attribute of contingency. It is this feature which does not merely add governing through contingency to the political rationalities and governmental technologies of contemporary liberal rule. It lends its own distinctive infection to them; one which has had a profound impact on the nature of liberal rule and war in relation, especially, to its current hyperbolicization of security and its newly problematized and proliferating accounts of dangers, threats and enemies. For if the biopolitical imperative is that of making life live, the martial expression of that imperative, the drive to liberal war, is preparedness to make war on the enemies of life. The biopoltiical imperative to make life live finds its expression today, however in making life live the emergency of its emergence; for that is what species life is now said to be. <u><mark>The liberal way of</mark> rule and <mark>war has </u>thus<u> become the preparedness to make war on whatever threatens life’s capacity to live the emergency of its emergence</u></mark>. For allied to the radical contingency of species existence is an account of species existence as a life of continuous complex adaptation and emergence. From the perspective of security and war, in particular, such a pluripotent life, characterized by its continuously unfolding potential, is a life that is continuously becoming-dangerous to itself, and to other life forms. Such danger is not merely actual; because life itself, here has become not merely actual. The emphasis in the problematization of danger which accompanies such a politics of life itself therefore also shifts dramatically from the actual to the virtual. Only this explains the astonishing degree to which the historically secure lives of the Atlantic basin have come to construe themselves, politically, as radically endangered by as many unknown as there are unknowable dangers; a point regularly and frankly admitted, officially, from terror to health mandarins, nationally and internationally. Many have observed that the<u> societies </u>of the Atlantic basin<u> are </u>now<u> increasingly ruled by fear; </u>that there is a politics of fear. But they interpret this politics of fear in political naïve ways, as the outcome of deliberate machination by political and economic elites. They may well be correct to some degree. But what is perfectly evident, also, is that the<u> elites </u>themselves<u> are governed by the very grid of intelligibility furnished by the account of life as an emergency of emergence</u>. It is not simply a matter, therefore, of leaders playing on fears. The leadership itself is in the grip of a conjugation of government and rule whose very generative principle of formation is permanent emergency. In other words, fear is no longer simply an affect open to regular manipulation by leadership cadres. It is, but it is not only that, and not even most importantly that. More importantly (because<u> this is not a condition that can be resolved simply by ‘throwing the rascals out’) </u>in the permanent emergency of emergence, fear becomes a generative principle of formation for rule. The emergency of emergence therefore poses a found crisis in western understandings of the political, and in the hopes and expectations invested in political as opposed to other forms of life. Given the wealth and given the vast military preponderance in weapons of mass destruction and other forms of global deployed military capabilities of the societies of the Atlantic basin, notably, of course, the United States, this poses a world crisis as well. In short, then,<u> <mark>this complex adaptive emergent life exists</mark> in the permanent state of emergence. Its politics of security and war</u>, which is to say its very foundational politics of rule as well,<u> <mark>now revolve around this state of emergency</u></mark>. Here, that in virtue of which a ‘we’ comes to belong together, its very generative principle of formation (our shorthand definition of politics), has become this emergency. What happens, we also therefore ask of the biopoliticization of rule, when emergency becomes the generative principle of formation of community and rule? Our answer has already been given. <u><mark>Politics becomes subject to the urgent and compelling political economy, the logistical and technical dynamics, of war</mark>. </u>No longer a ‘we’ in virtue of abiding by commonly agreed rules of government, it becomes a ‘we’ formed by abiding by commonly agreed rules of government, it becomes a ‘we’ formed by the rule of the emergency itself; and that is where the political crisis, the crisis of the political itself is that a ‘we’ can belong together not only in terms of agreeing to abide by the rule of its generative principles of formation but also by the willingness to keep the nature of operation of those generative principles of formation under common deliberative scrutiny. <u><mark>You cannot, however, debate emergency. You can only interrogate the futile demand it makes on you,</mark> </u>and all the episteme challenges it poses, acceding to those demands according both to how well you can come to know them, and how well you have also adapted you affects to suffering them, or perish. The very exigencies of emergency thus militate profoundly against the promise of ‘politics’ as it has been commonly understood in the western tradition; not simply as a matter of rule, but as a matter of self-rule in which it was possible to debate the nature of the self in terms of the good for and of the self. Note, also, how much the very idea of the self has disappeared from view in this conflation of life with species life. The only intelligence, the only self-knowledge, the only culture which qualifies in the permanence of this emergency is the utilitarian and instrumental technologies said to be necessary to endure it. We have been here before in the western tradition and we have experienced the challenges of this condition as tyranny (Arendt 1968). The emergency of emergence, the generative principle of formation, the referential matrix of contemporary biopolitics globally, is a newly formed, pervasive and insidiously complex, soft totalitarian regime of power relations made all the more difficult to contest precisely because, governing through the contingent emergency of emergence, it is a governing through the transactional freedoms of contingency </p>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
25,621
5
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,032
Low oil prices force Iran to the table and provide better pressure- sanctions only risk derailing a deal
NYT 12/26
NYT 12/26/2014 (International New York Times, Swift drop in oil prices has rivals of U.S. reeling; Washington might gain leverage as big energy exporters are squeezed, lexis)
A plunge in oil prices has sent tremors through the global political order, setting off an abrupt shift in fortunes that has bolstered the interests of the United States and pushed Iran to the brink of financial crisis The price plunge may influence Iran's deliberations over whether to agree to a deal on its nuclear program oil prices fall was so sharp as to unsettle plans and assumptions in many governments The price drop ''is knocking down America's principal opponents without us even trying For Iran it is as if Congress had passed tougher sanctions Iran has been hit so hard that its government is offering men the option of buying their way out of military service ''The government needs money badly.
A plunge in oil prices has sent tremors through the global political order, setting off an abrupt shift in fortunes that has bolstered the interests of the United States and pushed Iran to the brink of financial crisis The price plunge may influence Iran's deliberations over whether to agree to a deal on its nuclear program For Iran it is as if Congress had passed tougher sanctions Iran has been hit so hard that its governme is offering men the option of buying their way out of military service ''The government needs money badly
A plunge in oil prices has sent tremors through the global political and economic order, setting off an abrupt shift in fortunes that has bolstered the interests of the United States and pushed several big oil-exporting nations - particularly those hostile to the West, like Russia, Iran and Venezuela - to the brink of financial crisis. The nearly 50 percent decline in oil prices since June has had the most conspicuous impact on the Russian economy and President Vladimir V. Putin. The former finance minister Aleksei L. Kudrin, a longtime friend of Mr. Putin's, warned this week of a ''full-blown economic crisis'' and called for better relations with Europe and the United States. But the ripple effects are spreading much more broadly than that. The price plunge may also influence Iran's deliberations over whether to agree to a deal on its nuclear program with the West; force the oil-rich nations of the Middle East to reassess their role in managing global supply; and give a boost to the economies of the biggest oil-consuming nations, notably the United States and China. It might even have been a late factor in Cuba's decision to seal a rapprochement with Washington. After a precipitous drop, to less than $60 a barrel from around $115 a barrel in June, oil prices settled at a low level this week. Their fall, even if partly reversed, was so sharp and so quick as to unsettle plans and assumptions in many governments. That includes Mr. Putin's apparent hope that Russia could weather Western sanctions over its intervention in Ukraine without serious economic harm, and Venezuela's aspirations for continuing the free-spending policies of Hugo Chávez, who died in 2013 while president. The price drop, said Edward N. Luttwak, a longtime Pentagon adviser and author of several books on geopolitical and economic strategy, ''is knocking down America's principal opponents without us even trying.'' For Iran, which is estimated to be losing $1 billion a month because of the fall, it is as if Congress had passed the much tougher sanctions that the White House lobbied against, he said. Iran has been hit so hard that its government, looking for ways to fill a widening hole in its budget, is offering young men the option of buying their way out of an obligatory two years of military service. ''We are on the eve of a major crisis,'' an Iranian economist, Hossein Raghfar, was quoted as saying on Sunday by the newspaper Etemaad. ''The government needs money badly.''
2,483
<h4>Low oil prices force Iran to the table and provide better pressure- sanctions only risk derailing a deal</h4><p><strong>NYT 12/26</strong>/2014 (International New York Times, Swift drop in oil prices has rivals of U.S. reeling; Washington might gain leverage as big energy exporters are squeezed, lexis)</p><p><u><mark>A plunge in oil prices has sent tremors through the global political</u></mark> and economic <u><mark>order, setting off an abrupt shift in fortunes that has bolstered the interests of the United States and pushed</u></mark> several big oil-exporting nations - particularly those hostile to the West, like Russia, <u><mark>Iran</u></mark> and Venezuela - <u><mark>to the brink of financial crisis</u></mark>. The nearly 50 percent decline in oil prices since June has had the most conspicuous impact on the Russian economy and President Vladimir V. Putin. The former finance minister Aleksei L. Kudrin, a longtime friend of Mr. Putin's, warned this week of a ''full-blown economic crisis'' and called for better relations with Europe and the United States. But the ripple effects are spreading much more broadly than that. <u><mark>The price plunge may</u></mark> also <u><strong><mark>influence Iran's deliberations over whether to agree to a deal on its nuclear program</u></strong></mark> with the West; force the oil-rich nations of the Middle East to reassess their role in managing global supply; and give a boost to the economies of the biggest oil-consuming nations, notably the United States and China. It might even have been a late factor in Cuba's decision to seal a rapprochement with Washington. After a precipitous drop, to less than $60 a barrel from around $115 a barrel in June, <u>oil prices</u> settled at a low level this week. Their <u>fall</u>, even if partly reversed, <u>was so sharp</u> and so quick <u>as to unsettle plans and assumptions in many governments</u>. That includes Mr. Putin's apparent hope that Russia could weather Western sanctions over its intervention in Ukraine without serious economic harm, and Venezuela's aspirations for continuing the free-spending policies of Hugo Chávez, who died in 2013 while president. <u>The price drop</u>, said Edward N. Luttwak, a longtime Pentagon adviser and author of several books on geopolitical and economic strategy, <u>''is knocking down America's principal opponents without us even trying</u>.'' <u><strong><mark>For Iran</u></strong></mark>, which is estimated to be losing $1 billion a month because of the fall, <u><strong><mark>it is as if Congress had passed</u></strong></mark> the much <u><strong><mark>tougher sanctions</u></strong></mark> that the White House lobbied against, he said. <u><mark>Iran has been hit so hard that its governme</mark>nt</u>, looking for ways to fill a widening hole in its budget, <u><mark>is offering</u></mark> young <u><mark>men the option of buying their way out of</u></mark> an obligatory two years of <u><mark>military service</u></mark>. ''We are on the eve of a major crisis,'' an Iranian economist, Hossein Raghfar, was quoted as saying on Sunday by the newspaper Etemaad. <u><mark>''The government needs money badly</mark>.</u><strong>''</p></strong>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Causes Prolif
430,541
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,033
Structural violence and inequality kills millions yearly. Probability outweighs magnitude—treat near zero risks as zero—Improbable risk scenarios are instruments used to justify militarism and mask responsibility for structural violence.
Scheper-Hughes and Bourgois UPenn) 4
Scheper-Hughes and Bourgois (Prof of Anthropology @ Cal-Berkely; Prof of Anthropology @ UPenn) 4 (Nancy and Philippe, Introduction: Making Sense of Violence, in Violence in War and Peace, pg. 19-22)
Absolutely central to our approach is a blurring of categories and distinctions between wartime and peacetime violence. Close attention to the “little” violences produced in the structures, habituses, and mentalites of everyday life shifts our attention to pathologies of class, race, and gender inequalities the license - even the duty - to kill, maim, or soul-murder. it is absolutely necessary to make just such existential leaps in purposefully linking violent acts in normal times to those of abnormal times. there is), an even greater risk lies in failing to sensitize ourselves, in misrecognizing protogenocidal practices and sentiments daily enacted as normative behavior by “ordinary” good-enough citizens Peacetime crimes constitute the “small wars and invisible genocides These are “invisible” genocides not because they are secreted away or hidden from view, but quite the opposite. the things that are hardest to perceive are those which are right before our eyes and therefore taken for granted. Peacetime crimes suggests the possibility that war crimes are merely ordinary, everyday crimes of public consent applied systematically and dramatically in the extreme context of war The public consensus is based primarily on a new mobilization of an old fear of the mob, the mugger, the rapist, the Black man, the undeserving poor. How many public executions of mentally deficient prisoners in the United States are needed to make life feel more secure for the affluent? it is essential that we recognize the existence of a genocidal capacity among otherwise good-enough humans and that we need to exercise a defensive hypervigilance to the less dramatic, permitted, and even rewarded everyday acts of violence that render participation in genocidal acts and policies possible Under the violence continuum we include, therefore, all expressions of radical social exclusion, dehumanization, depersonal- ization, pseudospeciation, and reification which normalize atrocious behavior and violence toward others A constant self-mobilization for alarm, a state of constant hyperarousal is, perhaps, a reasonable response to Benjamin’s view of late modern history as a chronic “state of emergency” Rampp 9 a Specific Concept of Security http://www.inter-disciplinary.net/ptb/wvw/wvw5/Rampp%20paper.pdf] The question arises whether a logic of security is appropriate I strongly doubt this. better alternative approaches to solve problems in the concrete situation are ignored by securitizing it To avoid an intransparent amalgamation of topics, I suggest to discuss practice exclusively and only then investigate connections in the real world.
it is absolutely necessary to make existential leaps in purposefully linking violent acts in normal times to those of abnormal times an even greater risk lies in failing to sensitize ourselves Peacetime crimes constitute the “small wars and invisible genocides” public consensus is based primarily on a new mobilization of an old fear of the Black man, the undeserving poor it is essential that we recognize the genocidal capacity among otherwise good-enough humans and that we need to exercise a defensive hypervigilance to the less dramatic, permitted everyday acts of violence that render participation in genocidal acts and policies possible The question arises whether security is appropriate I strongly doubt this. better alternative approaches to solve problems in the concrete situation are ignored by securitizing it To avoid an intransparent amalgamation , I suggest to discuss practice exclusively and only then investigate connections in the real world.
This large and at first sight “messy” Part VII is central to this anthology’s thesis. It encompasses everything from the routinized, bureaucratized, and utterly banal violence of children dying of hunger and maternal despair in Northeast Brazil (Scheper-Hughes, Chapter 33) to elderly African Americans dying of heat stroke in Mayor Daly’s version of US apartheid in Chicago’s South Side (Klinenberg, Chapter 38) to the racialized class hatred expressed by British Victorians in their olfactory disgust of the “smelly” working classes (Orwell, Chapter 36). In these readings violence is located in the symbolic and social structures that overdetermine and allow the criminalized drug addictions, interpersonal bloodshed, and racially patterned incarcerations that characterize the US “inner city” to be normalized (Bourgois, Chapter 37 and Wacquant, Chapter 39). Violence also takes the form of class, racial, political self-hatred and adolescent self-destruction (Quesada, Chapter 35), as well as of useless (i.e. preventable), rawly embodied physical suffering, and death (Farmer, Chapter 34). Absolutely central to our approach is a blurring of categories and distinctions between wartime and peacetime violence. Close attention to the “little” violences produced in the structures, habituses, and mentalites of everyday life shifts our attention to pathologies of class, race, and gender inequalities. More important, it interrupts the voyeuristic tendencies of “violence studies” that risk publicly humiliating the powerless who are often forced into complicity with social and individual pathologies of power because suffering is often a solvent of human integrity and dignity. Thus, in this anthology we are positing a violence continuum comprised of a multitude of “small wars and invisible genocides” (see also Scheper- Hughes 1996; 1997; 2000b) conducted in the normative social spaces of public schools, clinics, emergency rooms, hospital wards, nursing homes, courtrooms, public registry offices, prisons, detention centers, and public morgues. The violence continuum also refers to the ease with which humans are capable of reducing the socially vulnerable into expendable nonpersons and assuming the license - even the duty - to kill, maim, or soul-murder. We realize that in referring to a violence and a genocide continuum we are flying in the face of a tradition of genocide studies that argues for the absolute uniqueness of the Jewish Holocaust and for vigilance with respect to restricted purist use of the term genocide itself (see Kuper 1985; Chaulk 1999; Fein 1990; Chorbajian 1999). But we hold an opposing and alternative view that, to the contrary, it is absolutely necessary to make just such existential leaps in purposefully linking violent acts in normal times to those of abnormal times. Hence the title of our volume: Violence in War and in Peace. If (as we concede) there is a moral risk in overextending the concept of “genocide” into spaces and corners of everyday life where we might not ordinarily think to find it (and there is), an even greater risk lies in failing to sensitize ourselves, in misrecognizing protogenocidal practices and sentiments daily enacted as normative behavior by “ordinary” good-enough citizens. Peacetime crimes, such as prison construction sold as economic development to impoverished communities in the mountains and deserts of California, or the evolution of the criminal industrial complex into the latest peculiar institution for managing race relations in the United States (Waquant, Chapter 39), constitute the “small wars and invisible genocides” to which we refer. This applies to African American and Latino youth mortality statistics in Oakland, California, Baltimore, Washington DC, and New York City. These are “invisible” genocides not because they are secreted away or hidden from view, but quite the opposite. As Wittgenstein observed, the things that are hardest to perceive are those which are right before our eyes and therefore taken for granted. In this regard, Bourdieu’s partial and unfinished theory of violence (see Chapters 32 and 42) as well as his concept of misrecognition is crucial to our task. By including the normative everyday forms of violence hidden in the minutiae of “normal” social practices - in the architecture of homes, in gender relations, in communal work, in the exchange of gifts, and so forth - Bourdieu forces us to reconsider the broader meanings and status of violence, especially the links between the violence of everyday life and explicit political terror and state repression, Similarly, Basaglia’s notion of “peacetime crimes” - crimini di pace - imagines a direct relationship between wartime and peacetime violence. Peacetime crimes suggests the possibility that war crimes are merely ordinary, everyday crimes of public consent applied systematically and dramatically in the extreme context of war. Consider the parallel uses of rape during peacetime and wartime, or the family resemblances between the legalized violence of US immigration and naturalization border raids on “illegal aliens” versus the US government- engineered genocide in 1938, known as the Cherokee “Trail of Tears.” Peacetime crimes suggests that everyday forms of state violence make a certain kind of domestic peace possible. Internal “stability” is purchased with the currency of peacetime crimes, many of which take the form of professionally applied “strangle-holds.” Everyday forms of state violence during peacetime make a certain kind of domestic “peace” possible. It is an easy-to-identify peacetime crime that is usually maintained as a public secret by the government and by a scared or apathetic populace. Most subtly, but no less politically or structurally, the phenomenal growth in the United States of a new military, postindustrial prison industrial complex has taken place in the absence of broad-based opposition, let alone collective acts of civil disobedience. The public consensus is based primarily on a new mobilization of an old fear of the mob, the mugger, the rapist, the Black man, the undeserving poor. How many public executions of mentally deficient prisoners in the United States are needed to make life feel more secure for the affluent? What can it possibly mean when incarceration becomes the “normative” socializing experience for ethnic minority youth in a society, i.e., over 33 percent of young African American men (Prison Watch 2002). In the end it is essential that we recognize the existence of a genocidal capacity among otherwise good-enough humans and that we need to exercise a defensive hypervigilance to the less dramatic, permitted, and even rewarded everyday acts of violence that render participation in genocidal acts and policies possible (under adverse political or economic conditions), perhaps more easily than we would like to recognize. Under the violence continuum we include, therefore, all expressions of radical social exclusion, dehumanization, depersonal- ization, pseudospeciation, and reification which normalize atrocious behavior and violence toward others. A constant self-mobilization for alarm, a state of constant hyperarousal is, perhaps, a reasonable response to Benjamin’s view of late modern history as a chronic “state of emergency” (Taussig, Chapter 31). Rampp 9 [Benjamin, University of Tübingen, Interdepartmental Centre for Ethics in the Sciences and Humanities (IZEW). Insecurity by Impreciseness Towards a Specific Concept of Security http://www.inter-disciplinary.net/ptb/wvw/wvw5/Rampp%20paper.pdf] The question arises whether such a logic of security – which in practice comprises more terms like intentional threats, us vs. them (Wæver 1995: 63), coercion, violence and counter vio- lence, or the loss of freedoms than the idea of “peace of mind” – is appropriate for the respec- tive situations. I strongly doubt this. Rather, potentially better alternative approaches to solve problems in the concrete situation are ignored by securitizing it (Wæver 1995: 57). Of course, issues of economy, food, health, environment, and the social dimension are linked with security. To avoid an intransparent amalgamation of topics, I therefore suggest – from a methodological point of view – to discuss both definitions and fields of practice exclusively and only then investigate connections in the real world.
8,397
<h4>Structural violence and inequality kills millions yearly. Probability outweighs magnitude—treat near zero risks as zero—Improbable risk scenarios are instruments used to <u>justify</u> militarism and mask responsibility for structural violence. </h4><p><strong><mark>Scheper-Hughes and Bourgois</strong></mark> (Prof of Anthropology @ Cal-Berkely; Prof of Anthropology @ <strong><mark>UPenn) 4</p><p></strong></mark>(Nancy and Philippe, Introduction: Making Sense of Violence, in Violence in War and Peace, pg. 19-22) </p><p>This large and at first sight “messy” Part VII is central to this anthology’s thesis. It encompasses everything from the routinized, bureaucratized, and utterly banal violence of children dying of hunger and maternal despair in Northeast Brazil (Scheper-Hughes, Chapter 33) to elderly African Americans dying of heat stroke in Mayor Daly’s version of US apartheid in Chicago’s South Side (Klinenberg, Chapter 38) to the racialized class hatred expressed by British Victorians in their olfactory disgust of the “smelly” working classes (Orwell, Chapter 36). In these readings violence is located in the symbolic and social structures that overdetermine and allow the criminalized drug addictions, interpersonal bloodshed, and racially patterned incarcerations that characterize the US “inner city” to be normalized (Bourgois, Chapter 37 and Wacquant, Chapter 39). Violence also takes the form of class, racial, political self-hatred and adolescent self-destruction (Quesada, Chapter 35), as well as of useless (i.e. preventable), rawly embodied physical suffering, and death (Farmer, Chapter 34). <u>Absolutely central to our approach is a blurring of categories and distinctions between wartime and peacetime violence. Close attention to the “little” violences produced in the structures, habituses, and mentalites of everyday life shifts our attention to pathologies of class, race, and gender inequalities</u>. More important, it interrupts the voyeuristic tendencies of “violence studies” that risk publicly humiliating the powerless who are often forced into complicity with social and individual pathologies of power because suffering is often a solvent of human integrity and dignity. Thus, in this anthology we are positing a violence continuum comprised of a multitude of “small wars and invisible genocides” (see also Scheper- Hughes 1996; 1997; 2000b) conducted in the normative social spaces of public schools, clinics, emergency rooms, hospital wards, nursing homes, courtrooms, public registry offices, prisons, detention centers, and public morgues. The violence continuum also refers to the ease with which humans are capable of reducing the socially vulnerable into expendable nonpersons and assuming<u> the license - even the duty - to kill, maim, or soul-murder.</u> We realize that in referring to a violence and a genocide continuum we are flying in the face of a tradition of genocide studies that argues for the absolute uniqueness of the Jewish Holocaust and for vigilance with respect to restricted purist use of the term genocide itself (see Kuper 1985; Chaulk 1999; Fein 1990; Chorbajian 1999). But we hold an opposing and alternative view that, to the contrary, <u><mark>it is absolutely necessary to make</mark> just such <mark>existential leaps in purposefully linking violent acts in normal times to those of abnormal times</mark>.</u> Hence the title of our volume: Violence in War and in Peace. If (as we concede) there is a moral risk in overextending the concept of “genocide” into spaces and corners of everyday life where we might not ordinarily think to find it (and <u>there is), <mark>an even greater risk lies in failing to sensitize ourselves</mark>, in misrecognizing protogenocidal practices and sentiments daily enacted as normative behavior by “ordinary” good-enough citizens</u>. <u><mark>Peacetime crimes</u></mark>, such as prison construction sold as economic development to impoverished communities in the mountains and deserts of California, or the evolution of the criminal industrial complex into the latest peculiar institution for managing race relations in the United States (Waquant, Chapter 39), <u><mark>constitute the “small wars and invisible genocides</u>”</mark> to which we refer. This applies to African American and Latino youth mortality statistics in Oakland, California, Baltimore, Washington DC, and New York City. <u>These are “invisible” genocides not because they are secreted away or hidden from view, but quite the opposite.</u> As Wittgenstein observed, <u>the things that are hardest to perceive are those which are right before our eyes and therefore taken for granted.</u> In this regard, Bourdieu’s partial and unfinished theory of violence (see Chapters 32 and 42) as well as his concept of misrecognition is crucial to our task. By including the normative everyday forms of violence hidden in the minutiae of “normal” social practices - in the architecture of homes, in gender relations, in communal work, in the exchange of gifts, and so forth - Bourdieu forces us to reconsider the broader meanings and status of violence, especially the links between the violence of everyday life and explicit political terror and state repression, Similarly, Basaglia’s notion of “peacetime crimes” - crimini di pace - imagines a direct relationship between wartime and peacetime violence. <u>Peacetime crimes suggests the possibility that war crimes are merely ordinary, everyday crimes of public consent applied systematically and dramatically in the extreme context of war</u>. Consider the parallel uses of rape during peacetime and wartime, or the family resemblances between the legalized violence of US immigration and naturalization border raids on “illegal aliens” versus the US government- engineered genocide in 1938, known as the Cherokee “Trail of Tears.” Peacetime crimes suggests that everyday forms of state violence make a certain kind of domestic peace possible. Internal “stability” is purchased with the currency of peacetime crimes, many of which take the form of professionally applied “strangle-holds.” Everyday forms of state violence during peacetime make a certain kind of domestic “peace” possible. It is an easy-to-identify peacetime crime that is usually maintained as a public secret by the government and by a scared or apathetic populace. Most subtly, but no less politically or structurally, the phenomenal growth in the United States of a new military, postindustrial prison industrial complex has taken place in the absence of broad-based opposition, let alone collective acts of civil disobedience. <u>The <mark>public consensus is based primarily on a new mobilization of an old fear of the</mark> mob, the mugger, the rapist, the <mark>Black man, the undeserving poor</mark>. How many public executions of mentally deficient prisoners in the United States are needed to make life feel more secure for the affluent?</u> What can it possibly mean when incarceration becomes the “normative” socializing experience for ethnic minority youth in a society, i.e., over 33 percent of young African American men (Prison Watch 2002). In the end <u><mark>it is essential that we recognize the</mark> existence of a <mark>genocidal capacity among otherwise good-enough humans and that we need to exercise a defensive <strong>hypervigilance to the less dramatic, permitted</mark>, and even rewarded <mark>everyday acts</strong> of violence that <strong>render participation in genocidal acts and policies possible</u></strong></mark> (under adverse political or economic conditions), perhaps more easily than we would like to recognize. <u>Under the violence continuum we include, therefore, all expressions of radical social exclusion, dehumanization, depersonal- ization, pseudospeciation, and reification which normalize atrocious behavior and violence toward others</u>. <u>A constant self-mobilization for alarm, a state of constant hyperarousal is, perhaps, a reasonable response to Benjamin’s view of late modern history as a chronic “state of emergency”</u> (Taussig, Chapter 31).</p><p><u><strong>Rampp 9</u></strong> [Benjamin, University of Tübingen, Interdepartmental Centre for Ethics in the Sciences and Humanities (IZEW). Insecurity by Impreciseness Towards<u><strong> a Specific Concept of Security http://www.inter-disciplinary.net/ptb/wvw/wvw5/Rampp%20paper.pdf]</p><p></strong><mark>The question arises whether</u></mark> such <u>a logic of <mark>security</u></mark> – which in practice comprises more terms like intentional threats, us vs. them (Wæver 1995: 63), coercion, violence and counter vio- lence, or the loss of freedoms than the idea of “peace of mind” – <u><mark>is appropriate</u></mark> for the respec- tive situations. <u><mark>I strongly doubt this.</u></mark> Rather, potentially <u><mark>better alternative approaches to solve problems in the concrete situation are ignored by securitizing it</u></mark> (Wæver 1995: 57). Of course, issues of economy, food, health, environment, and the social dimension are linked with security. <u><mark>To avoid an intransparent amalgamation </mark>of topics<mark>, I</u></mark> therefore <u><mark>suggest</u></mark> – from a methodological point of view – <u><mark>to discuss</u></mark> both definitions and fields of <u><mark>practice <strong>exclusively</strong> and <strong>only then</strong> investigate connections in the real world.</p></u></mark>
2nc
null
1NC Property Rights DA
16,028
483
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,034
Yes compliance
Dahl 9/19/14
Dahl 9/19/14 --- Reuters (Fredrik, “Iran moving to comply with extended nuclear deal with powers-IAEA”, http://af.reuters.com/article/worldNews/idAFKBN0HE1RG20140919)//trepka
Iran is taking further action to comply with the terms of an extended interim agreement with six world powers over its disputed atomic activities, a U.N. nuclear watchdog report showed The findings though no major surprise may be seen as positive by the West as negotiations resumed in New York this week on ending the decade-old nuclear stand-off. Iran is continuing to meet its commitments In addition, as agreed when the deal was extended by four months in July, it is using some of its higher-grade enriched uranium in oxide form to produce fuel a step that experts say would make it more difficult to use the material for any bombs. After years of escalating tensions between Iran and the West, the election in mid-2013 of Hassan Rouhani, a pragmatist as Iranian president on a platform of ending Tehran's international isolation created new room for diplomacy that ultimately led to last year's breakthrough nuclear deal. Under the preliminary accord, Iran halted its most contested nuclear work It also converted its stockpile of the material into oxide from gas. it agreed to take some additional nuclear steps, including making nuclear fuel for a research reactor and diluting a large amount of low-enriched uranium. IAEA has inspectors on the ground in Iran who are monitoring its enrichment sites on a daily basis. Its monthly reports on the implementation of the nuclear agreement are issued to its member states and not made public.
Iran is taking further action to comply with the agreement , a U.N. nuclear report showed findings may b positive as negotiations resumed this week , it is using high grade uranium to produce fuel - a step experts say would make it more difficult to use material for bombs the election of Rouhani, a pragmatist created new diplomacy IAEA has inspectors monthly reports are issued
(Reuters) - Iran is taking further action to comply with the terms of an extended interim agreement with six world powers over its disputed atomic activities, a U.N. nuclear watchdog report obtained by Reuters on Friday showed. The findings in a monthly update by the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) - though no major surprise - may be seen as positive by the West as negotiations resumed in New York this week on ending the decade-old nuclear stand-off. The IAEA document made clear that Iran is continuing to meet its commitments under the preliminary accord that it reached with the United States, France, Germany, Britain, China and Russia late last year and that took effect in January. In addition, as agreed when the deal was extended by four months in July, it is using some of its higher-grade enriched uranium in oxide form to produce fuel - a step that experts say would make it more difficult to use the material for any bombs. The IAEA is tasked with checking that Iran is living up to its part of the temporary agreement, which was designed to buy time for the current talks on a comprehensive settlement of the dispute that would dispel fears of a new Middle East war. Iran denies Western allegations that it has been working to develop a capability to make atomic bombs, saying it is refining uranium to fuel a planned network of nuclear power plants. After years of escalating tensions between Iran and the West, the election in mid-2013 of Hassan Rouhani, a pragmatist, as Iranian president on a platform of ending Tehran's international isolation created new room for diplomacy that ultimately led to last year's breakthrough nuclear deal. The initial aim was for Iran and the six powers to reach a long-term agreement by a self-imposed July 20 deadline. But the talks and the interim deal were extended until Nov. 24 in view of persistently wide differences over the future size of Iran's uranium enrichment program, activity which can have both civilian and military purposes. NUCLEAR FUEL Under the preliminary accord, Iran halted its most contested nuclear work - enrichment of uranium to a higher fissile concentration of 20 percent - in exchange for a limited easing of sanctions that are hurting its oil-dependent economy. It also converted its stockpile of the material into oxide from gas. Over the four months of the deal's extension, Iran is to receive $2.8 billion in previously frozen oil revenue held in banks abroad, in addition to the $4.2 billion it got during the January-July period. In exchange, it agreed to take some additional nuclear steps, including making nuclear fuel for a research reactor and diluting a large amount of low-enriched uranium. Friday's IAEA report said Iran since July 24 had used 12.5 kg (28 lbs) of its 20 percent uranium in oxide form for manufacturing fuel. It also said Iran had begun preparatory work for diluting more than four tonnes of uranium gas enriched to up to two percent. Uranium can be used for atomic energy plants, Iran's stated aim, but can also provide material for bombs if processed to a high degree, which the West fears may be the ultimate aim. The Vienna-based IAEA has inspectors on the ground in Iran who are monitoring its enrichment sites on a daily basis. Its monthly reports on the implementation of the nuclear agreement are issued to its member states and not made public.
3,379
<h4>Yes compliance </h4><p><strong>Dahl 9/19/14 </strong>--- Reuters (Fredrik, “Iran moving to comply with extended nuclear deal with powers-IAEA”, http://af.reuters.com/article/worldNews/idAFKBN0HE1RG20140919)//trepka</p><p>(Reuters) - <u><mark>Iran is taking <strong>further action</strong> to <strong>comply</strong> with the</mark> terms of an extended interim <mark>agreement</mark> with six world powers over its disputed atomic activities<mark>, a U.N. nuclear</mark> watchdog <mark>report</u></mark> obtained by Reuters on Friday <u><mark>showed</u></mark>. <u>The <mark>findings</u></mark> in a monthly update by the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) - <u>though no major surprise</u> - <u><mark>may b</mark>e seen as <strong><mark>positive</u></strong></mark> <u>by the West <mark>as negotiations resumed</mark> in New York <mark>this week</mark> on ending the decade-old nuclear stand-off. </u>The IAEA document made clear that <u>Iran is <strong>continuing to meet its commitments</u></strong> under the preliminary accord that it reached with the United States, France, Germany, Britain, China and Russia late last year and that took effect in January. <u>In addition, as agreed when the deal was extended by four months in July<mark>, it is using</mark> some of its <mark>high</mark>er-<mark>grade</mark> enriched <mark>uranium</mark> in oxide form <mark>to produce fuel</u> - <u>a step</mark> that <strong><mark>experts say</strong> would make it more difficult to use</mark> the <mark>material for</mark> <strong>any <mark>bombs</strong></mark>. </u>The IAEA is tasked with checking that Iran is living up to its part of the temporary agreement, which was designed to buy time for the current talks on a comprehensive settlement of the dispute that would dispel fears of a new Middle East war. Iran denies Western allegations that it has been working to develop a capability to make atomic bombs, saying it is refining uranium to fuel a planned network of nuclear power plants. <u>After years of escalating tensions between Iran and the West, <mark>the election</mark> in mid-2013 <mark>of</mark> Hassan <mark>Rouhani, a <strong>pragmatist</u></strong></mark>, <u>as Iranian president on a platform of ending Tehran's international isolation <mark>created new</mark> room for <mark>diplomacy</mark> that ultimately led to last year's breakthrough nuclear deal. </u>The initial aim was for Iran and the six powers to reach a long-term agreement by a self-imposed July 20 deadline. But the talks and the interim deal were extended until Nov. 24 in view of persistently wide differences over the future size of Iran's uranium enrichment program, activity which can have both civilian and military purposes. NUCLEAR FUEL <u>Under the preliminary accord, Iran halted its most contested nuclear work</u> - enrichment of uranium to a higher fissile concentration of 20 percent - in exchange for a limited easing of sanctions that are hurting its oil-dependent economy. <u>It also converted its stockpile of the material into oxide from gas. </u>Over the four months of the deal's extension, Iran is to receive $2.8 billion in previously frozen oil revenue held in banks abroad, in addition to the $4.2 billion it got during the January-July period. In exchange, <u>it agreed to take some additional nuclear steps, including making nuclear fuel for a research reactor and diluting a large amount of low-enriched uranium. </u>Friday's IAEA report said Iran since July 24 had used 12.5 kg (28 lbs) of its 20 percent uranium in oxide form for manufacturing fuel. It also said Iran had begun preparatory work for diluting more than four tonnes of uranium gas enriched to up to two percent. Uranium can be used for atomic energy plants, Iran's stated aim, but can also provide material for bombs if processed to a high degree, which the West fears may be the ultimate aim. The Vienna-based <u><mark>IAEA</u> <u>has inspectors</mark> on the ground in Iran who are monitoring its enrichment sites on a daily basis. Its <strong><mark>monthly reports</strong></mark> on the implementation of the nuclear agreement <mark>are issued</mark> to its member states and not made public.</p></u>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Causes Prolif
218,942
8
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,035
First is heg
Hossein-Zadeh 10
Hossein-Zadeh 10 [ISMAEL HOSSEIN-ZADEH,author of The Political Economy of U.S. Militarism (Palgrave-Macmillan 2007), teaches economics at Drake University, Des Moines, Iowa, “The Globalization of Militarism”, 2011, http://hamsayeh.net/archive/144-the-globalization-of-militarism.htm]
In response to the escalation of US military spending, which has tripled the last 10 years Russia has drastically increased its military spending military encirclement of China has led that country to also further strengthen its military capabilities. US geopolitical ambitions have compelled countries such as Iran, Venezuela and North Korea to strengthen their armed forces US militarization of the world is the source of a largely redundant and disproportionately large allocation of the world’s precious resources to war to justify this lopsided allocation beneficiaries of war dividends create fear, suspicion and hostility among peoples and nations of the world sowing the seeds of war, international conflicts and global instability.
null
The expansion of NATO to include most of the Eastern Europe has led Russia, which had curtailed its military spending during the 1990s in the hope that, following the collapse of the Berlin Wall, the US would also do the same, to once again increase its military spending. In response to the escalation of US military spending, which has nearly tripled during the last 10 years (from $295 billion when George W. Bush went to the White House in January 2001 to the current figure of nearly one trillion dollars), Russia too has drastically increased its military spending during the same time period (from about $22 billion in 2000 to $61 billion today). In a similar fashion, US military encirclement of China (through a number of military alliances and partnerships that range from Pakistan, Afghanistan and India to South China Sea/Southeast Asia, Taiwan, South Korea, Japan, Cambodia, Malaysia, New Zealand and most recently Vietnam) has led that country to also further strengthen its military capabilities. Just as the US military and geopolitical ambitions have led Russia and China to reinforce their military capabilities, so have they compelled other countries such as Iran, Venezuela and North Korea to likewise strengthen their armed forces and buttress their military preparedness. Not only does aggressive US militarism compel its “adversaries” to allocate a disproportionately large share of their precious resources to military spending, but it also coerces its “allies” to likewise embark on a path of militarization. Thus, countries like Japan and Germany, whose military capabilities were reduced to purely defensive postures following the atrocities of World War II, have once again been re-militarizing in recent years under the impetus of what US military strategists call “the need to share the burden of global security.” Thus, while Germany and Japan still operate under a “peace constitution,” their military expenditures on a global scale now rank sixth and seventh, respectively (behind the US, China, France, UK and Russia). US militarization of the world (both directly through the spread of its own military apparatus across the globe and indirectly by compelling both “friends” and “foe” to militarize) has a number of ominous consequences for the overwhelming majority or the population the world. For one thing, it is the source of a largely redundant and disproportionately large allocation of the world’s precious resources to war, militarism and wasteful production of the means of death and destruction. Obviously, as this inefficient, class-biased disbursement of resources drains public finance and accumulates national debt, it also brings tremendous riches and treasures to war profiteers, that is, the beneficiaries of the military capital and the finance capital. Secondly, to justify this lopsided allocation of the lion’s share of national resources to military spending, beneficiaries of war dividends tend to create fear, suspicion and hostility among peoples and nations of the world, thereby sowing the seeds of war, international conflicts and global instability.
3,119
<h4><strong>First is heg</h4><p>Hossein-Zadeh 10<u></strong> [ISMAEL HOSSEIN-ZADEH,author of The Political Economy of U.S. Militarism (Palgrave-Macmillan 2007), teaches economics at Drake University, Des Moines, Iowa, “The Globalization of Militarism”, 2011, http://hamsayeh.net/archive/144-the-globalization-of-militarism.htm]</p><p></u>The expansion of NATO to include most of the Eastern Europe has led Russia, which had curtailed its military spending during the 1990s in the hope that, following the collapse of the Berlin Wall, the US would also do the same, to once again increase its military spending. <u>In response to the escalation of US military spending, which has</u> nearly <u>tripled</u> during <u>the last 10 years</u> (from $295 billion when George W. Bush went to the White House in January 2001 to the current figure of nearly one trillion dollars), <u>Russia</u> too <u>has drastically increased its military spending</u> during the same time period (from about $22 billion in 2000 to $61 billion today). In a similar fashion, US <u>military encirclement of China</u> (through a number of military alliances and partnerships that range from Pakistan, Afghanistan and India to South China Sea/Southeast Asia, Taiwan, South Korea, Japan, Cambodia, Malaysia, New Zealand and most recently Vietnam) <u>has led that country to also further strengthen its military capabilities.</u> Just as the <u>US</u> military and <u>geopolitical ambitions</u> have led Russia and China to reinforce their military capabilities, so <u>have</u> they <u>compelled</u> other <u>countries such as Iran, Venezuela and North Korea to</u> likewise <u>strengthen their armed forces</u> and buttress their military preparedness. Not only does aggressive US militarism compel its “adversaries” to allocate a disproportionately large share of their precious resources to military spending, but it also coerces its “allies” to likewise embark on a path of militarization. Thus, countries like Japan and Germany, whose military capabilities were reduced to purely defensive postures following the atrocities of World War II, have once again been re-militarizing in recent years under the impetus of what US military strategists call “the need to share the burden of global security.” Thus, while Germany and Japan still operate under a “peace constitution,” their military expenditures on a global scale now rank sixth and seventh, respectively (behind the US, China, France, UK and Russia). <u>US militarization of the world</u> (both directly through the spread of its own military apparatus across the globe and indirectly by compelling both “friends” and “foe” to militarize) has a number of ominous consequences for the overwhelming majority or the population the world. For one thing, it <u>is the source of a largely redundant and disproportionately large allocation of the world’s precious resources to war</u>, militarism and wasteful production of the means of death and destruction. Obviously, as this inefficient, class-biased disbursement of resources drains public finance and accumulates national debt, it also brings tremendous riches and treasures to war profiteers, that is, the beneficiaries of the military capital and the finance capital. Secondly, <u>to justify this lopsided allocation</u> of the lion’s share of national resources to military spending, <u>beneficiaries of war dividends</u> tend to <u>create fear, suspicion and hostility among peoples and nations of the world</u>, thereby <u><strong>sowing the seeds of war, international conflicts and global instability.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 1—Heg
430,543
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,036
Prefer it --- all their ev is rhetoric
Forbes 11/30
Forbes 11/30 (The Iranian Nuclear Deal Is A Good One http://www.forbes.com/sites/jamesconca/2013/11/30/the-iranian-nuclear-deal-is-a-good-one/ James Conca 11/30/13
new deal between Iran and six superpowers. the United States, Great Britain, France, Germany, Russia and China (the P5+1 group) reached an interim deal with Iran to stop their nuclear weapons program. Four key provisions were obtained no enrichment of U above 5% U-235 ) no additional centrifuges are to be installed or produced stop all work on the heavy-water reactor at Arak provide design details on the reactor and do not develop the reprocessing facilities needed to separate Pu from used fuel,¶ full access by IAEA inspectors to all nuclear facilities including daily visitation to Natanz and Fordow, and continuous camera surveillance of key sites.¶ Despite all the rhetoric of horror and claims that this deal is a mistake, this deal is just what we all hoped for as the first step to resolving the Iranian nuclear weapons issue It is the first step to bringing Iran into the world’s nuclear community as a partner instead of an adversary, Iran’s theocracy embodied by their new President has decided that the cost/benefit of maintaining an expensive, useless nuclear program that is still a long way from producing a reliable weapon, while being starved by a barrage of sanctions, on the heels of a global economic meltdown, has now gone into the too-much-cost-and-not-enough-benefit category.¶ there is now an opening to change the game.¶ I’m not sure what the naysayers of this deal think the sanctions were suppose to do. The purpose of sanctions is to get a specific party to the negotiating table. Sanctions are not meant to destroy a nation, cause widespread poverty of its people and destruction of their economy, or topple governments. As much as some leaders in Israel and Saudi Arabia want to use the U.S. to decapitate their nemesis, this is not the point of these talks We need nuclear energy to spread around the world without proliferating weapons. How we handle Iran will determine the future of nuclear energy in many countries outside of the developed world, and we better get it right All other rhetoric is posturing. Isolation is the worst strategy for bringing a country into the civil world’s fold And while discussions focus on 20% U-235 as sufficiently enriched to make an atomic weapon, that is only theoretically correct. No one has made a weapon from such lowly-enriched materials and no one ever will.¶
new deal stop their nuclear program. Four key provisions were obtained no enrichment above 5% no additional centrifuges stop heavy-water reacto full access by IAEA inspectors to all facilities, including continuous surveillance Despite rhetoric of horror this deal is the first step to resolving Iranian nuclear issue It is the first step to bringing Iran into nuclear community as a partner The purpose of sanctions is to get a party to the table As much as some leaders in Israel want to use the U.S. this is not the point All rhetoric is posturing Isolation is the worst strategy
This Thanksgiving had an extra reason to be thankful – the new deal between Iran and six superpowers. Last week, the United States, Great Britain, France, Germany, Russia and China (the P5+1 group) reached an interim deal with Iran to stop their nuclear weapons program. Four key provisions were obtained in this deal:¶ 1) no enrichment of U above 5% U-235, and all highly-enriched materials, some as high as 20% U-235, must be blended down to less than 5% or altered to a form not usable for weapons.¶ 2) no additional centrifuges are to be installed or produced, and three-fourths of the centrifuges at Fordow and half of the centrifuges at Natanz will be inoperable,¶ 3) stop all work on the heavy-water reactor at Arak, provide design details on the reactor (which could be used to produce Pu for the other type of atomic weapon) and do not develop the reprocessing facilities needed to separate Pu from used fuel,¶ 4) full access by IAEA inspectors to all nuclear facilities, including daily visitation to Natanz and Fordow, and continuous camera surveillance of key sites.¶ Despite all the rhetoric of horror and claims that this deal is a mistake, this deal is just what we all hoped for as the first step to resolving the Iranian nuclear weapons issue, the structure of which we’ve been proposing for years. It is the first step to bringing Iran into the world’s nuclear community as a partner instead of an adversary, making Iran a compliant signatory of the Non-Proliferation Treaty. While this may make some of its neighbors nervous, there is no real alternative that does not involve lots of destruction and death.¶ Old orders are falling in the Middle East. The region is in upheaval, Shia and Sunni are as far apart as ever, and Iran’s theocracy, embodied by their new President Hassan Rouhani, has decided that the cost/benefit of maintaining an expensive, useless nuclear program that is still a long way from producing a reliable weapon, while being starved by a barrage of sanctions, on the heels of a global economic meltdown, has now gone into the too-much-cost-and-not-enough-benefit category.¶ Thus, there is now an opening to change the game.¶ This deal is not about trust, as the last point above about access addresses. No one trusts governments, even supposedly good ones. There must be unfettered access to verify that the nuclear facilities are not being used to produce weapons and that is what this deal allows, and it will be easy to determine when Iran breaks this deal (The Economist; The Guardian; Fox News).¶ But the facilities can, and will, be used to support nuclear power, as was the original purpose of Iran’s nuclear program when the United States set it up under the Shah in the 1960s, and that is the actual end point of this whole deal. Not the end of Iran’s nuclear program or the destruction of their facilities, their country or their people.¶ I’m not sure what the naysayers of this deal think the sanctions were suppose to do. The purpose of sanctions is to get a specific party to the negotiating table. Sanctions are not meant to destroy a nation, cause widespread poverty of its people and destruction of their economy, or topple governments. The fear of these happening, not the reality of them, is what gets a government to the table.¶ As much as some leaders in Israel and Saudi Arabia want to use the U.S. to decapitate their nemesis, this is not the point of these talks. And what happens here goes far beyond just Iran. We need nuclear energy to spread around the world without proliferating weapons. How we handle Iran will determine the future of nuclear energy in many countries outside of the developed world, and we better get it right. There will always be pressures to develop weapons and we need strategies and experience in diverting these programs away from weapons.¶ Besides, the art of diplomacy is the art of finding a win-win for all parties. It’s significant that the Obama Administration knows how to use diplomacy the way only the U.S. can. It is in both our and the world’s best interest, to find a solution that allows Iran nuclear energy without weapons.¶ All other rhetoric is posturing. Isolation is the worst strategy for bringing a country into the civil world’s fold. Just look at North Korea. Rouhani has to move forward in a way that does not shame Iran. The celebration in Iran over this deal is a strong indication of the win-win nature of this deal, not the ridiculous charge of the opposition that the U.S. was taken for a ride. Iran wants to, and according to international law can, have a nuclear energy program, including enrichment and production, as long as it falls under the appropriate international controls and is not producing weapons.¶ It is no wonder that Iran wants this deal as badly as it seems. It is a way out of a very tricky and dangerous situation. Countries having the bomb never seem to get attacked, but those that give up their nuclear programs completely tend to end badly. Just ask Iraq and Libya. To avoid this fate, Iran has to back away from nuclear weapons while retaining a nuclear energy program.¶ The U.S. understands that this deal is a good step toward that end. A final deal will include a structure that precludes the ability to make a weapon, such as abandoning or altering the reactor at Arak, and closing the Fordow enrichment facility because it is basically immune from attack being under a mountain. But the whole deal doesn’t have to be done all at once.¶ All things considered, this deal with Iran is a good one for the world.¶ Technical Endnotes – Just a few technical clarifications since science rarely enters media coverage of nuclear issues, yet is extremely important. The original level of U-235 in the uranium ore, that is mined like any other ore, is 0.7% U-235. 5% U-235 is the level of enrichment for nuclear fuel for power reactors. Although some reactor designs can use anything from natural uranium to highly-enriched material, most power reactor fuel is between 3% and 5% enriched as is used in Iran’s Bushehr reactor, a reactor no one cares much about for this reason. You can’t make a bomb out of these materials. This is the basis for the first key provision of the deal.¶ And while discussions focus on 20% U-235 as sufficiently enriched to make an atomic weapon, that is only theoretically correct. No one has made a weapon from such lowly-enriched materials and no one ever will.¶ Enrichment needs to be >90% to make a reliable weapon. Reliability in this case is not like having a reliable flashlight. Reliable in this case means the atomic weapon will work when you want it to. It’s why there’s so much testing associated with a weapons program. If you’re going to make the fatal decision to field a nuke, it better work, and everyone knows it has to be over 90% U-235 to be really useful.¶ Finally, an atomic weapon is fission-based such as U-235 and Pu-239 whose nuclei split to change a bit of matter into a huge amount of energy. These are what was dropped during WWII, what Iran was working towards with U, and what North Korea has developed with Pu. In contrast, a nuclear weapon is fusion-based such as a hydrogen bomb, whose nuclei fuse to change a bit of matter into even more energy.
7,251
<h4>Prefer it --- all their ev is <u>rhetoric</h4><p></u><strong>Forbes 11/30 </strong>(The Iranian Nuclear Deal Is A Good One http://www.forbes.com/sites/jamesconca/2013/11/30/the-iranian-nuclear-deal-is-a-good-one/ James Conca 11/30/13 </p><p>This Thanksgiving had an extra reason to be thankful – the <u><mark>new deal </mark>between Iran and six superpowers.</u> Last week, <u>the United States, Great Britain, France, Germany, Russia and China (the P5+1 group) reached an interim deal with Iran to <mark>stop their nuclear </mark>weapons</u> <u><mark>program. Four key provisions were obtained</u></mark> in this deal:¶ 1) <u><mark>no enrichment </mark>of U <mark>above 5% </mark>U-235</u>, and all highly-enriched materials, some as high as 20% U-235, must be blended down to less than 5% or altered to a form not usable for weapons.¶ 2<u>) <mark>no additional centrifuges</mark> are to be installed or produced</u>, and three-fourths of the centrifuges at Fordow and half of the centrifuges at Natanz will be inoperable,¶ 3) <u><mark>stop </mark>all work on the <mark>heavy-water reacto</mark>r at Arak</u>, <u>provide design details on the reactor</u> (which could be used to produce Pu for the other type of atomic weapon) <u>and do not develop the reprocessing facilities needed to separate Pu from used fuel,¶ </u>4) <u><mark>full access by IAEA inspectors to all </mark>nuclear <mark>facilities</u>, <u>including </mark>daily visitation to Natanz and Fordow, and <mark>continuous </mark>camera <mark>surveillance</mark> of key sites.¶ <mark>Despite</mark> all the <mark>rhetoric of</mark> <mark>horror </mark>and claims that this deal is a mistake, <mark>this deal is</mark> just what we all hoped for as <mark>the first step to resolving</mark> the <mark>Iranian nuclear </mark>weapons <mark>issue</u></mark>, the structure of which we’ve been proposing for years. <u><mark>It is the first step to bringing Iran into</mark> the world’s <mark>nuclear community as a partner</mark> instead of an adversary, </u>making Iran a compliant signatory of the Non-Proliferation Treaty. While this may make some of its neighbors nervous, there is no real alternative that does not involve lots of destruction and death.¶ Old orders are falling in the Middle East. The region is in upheaval, Shia and Sunni are as far apart as ever, and <u>Iran’s theocracy</u>, <u>embodied by their new President</u> Hassan Rouhani, <u>has decided that the cost/benefit of maintaining an expensive, useless nuclear program that is still a long way from producing a reliable weapon, while being starved by a barrage of sanctions, on the heels of a global economic meltdown, has now gone into the too-much-cost-and-not-enough-benefit category.¶ </u>Thus, <u>there is now an opening to change the game.¶</u> This deal is not about trust, as the last point above about access addresses. No one trusts governments, even supposedly good ones. There must be unfettered access to verify that the nuclear facilities are not being used to produce weapons and that is what this deal allows, and it will be easy to determine when Iran breaks this deal (The Economist; The Guardian; Fox News).¶ But the facilities can, and will, be used to support nuclear power, as was the original purpose of Iran’s nuclear program when the United States set it up under the Shah in the 1960s, and that is the actual end point of this whole deal. Not the end of Iran’s nuclear program or the destruction of their facilities, their country or their people.¶ <u>I’m not sure what the naysayers of this deal think the sanctions were suppose to do. <mark>The purpose of sanctions is to get a </mark>specific <mark>party to the </mark>negotiating <mark>table</mark>. Sanctions are not meant to destroy a nation, cause widespread poverty of its people and destruction of their economy, or topple governments.</u> The fear of these happening, not the reality of them, is what gets a government to the table.¶ <u><mark>As much as some leaders in Israel </mark>and Saudi Arabia <mark>want to use the U.S. </mark>to decapitate their nemesis, <mark>this is not the point</mark> of these talks</u>. And what happens here goes far beyond just Iran. <u>We need nuclear energy to spread around the world without proliferating weapons. How we handle Iran will determine the future of nuclear energy in many countries outside of the developed world, and we better get it right</u>. There will always be pressures to develop weapons and we need strategies and experience in diverting these programs away from weapons.¶ Besides, the art of diplomacy is the art of finding a win-win for all parties. It’s significant that the Obama Administration knows how to use diplomacy the way only the U.S. can. It is in both our and the world’s best interest, to find a solution that allows Iran nuclear energy without weapons.¶ <u><mark>All</mark> other <mark>rhetoric is posturing</mark>.</u> <u><mark>Isolation is the worst strategy</u></mark> <u>for bringing a country into the civil world’s fold</u>. Just look at North Korea. Rouhani has to move forward in a way that does not shame Iran. The celebration in Iran over this deal is a strong indication of the win-win nature of this deal, not the ridiculous charge of the opposition that the U.S. was taken for a ride. Iran wants to, and according to international law can, have a nuclear energy program, including enrichment and production, as long as it falls under the appropriate international controls and is not producing weapons.¶ It is no wonder that Iran wants this deal as badly as it seems. It is a way out of a very tricky and dangerous situation. Countries having the bomb never seem to get attacked, but those that give up their nuclear programs completely tend to end badly. Just ask Iraq and Libya. To avoid this fate, Iran has to back away from nuclear weapons while retaining a nuclear energy program.¶ The U.S. understands that this deal is a good step toward that end. A final deal will include a structure that precludes the ability to make a weapon, such as abandoning or altering the reactor at Arak, and closing the Fordow enrichment facility because it is basically immune from attack being under a mountain. But the whole deal doesn’t have to be done all at once.¶ All things considered, this deal with Iran is a good one for the world.¶ Technical Endnotes – Just a few technical clarifications since science rarely enters media coverage of nuclear issues, yet is extremely important. The original level of U-235 in the uranium ore, that is mined like any other ore, is 0.7% U-235. 5% U-235 is the level of enrichment for nuclear fuel for power reactors. Although some reactor designs can use anything from natural uranium to highly-enriched material, most power reactor fuel is between 3% and 5% enriched as is used in Iran’s Bushehr reactor, a reactor no one cares much about for this reason. You can’t make a bomb out of these materials. This is the basis for the first key provision of the deal.¶ <u>And while discussions focus on 20% U-235 as sufficiently enriched to make an atomic weapon, that is only theoretically correct.</u> <u>No one has made a weapon from such lowly-enriched materials and no one ever will.¶ </u>Enrichment needs to be >90% to make a reliable weapon. Reliability in this case is not like having a reliable flashlight. Reliable in this case means the atomic weapon will work when you want it to. It’s why there’s so much testing associated with a weapons program. If you’re going to make the fatal decision to field a nuke, it better work, and everyone knows it has to be over 90% U-235 to be really useful.¶ Finally<strong>, an atomic weapon is fission-based such as U-235 and Pu-239 whose nuclei split to change a bit of matter into a huge amount of energy. These are what was dropped during WWII, what Iran was working towards with U, and what North Korea has developed with Pu. In contrast, a nuclear weapon is fusion-based such as a hydrogen bomb, whose nuclei fuse to change a bit of matter into even more energy.</p></strong>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Causes Prolif
218,942
8
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,037
Turns the environment—US militarism will destroys the biosphere even if every other issue were solved
Scipes 09
Kim Scipes, Ph.D., is an Assistant Professor of Sociology at Purdue University North Central in Westville, Indiana, 2009, http://countercurrents.org/scipes291209.htm
Sanders focuses on the environmental costs of militarism, particularly those from the US military. Sanders recognizes the incredible threat by greenhouse gases to the worlds’ peoples well-being and, in fact, to our very survival. Sanders also knows the environment is not just threatened by greenhouse gasses, but recognizes pollution of the water, air and soil as joining with greenhouse gases to imperil us all. Yet he makes an incredibly important point, trying to put things into perspective and to focus our attention: “… here’s the awful truth: even if every person, every automobile, and every factory suddenly emitted zero emissions, the Earth would still be headed head first and at full speed toward total disaster for one major reason. The [US] military—that voracious vampire—produces enough greenhouse gases, by itself, to place the entire globe, with all its inhabitants large and small, in the most immanent danger of extinction the United States military would then rank in fuel consumption with countries like Iran, Indonesia and Spain. Sanders further discusses the military’s impact on the environment. He talks about the impact of exploding bombs, cluster bombs, napalm, cannon rounds, depleted uranium, etc. He points out that the US military estimates they need about 1.5 billion rounds for their M-16 rifles a year. “Depleted uranium is essentially U-238, the isotope after the fissionable isotope, U-235, has been extracted from uranium ore.” DU has a half-life of 4.7 billion years. He continues: “… a good deal of the country of Iraq, both its deserts and cities, hums with radioactivity .” He sees the problem being not just the illegal and immoral wars in Iraq, Afghanistan, etc. He sees the US military as being an essential part of the US Empire, along with the major multinational corporations. He sees the military as an institution as a threat to global environmental survival. politicians won’t address the problem; they are too incorporated in the US Empire the US military can continue to launch wars and continue killing people (including Americans) around the world, or we can end war, and devote resources to the well-being of people in this country and others around the world. The choice is our’s. But we also need to realize that if we let the US military continue on its path of continual war with its on-going quest for global domination, it will destroy all the humans, animals and vegetation on the planet. Your move, good people.
if every person automobile, and factory emitted zero emissions, the Earth would still be headed head full speed toward total disaster for one reason. The [US] military that vampire produces enough g h g by itself to place the entire globe in danger of extinction U S military would rank in fuel consumption with countries like Indonesia impact of exploding bombs, napalm, cannon rounds, depleted uranium, etc. Iraq, hums with radioactivity the US military can continue to kill people or we can end war, and devote resources to the well-being of people we need to realize if the US military continue on its path it will destroy all humans, animals and vegetation on the planet.
As a US military veteran—USMC, 1969-73, who turned around while on active duty—I have been incredibly frustrated at the impotence of the anti-war movement in the United States to stop the wars in particularly Iraq, Afghanistan and, increasingly, Pakistan. I am, obviously, not alone. Many other people—veterans, as well as many more civilians—also share this frustration. Barry Sanders’ new book, The Green Zone, takes a different angle than any I’ve seen before, and I believe it’s an approach I believe we all need to consider: Sanders focuses on the environmental costs of militarism, particularly those from the US military. Sanders recognizes the incredible threat by greenhouse gases to the worlds’ peoples well-being and, in fact, to our very survival. [Percentage of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere has risen from 280 parts per million (ppm) before the industrial revolution started in 1750 to where the latest readings are 392 ppm—should it reach 450, the accompanying temperature rise would lead to uncontrollable melting of the tundra across Russia and Canada, and the release of untold amounts of methane: methane has 20 times greater impact on the atmosphere than carbon dioxide. James Hansen of NASA believes we must go below 350 ppm to prevent serious environmental damage worldwide—KS.] Sanders also knows the environment is not just threatened by greenhouse gasses, but recognizes pollution of the water, air and soil as joining with greenhouse gases to imperil us all. Yet he makes an incredibly important point, trying to put things into perspective and to focus our attention: “… here’s the awful truth: even if every person, every automobile, and every factory suddenly emitted zero emissions, the Earth would still be headed head first and at full speed toward total disaster for one major reason. The [US] military—that voracious vampire—produces enough greenhouse gases, by itself, to place the entire globe, with all its inhabitants large and small, in the most immanent danger of extinction” (p, 22). To put it plain language, that social institution that is said to protect Americans is, in fact, hastening our very extermination along with all the other people of the planet. Sanders addresses the military’s affects on the environment in many ways. He starts off with trying to figure out how much (fossil) fuel the military uses, with their resulting greenhouse emissions there from. Despite diligent efforts, he cannot find out specific numbers, so he is forced to estimate. After carefully working through different categories, he comes to what he calls a conservative estimate of 1 million barrels of oil a day, which translates to almost 20 million gallons each and every day! He puts this number into international perspective: “If that indeed turns out to be the case, the United States military would then rank in fuel consumption with countries like Iran, Indonesia and Spain. It is truly an astonishing accomplishment, especially when one considers … that the military has only about 1.5 million troops on active duty, and Iran has a population of 66 million, Indonesia a whopping 235 million” (54) The cost, incidentally, is also quite high. He quotes a US Army General as estimating that the cost of this fuel averages $300 a gallon! (55) Yet, how does this contribute to global warming? He reports that the US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) estimates that “each gallon of gasoline produces 19.4 pounds of CO 2” (carbon dioxide). If his estimate of 1 million barrels of oil a day is correct, he writes, “then the combined armed forces sends into the atmosphere about 400 million pounds of greenhouse gases a day, or 200,000 tons. That totals 146 billion pounds a year—or 73 million tons of carbon a year” (67-68). And that’s just regarding fuel use. Sanders further discusses the military’s impact on the environment. He talks about the impact of exploding bombs, cluster bombs, napalm, cannon rounds, depleted uranium, etc. He points out that the US military estimates they need about 1.5 billion rounds for their M-16 rifles a year. He talks about the impact of US military bases around the world, including in the Philippines and Puerto Rico. To me, the most sickening chapter was the one on depleted uranium or DU. He explains, “Depleted uranium is essentially U-238, the isotope after the fissionable isotope, U-235, has been extracted from uranium ore.” DU has a half-life of 4.7 billion years. He continues: “… a good deal of the country of Iraq, both its deserts and cities, hums with radioactivity. For since 1991, the US has been manufacturing ‘just about all [of its] bullets, tank shells, missiles, dumb bombs, smart bombs, and 500- and 2000-pound bombs, and everything else engineered to help our side in the war of Us against Them, [with] depleted uranium in it. Lots of depleted uranium. A single cruise missile, which weighs 3,000 pounds, carries within its casing 800 pounds of depleted uranium.’ Recall that the Air Force dropped 800 of these bombs in just the first two days of the war. The math: 800 bombs multiplied by 800 pounds of depleted uranium equal 640,000 pounds, or 320 tons of radioactive waste dumped on that country in just the first two days of devastation” (83). The impact is devastating. When DU hits something, it ignites, reaching temperatures between 3,000-5,000 degrees Celsius (5,432-9,032 degrees F). It goes through metal like a hot knife through butter, making it a superb military weapon. But is also releases radiation upon impact, poisoning all around it. Its tiny particles can be inhaled—people don’t have to touch irradiated materials. Thus, Iraqis are being poisoned by simply breathing the air! And, once inhaled, DU hardens, turning into insoluble pellets than cannot be excreted. DU poisoning is a literal death sentence. It not only kills, however, but it can damage human DNA—it’s the gift that keeps on giving, to generations and generations. Yet, radiation is an equal opportunity destroyer: it also poisons those in occupying armies. Evidence from the Gulf War I (“Desert Storm”) shows the impact on American troops. Sanders quotes Arthur Bernklau, who has extensively studied the problem: “Of the 580,400 soldiers who served in Gulf War I, 11,000 are now dead. By the year 2000, there were 325,000 on permanent medical disability. More than a decade later, more than half (56 percent) who served in Gulf War I have permanent medical problems.” Bernklau then points out that the disability rate for soldiers in Vietnam was 10 percent (87). Yet the impact is not just on Iraqis, or the soldiers who fought there. Sanders points out that, according to the London Sunday Times, radiation sensors in Britain reported a four-fold increase in airborne uranium just a few days after George W. Bush launched the March 19, 2003 attack on Iraq. That sounds bad enough, that the uranium can travel the approximately 2500 miles from Baghdad to London. But what Sanders does not note is that global weather does not travel east to west: it travels west to east. In other words, this uranium had to cross North America to get from Iraq to Britain! There is much more detailed information included in this small, highly accessible book. AK Press deserves our respect and support for publishing such a worthy volume: and this is one we each should purchase and urge others to do so as well. The biggest strength of this book is Sanders’ clarity: this man is, if you will permit, “on target.” He sees the problem being not just the illegal and immoral wars in Iraq, Afghanistan, etc. He sees the US military as being an essential part of the US Empire, along with the major multinational corporations. He sees the military as an institution as a threat to global environmental survival. He recognizes that politicians won’t address the problem; they are too incorporated in the US Empire. It says it is up to us, individually and collectively, in the US (primarily) and together with people around the world. Basically, his argument is this: the US military can continue to launch wars and continue killing people (including Americans) around the world, or we can end war, and devote resources to the well-being of people in this country and others around the world. The choice is our’s. But we also need to realize that if we let the US military continue on its path of continual war with its on-going quest for global domination, it will destroy all the humans, animals and vegetation on the planet. Your move, good people.
8,517
<h4><strong>Turns the environment—US militarism will destroys the biosphere even if every other issue were solved</h4><p></strong> Kim <strong>Scipes</strong>, Ph.D., is an Assistant Professor of Sociology at Purdue University North Central in Westville, Indiana, 20<strong>09</strong>, http://countercurrents.org/scipes291209.htm </p><p>As a US military veteran—USMC, 1969-73, who turned around while on active duty—I have been incredibly frustrated at the impotence of the anti-war movement in the United States to stop the wars in particularly Iraq, Afghanistan and, increasingly, Pakistan. I am, obviously, not alone. Many other people—veterans, as well as many more civilians—also share this frustration. Barry Sanders’ new book, The Green Zone, takes a different angle than any I’ve seen before, and I believe it’s an approach I believe we all need to consider: <u>Sanders focuses on the environmental costs of militarism, particularly those from the US military. Sanders recognizes the incredible threat by greenhouse gases to the worlds’ peoples well-being and, in fact, to our very survival.</u> [Percentage of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere has risen from 280 parts per million (ppm) before the industrial revolution started in 1750 to where the latest readings are 392 ppm—should it reach 450, the accompanying temperature rise would lead to uncontrollable melting of the tundra across Russia and Canada, and the release of untold amounts of methane: methane has 20 times greater impact on the atmosphere than carbon dioxide. James Hansen of NASA believes we must go below 350 ppm to prevent serious environmental damage worldwide—KS.] <u>Sanders also knows the environment is not just threatened by greenhouse gasses, but recognizes pollution of the water, air and soil as joining with greenhouse gases to imperil us all. Yet he makes an incredibly important point, trying to put things into perspective and to focus our attention: “… here’s the awful truth: even <mark>if every person</mark>, every <mark>automobile, and</mark> every <mark>factory</mark> suddenly <mark>emitted zero emissions, the Earth would still be headed head</mark> first and at <mark>full speed toward total disaster for one</mark> major <mark>reason. The [US] military</mark>—<mark>that</mark> voracious <mark>vampire</mark>—<mark>produces enough g</mark>reen<mark>h</mark>ouse <mark>g</mark>ases, <mark>by itself</mark>, <mark>to place the entire globe</mark>, with all its inhabitants large and small, <mark>in</mark> the most immanent <mark>danger of extinction</u></mark>” (p, 22). To put it plain language, that social institution that is said to protect Americans is, in fact, hastening our very extermination along with all the other people of the planet. Sanders addresses the military’s affects on the environment in many ways. He starts off with trying to figure out how much (fossil) fuel the military uses, with their resulting greenhouse emissions there from. Despite diligent efforts, he cannot find out specific numbers, so he is forced to estimate. After carefully working through different categories, he comes to what he calls a conservative estimate of 1 million barrels of oil a day, which translates to almost 20 million gallons each and every day! He puts this number into international perspective: “If that indeed turns out to be the case, <u>the <mark>U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates <mark>military</mark> <mark>would</mark> then <mark>rank in fuel consumption with countries like</mark> Iran, <mark>Indonesia</mark> and Spain.</u> It is truly an astonishing accomplishment, especially when one considers … that the military has only about 1.5 million troops on active duty, and Iran has a population of 66 million, Indonesia a whopping 235 million” (54) The cost, incidentally, is also quite high. He quotes a US Army General as estimating that the cost of this fuel averages $300 a gallon! (55) Yet, how does this contribute to global warming? He reports that the US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) estimates that “each gallon of gasoline produces 19.4 pounds of CO 2” (carbon dioxide). If his estimate of 1 million barrels of oil a day is correct, he writes, “then the combined armed forces sends into the atmosphere about 400 million pounds of greenhouse gases a day, or 200,000 tons. That totals 146 billion pounds a year—or 73 million tons of carbon a year” (67-68). And that’s just regarding fuel use. <u>Sanders further discusses the military’s impact on the environment. He talks about the <mark>impact of exploding bombs,</mark> cluster bombs, <mark>napalm, cannon rounds, depleted uranium, etc.</mark> He points out that the US military estimates they need about 1.5 billion rounds for their M-16 rifles a year. </u>He talks about the impact of US military bases around the world, including in the Philippines and Puerto Rico. To me, the most sickening chapter was the one on depleted uranium or DU. He explains, <u>“Depleted uranium is essentially U-238, the isotope after the fissionable isotope, U-235, has been extracted from uranium ore.” DU has a half-life of 4.7 billion years. He continues: “… a good deal of the country of <mark>Iraq,</mark> both its deserts and cities, <mark>hums with radioactivity</u></mark>. For since 1991, the US has been manufacturing ‘just about all [of its] bullets, tank shells, missiles, dumb bombs, smart bombs, and 500- and 2000-pound bombs, and everything else engineered to help our side in the war of Us against Them, [with] depleted uranium in it. Lots of depleted uranium. A single cruise missile, which weighs 3,000 pounds, carries within its casing 800 pounds of depleted uranium.’ Recall that the Air Force dropped 800 of these bombs in just the first two days of the war. The math: 800 bombs multiplied by 800 pounds of depleted uranium equal 640,000 pounds, or 320 tons of radioactive waste dumped on that country in just the first two days of devastation” (83). The impact is devastating. When DU hits something, it ignites, reaching temperatures between 3,000-5,000 degrees Celsius (5,432-9,032 degrees F). It goes through metal like a hot knife through butter, making it a superb military weapon. But is also releases radiation upon impact, poisoning all around it. Its tiny particles can be inhaled—people don’t have to touch irradiated materials. Thus, Iraqis are being poisoned by simply breathing the air! And, once inhaled, DU hardens, turning into insoluble pellets than cannot be excreted. DU poisoning is a literal death sentence. It not only kills, however, but it can damage human DNA—it’s the gift that keeps on giving, to generations and generations. Yet, radiation is an equal opportunity destroyer: it also poisons those in occupying armies. Evidence from the Gulf War I (“Desert Storm”) shows the impact on American troops. Sanders quotes Arthur Bernklau, who has extensively studied the problem: “Of the 580,400 soldiers who served in Gulf War I, 11,000 are now dead. By the year 2000, there were 325,000 on permanent medical disability. More than a decade later, more than half (56 percent) who served in Gulf War I have permanent medical problems.” Bernklau then points out that the disability rate for soldiers in Vietnam was 10 percent (87). Yet the impact is not just on Iraqis, or the soldiers who fought there. Sanders points out that, according to the London Sunday Times, radiation sensors in Britain reported a four-fold increase in airborne uranium just a few days after George W. Bush launched the March 19, 2003 attack on Iraq. That sounds bad enough, that the uranium can travel the approximately 2500 miles from Baghdad to London. But what Sanders does not note is that global weather does not travel east to west: it travels west to east. In other words, this uranium had to cross North America to get from Iraq to Britain! There is much more detailed information included in this small, highly accessible book. AK Press deserves our respect and support for publishing such a worthy volume: and this is one we each should purchase and urge others to do so as well. The biggest strength of this book is Sanders’ clarity: this man is, if you will permit, “on target<u>.” He sees the problem being not just the illegal and immoral wars in Iraq, Afghanistan, etc. He sees the US military as being an essential part of the US Empire, along with the major multinational corporations. He sees the military as an institution as a threat to global environmental survival.</u> He recognizes that <u>politicians won’t address the problem; they are too incorporated in the US Empire</u>. It says it is up to us, individually and collectively, in the US (primarily) and together with people around the world. Basically, his argument is this: <u><mark>the US military can continue to</mark> launch wars and continue <mark>kill</mark>ing <mark>people</mark> (including Americans) around the world, <mark>or we can end war, and devote resources to the well-being of people</mark> in this country and others around the world. The choice is our’s. But <mark>we</mark> also <mark>need</mark> <mark>to realize</mark> that <mark>if</mark> we let <mark>the US military continue on its path</mark> of continual war with its on-going quest for global domination, <mark>it will destroy all</mark> the <mark>humans, animals and vegetation on the planet.</mark> Your move<strong>, good people. </p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 1—Heg
430,544
3
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,038
Deal stops prolif and iran strike
Stephens, 11/14/13
Stephens, 11/14/13 – columnist for the Financial Times (Phillip, Financial Times, “The four big truths that are shaping the Iran talks” http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/af170df6-4d1c-11e3-bf32-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2kkvx15JT
Tehran’s acquisition of a bomb would set off a nuclear arms race that would see Saudi Arabia, Turkey and Egypt signing up to the nuclear club The nuclear non-proliferation treaty would be shattered. A future regional conflict could draw Israel into launching a pre-emptive nuclear strike This is not a region susceptible to cold war disciplines of deterrence neither a negotiated settlement nor air strikes can offer the rest of the world a watertight insurance policy. It should be possible to construct a deal that acts as a plausible restraint – and extends the timeframe for any breakout The best the international community can hope for is that, in return for a relaxation of sanctions, Iran will make a judgment that it is better off sticking with a threshold capability if Tehran does step back from the nuclear brink it will be because of its own calculation of the balance of advantage Iran now has a leadership that, faced with the severe and growing pain inflicted by sanctions, is prepared to talk Geneva can be counted a modest success The Geneva talks illuminated the shape of an interim agreement. Iran will not surrender the right it asserts to uranium enrichment, but will lower the level of enrichment from 20 per cent to 3 or 4 per cent It will suspend work on its heavy water reactor in Arak
a bomb set off arms race that would sign up the nuclear club The n p t would be shattered A conflict could draw Israel into a strike a deal acts as a restraint – and extends timeframe The best is in return for relaxation of sanctions, Iran will make a judgment that it is better off with threshold capability because of its own calculation Iran has leadership that is prepared to talk Iran will not surrender , but lower enrichment
The first of these is that Tehran’s acquisition of a bomb would be more than dangerous for the Middle East and for wider international security. It would most likely set off a nuclear arms race that would see Saudi Arabia, Turkey and Egypt signing up to the nuclear club. The nuclear non-proliferation treaty would be shattered. A future regional conflict could draw Israel into launching a pre-emptive nuclear strike. This is not a region obviously susceptible to cold war disciplines of deterrence. The second ineluctable reality is that Iran has mastered the nuclear cycle. How far it is from building a bomb remains a subject of debate. Different intelligence agencies give different answers. These depend in part on what the spooks actually know and in part on what their political masters want others to hear. The progress of an Iranian warhead programme is one of the known unknowns that have often wreaked havoc in this part of the world. Israel points to an imminent threat. European agencies are more relaxed, suggesting Tehran is still two years or so away from a weapon. Western diplomats broadly agree that Ayatollah Ali Khamenei has not taken a definitive decision to step over the line. What Iran has been seeking is what diplomats call a breakout capability – the capacity to dash to a bomb before the international community could effectively mobilise against it. The third fact – and this one is hard for many to swallow – is that neither a negotiated settlement nor the air strikes long favoured by Benjamin Netanyahu, Israel’s prime minister, can offer the rest of the world a watertight insurance policy. It should be possible to construct a deal that acts as a plausible restraint – and extends the timeframe for any breakout – but no amount of restrictions or intrusive monitoring can offer a certain guarantee against Tehran’s future intentions. By the same token, bombing Iran’s nuclear sites could certainly delay the programme, perhaps for a couple of years. But, assuming that even the hawkish Mr Netanyahu is not proposing permanent war against Iran, air strikes would not end it. You cannot bomb knowledge and technical expertise. To try would be to empower those in Tehran who say the regime will be safe only when, like North Korea, it has a weapon. So when Barack Obama says the US will never allow Iran to get the bomb he is indulging in, albeit understandable, wishful thinking. The best the international community can hope for is that, in return for a relaxation of sanctions, Iran will make a judgment that it is better off sticking with a threshold capability. To put this another way, if Tehran does step back from the nuclear brink it will be because of its own calculation of the balance of advantage. The fourth element in this dynamic is that Iran now has a leadership that, faced with the severe and growing pain inflicted by sanctions, is prepared to talk. There is nothing to say that Hassan Rouhani, the president, is any less hard-headed than previous Iranian leaders, but he does seem ready to weigh the options. Seen from this vantage point – and in spite of the inconclusive outcome – Geneva can be counted a modest success. Iran and the US broke the habit of more than 30 years and sat down to talk to each other. Know your enemy is a first rule of diplomacy – and of intelligence. John Kerry has his detractors but, unlike his predecessor Hillary Clinton, the US secretary of state understands that serious diplomacy demands a willingness to take risks. The Geneva talks illuminated the shape of an interim agreement. Iran will not surrender the right it asserts to uranium enrichment, but will lower the level of enrichment from 20 per cent to 3 or 4 per cent. It will suspend work on its heavy water reactor in Arak – a potential source of plutonium – negotiate about the disposal of some of its existing stocks of enriched uranium, and accept intrusive international inspections. A debate between the six powers about the strength and credibility of such pledges is inevitable, as is an argument with Tehran about the speed and scope of a run down of sanctions.
4,118
<h4>Deal stops prolif and iran strike</h4><p><strong>Stephens, 11/14/13 </strong>– columnist for the Financial Times (Phillip, Financial Times, “The four big truths that are shaping the Iran talks” http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/af170df6-4d1c-11e3-bf32-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2kkvx15JT</p><p>The first of these is that <u>Tehran’s acquisition of <mark>a bomb </mark>would</u> be more than dangerous for the Middle East and for wider international security. It would most likely <u><mark>set off </mark>a nuclear <mark>arms race</mark> <mark>that would </mark>see Saudi Arabia, Turkey and Egypt <mark>sign</mark>ing <mark>up </mark>to <mark>the nuclear club</u></mark>. <u><mark>The</mark> nuclear <mark>n</mark>on-<mark>p</mark>roliferation <mark>t</mark>reaty <mark>would be shattered</mark>. <mark>A</mark> future regional <mark>conflict could draw Israel into </mark>launching <mark>a</mark> pre-emptive nuclear <mark>strike</u></mark>. <u>This is not a region </u>obviously <u>susceptible to cold war disciplines of deterrence</u>. The second ineluctable reality is that Iran has mastered the nuclear cycle. How far it is from building a bomb remains a subject of debate. Different intelligence agencies give different answers. These depend in part on what the spooks actually know and in part on what their political masters want others to hear. The progress of an Iranian warhead programme is one of the known unknowns that have often wreaked havoc in this part of the world. Israel points to an imminent threat. European agencies are more relaxed, suggesting Tehran is still two years or so away from a weapon. Western diplomats broadly agree that Ayatollah Ali Khamenei has not taken a definitive decision to step over the line. What Iran has been seeking is what diplomats call a breakout capability – the capacity to dash to a bomb before the international community could effectively mobilise against it. The third fact – and this one is hard for many to swallow – is that <u>neither a negotiated settlement nor</u> the <u>air strikes</u> long favoured by Benjamin Netanyahu, Israel’s prime minister, <u>can offer the rest of the world a watertight insurance policy. It should be possible to construct <mark>a deal </mark>that <mark>acts as a </mark>plausible <mark>restraint – and extends </mark>the <mark>timeframe </mark>for any breakout</u> – but no amount of restrictions or intrusive monitoring can offer a certain guarantee against Tehran’s future intentions. By the same token, bombing Iran’s nuclear sites could certainly delay the programme, perhaps for a couple of years. But, assuming that even the hawkish Mr Netanyahu is not proposing permanent war against Iran, air strikes would not end it. You cannot bomb knowledge and technical expertise. To try would be to empower those in Tehran who say the regime will be safe only when, like North Korea, it has a weapon. So when Barack Obama says the US will never allow Iran to get the bomb he is indulging in, albeit understandable, wishful thinking. <u><mark>The best </mark>the international community can hope for <mark>is</mark> that, <mark>in return for</mark> a <mark>relaxation of sanctions,</mark> <mark>Iran will make a judgment that it is better off </mark>sticking <mark>with</mark> a <mark>threshold capability</u></mark>. To put this another way, <u>if Tehran does step back from the nuclear brink it will be <mark>because of its own calculation</mark> of the balance of advantage</u>. The fourth element in this dynamic is that <u><mark>Iran</mark> now <mark>has</mark> a <mark>leadership that</mark>, faced with the severe and growing pain inflicted by sanctions, <mark>is prepared to talk</u></mark>. There is nothing to say that Hassan Rouhani, the president, is any less hard-headed than previous Iranian leaders, but he does seem ready to weigh the options. Seen from this vantage point – and in spite of the inconclusive outcome – <u>Geneva can be counted a modest success</u>. Iran and the US broke the habit of more than 30 years and sat down to talk to each other. Know your enemy is a first rule of diplomacy – and of intelligence. John Kerry has his detractors but, unlike his predecessor Hillary Clinton, the US secretary of state understands that serious diplomacy demands a willingness to take risks. <u>The Geneva talks illuminated the shape of an interim agreement. <mark>Iran will not surrender</mark> the right it asserts to uranium enrichment<mark>, but </mark>will <mark>lower</mark> the level of <mark>enrichment</mark> from 20 per cent to 3 or 4 per cent</u>. <u>It will suspend work on its heavy water reactor in Arak</u> – a potential source of plutonium – negotiate about the disposal of some of its existing stocks of enriched uranium, and accept intrusive international inspections. A debate between the six powers about the strength and credibility of such pledges is inevitable, as is an argument with Tehran about the speed and scope of a run down of sanctions.</p>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Causes Prolif
178,292
102
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,039
Their insistence that their form of leadership is somehow benign proves the link – the exercise of American power, even when well-intentioned, exacerbates security dilemmas and ensures conflict.
Tang and Long 12
Tang and Long 12 [Shiping Tang and S.R. Joey Long, School of International Relations and Public Affairs, Fudan University America's military interventionism: A social evolutionary interpretation European Journal of International Relations September 2012 vol. 18 no. 3 509-538]
Because no country can be insulated from America’s exercise of its vast power, other states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if American intentions are not malevolent. America’s elites and public, informed by an ethnocentric sense of providence and self-righteousness cannot appreciate why other countries fear America’s enormous power and its promotion of supposedly universal beliefs. This apathy toward other countries’ fears inevitably exacerbates the security dilemma and spiral between America and other countries.
no country can be insulated from America’s exercise states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if intentions are not malevolent elites informed by ethnocentric self-righteousness, cannot appreciate why countries fear America’s power This apathy toward other countries’ fears exacerbates the security dilemma
Indeed, the United States has been able to behave in an abrasive and proselytizing manner internationally because geography and preponderant power affords it a comforting sense of security. While a state’s foreign policy is necessarily informed by a set of beliefs, active exportation of one’s beliefs through hard power inevitably makes the state very threatening to others that do not share those beliefs. Because no country can be insulated from America’s exercise of its vast power, other states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if American intentions are not malevolent. America’s blessing again becomes a curse to other states and ultimately to the United States as well. Meanwhile, America’s elites and public, informed by an ethnocentric sense of providence and self-righteousness, often cannot appreciate why other countries fear America’s enormous power and its promotion of its supposedly universal beliefs. This apathy toward other countries’ fears inevitably exacerbates the security dilemma and/or spiral between America and other countries.
1,083
<h4>Their insistence that their form of leadership is somehow benign proves the link – the exercise of American power, even when well-intentioned, exacerbates security dilemmas and ensures conflict.</h4><p><strong>Tang and Long 12</strong> [Shiping Tang and S.R. Joey Long, School of International Relations and Public Affairs, Fudan University America's military interventionism: A social evolutionary interpretation European Journal of International Relations September 2012 vol. 18 no. 3 509-538]</p><p>Indeed, the United States has been able to behave in an abrasive and proselytizing manner internationally because geography and preponderant power affords it a comforting sense of security. While a state’s foreign policy is necessarily informed by a set of beliefs, active exportation of one’s beliefs through hard power inevitably makes the state very threatening to others that do not share those beliefs. <u>Because <mark>no country can be insulated from America’s exercise</mark> of its vast power, other <mark>states</mark> <mark>invariably fear it and question its motives, even if</mark> American <mark>intentions are not malevolent</mark>.</u> America’s blessing again becomes a curse to other states and ultimately to the United States as well. Meanwhile, <u>America’s <mark>elites</mark> and public, <mark>informed by</mark> an <mark>ethnocentric</mark> sense of providence and <mark>self-righteousness</u>,</mark> often <u><mark>cannot appreciate why</mark> other <mark>countries fear America’s</mark> enormous <mark>power</mark> and its promotion of</u> its <u>supposedly universal beliefs. <mark>This apathy</mark> <mark>toward other countries’ fears</mark> inevitably <mark>exacerbates the</mark> <mark>security dilemma</mark> and</u>/or <u><strong>spiral between America and other countries.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
AT Benign
430,545
3
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,040
Above—AND—their evidence flows neg—concedes deal solves secret prolif.
International Peace, 11-4, their author
International Peace, 11-4, their author
a carefully constructed package would go a long way to ensuring that an Iranian attempt at sneak-out would fail
a carefully constructed package would go a long way to ensuring that an Iranian attempt at sneak-out would fail.
(James, “Who Cares about an Iranian Nuclear Breakout? Beware of an Atomic "Sneak-out"”, The National Interest, p. http://nationalinterest.org/feature/who-cares-about-iranian-nuclear-breakout-beware-atomic-sneak-11604) Interviews with Iranian scientists, without the presence of minders, could also be extremely helpful. No measure by itself would be a panacea, but a carefully constructed package would go a long way to ensuring that an Iranian attempt at sneak-out would fail.
477
<h4>Above—AND—their evidence flows neg—concedes <u>deal solves secret prolif</u><strong>.</h4><p>International Peace, 11-4, their author</p><p></strong>(James, “Who Cares about an Iranian Nuclear Breakout? Beware of an Atomic "Sneak-out"”, The National Interest, p. http://nationalinterest.org/feature/who-cares-about-iranian-nuclear-breakout-beware-atomic-sneak-11604) </p><p>Interviews with Iranian scientists, without the presence of minders, could also be extremely helpful. No measure by itself would be a panacea, but <u><mark>a carefully constructed package would go a long way to ensuring that an Iranian attempt at sneak-out would fail</u>.</p></mark>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Secret Prolif
430,546
1
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,041
And, if successful, apocalyptic representations of climate change lead to great power war – regional interventions and arms races
Brzoska 8
Brzoska (Inst. for Peace Research and Security Policy @ Hamburg) 8
(Micahel, “The Securitization of climate change and the power of conceptions of security” ISA Convention Paper) Originally a political conflict the confrontation became an existential conflict that was overwhelmingly addressed with military means, including the potential annihilation of humankind Climate change could meet a similar fate A political problem might be perceived as intractable necessitating the build-up of military forces The portrayal of climate change as a security problem could cause the richer countries in the global North to strengthen measures aimed at protecting them from the spillover of violent conflict from the poorer countries in the global South It could also be used by major powers as a justification for improving their military preparedness against the other major powers, leading to arms races This reaction would be counterproductive the financial means adapt to climate change will be reduced policy areas are in competition for scarce resources.
the confrontation became an existential conflict addressed with military means, including the potential annihilation of humankind Climate change could meet a similar fate A political problem perceived as intractable, necessitating the build-up of military forces The portrayal of climate change as a security problem could cause richer countries in the North to strengthen measures aimed at protecting them from the spillover of violent conflict from the South It could also be used by major powers as a justification for improving military preparedness leading to arms races This would be counterproductive financial means adapt to climate change will be reduced
(Micahel, “The Securitization of climate change and the power of conceptions of security” ISA Convention Paper) In the literature on securitization it is implied that when a problem is securitized it is difficult to limit this to an increase in attention and resources devoted to mitigating the problem (Brock 1997, Waever 1995). Securitization regularly leads to all-round ‘exceptionalism’ in dealing with the issue as well as to a shift in institutional localization towards ‘security experts’ (Bigot 2006), such as the military and police. Methods and instruments associated with these security organizations – such as more use of arms, force and violence – will gain in importance in the discourse on ‘what to do’. A good example of securitization was the period leading to the Cold War (Guzzini 2004 ). Originally a political conflict over the organization of societies, in the late 1940s, the East-West confrontation became an existential conflict that was overwhelmingly addressed with military means, including the potential annihilation of humankind. Efforts to alleviate the political conflict were, throughout most of the Cold War, secondary to improving military capabilities. Climate change could meet a similar fate. An essentially political problem concerning the distribution of the costs of prevention and adaptation and the losses and gains in income arising from change in the human environment might be perceived as intractable, thus necessitating the build-up of military and police forces to prevent it from becoming a major security problem. The portrayal of climate change as a security problem could, in particular, cause the richer countries in the global North, which are less affected by it, to strengthen measures aimed at protecting them from the spillover of violent conflict from the poorer countries in the global South that will be most affected by climate change. It could also be used by major powers as a justification for improving their military preparedness against the other major powers, thus leading to arms races. This kind of reaction to climate change would be counterproductive in various ways. Firstly, since more border protection, as well as more soldiers and arms, is expensive, the financial means compensate for the negative economic effects of reducing greenhouse gas emission and adapting to climate change will be reduced. Global military expenditure is again at the level of the height of the Cold War in real terms, reaching more than US $1,200 billion in 2006 or 3.5 percent of global income. While any estimate of the costs of mitigation (e.g. of restricting global warming to 2°C by 2050) and adaptation are speculative at the moment,1 they are likely to be substantial. While there is no necessary link between higher military expenditures and a lower willingness to spend on preventing and preparing for climate change, both policy areas are in competition for scarce resources.
2,969
<h4><strong>And, if successful, apocalyptic representations of climate change lead to great power war – regional interventions and arms races</h4><p>Brzoska </strong>(Inst. for Peace Research and Security Policy @ Hamburg) <strong>8 </p><p><u></strong>(Micahel, “The Securitization of climate change and the power of conceptions of security” ISA Convention Paper)</p><p></u>In the literature on securitization it is implied that when a problem is securitized it is difficult to limit this to an increase in attention and resources devoted to mitigating the problem (Brock 1997, Waever 1995). Securitization regularly leads to all-round ‘exceptionalism’ in dealing with the issue as well as to a shift in institutional localization towards ‘security experts’ (Bigot 2006), such as the military and police. Methods and instruments associated with these security organizations – such as more use of arms, force and violence – will gain in importance in the discourse on ‘what to do’. A good example of securitization was the period leading to the Cold War (Guzzini 2004 ). <u>Originally a political conflict</u> over the organization of societies, in the late 1940s, <u><mark>the</u></mark> East-West <u><mark>confrontation became an existential conflict</mark> that was overwhelmingly <mark>addressed</mark> <mark>with military means, including the potential annihilation of humankind</u></mark>. Efforts to alleviate the political conflict were, throughout most of the Cold War, secondary to improving military capabilities. <u><mark>Climate change could meet a similar fate</u></mark>. <u><mark>A</u></mark>n essentially <u><mark>political problem</u></mark> concerning the distribution of the costs of prevention and adaptation and the losses and gains in income arising from change in the human environment <u>might be <mark>perceived as intractable</u>,</mark> thus <u><mark>necessitating</mark> <mark>the build-up of military</u></mark> and police <u><mark>forces</u></mark> to prevent it from becoming a major security problem. <u><mark>The portrayal of climate change as a security problem</mark> <mark>could</u></mark>, in particular, <u><mark>cause</mark> the <mark>richer countries in the</mark> global <mark>North</u></mark>, which are less affected by it, <u><mark>to strengthen measures aimed at protecting them from the spillover of violent conflict from</mark> the poorer countries in <mark>the</mark> global <mark>South</u></mark> that will be most affected by climate change. <u><mark>It could also be used by major powers as a justification for improving</mark> their <mark>military preparedness</mark> against the other major powers, </u>thus<u> <mark>leading to arms races</u></mark>. <u><mark>This</u></mark> kind of <u>reaction</u> to climate change <u><mark>would be counterproductive</u></mark> in various ways. Firstly, since more border protection, as well as more soldiers and arms, is expensive, <u>the <mark>financial means</u></mark> compensate for the negative economic effects of reducing greenhouse gas emission and <u><mark>adapt</u></mark>ing <u><mark>to climate change will be reduced</u></mark>. Global military expenditure is again at the level of the height of the Cold War in real terms, reaching more than US $1,200 billion in 2006 or 3.5 percent of global income. While any estimate of the costs of mitigation (e.g. of restricting global warming to 2°C by 2050) and adaptation are speculative at the moment,1 they are likely to be substantial. While there is no necessary link between higher military expenditures and a lower willingness to spend on preventing and preparing for climate change, both <u><strong>policy areas are in competition for scarce resources.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 2—Climate
202,415
35
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,042
Obama’s only spending PC on foreign policy issues- that means Iran- it comes first
VOA 1/1
VOA 1/1/2015 (Obama, Republican Congress Likely to Clash on Global Affairs, http://www.voanews.com/content/obama-to-confront-republican-congress-on-global-affairs/2581620.html)
Congress will weigh in on global hotspots and America’s response to them when lawmakers return to Washington next week Conflicts from Ukraine to the Middle East are on legislators’ minds - as are high-profile international initiatives undertaken by Obama negotiations on Iran’s nuclear program resume one week after Congress gavels in makers will consider tougher sanctions on Tehran There will be a desire very quickly for Congress to weigh in on the Iran deal Obama is not immune to dissent from his own Democratic Party The president could have as many or more problems on the left, with Democrats, on international and national security issues as he could have with Republicans the president appears determined to leave a stamp on America’s outreach to the world
Congress will weigh in on global hotspots and America’s response to them when lawmakers return to Washington next week. Conflicts from Ukraine to the Middle East are on legislators’ minds - as are high-profile international initiatives undertaken b Obama negotiations on Iran’s nuclear program resume one week after Congress gavels in lawmakers will consider tougher sanctions on Tehran There will be a desire very quickly or Congress to weigh in on the Iran deal he president appears determined to leave a stamp on America’s outreach to the world.
The new, entirely Republican-led U.S. Congress will weigh in on global hotspots and America’s response to them when lawmakers return to Washington next week. Conflicts from Ukraine to the Middle East are on legislators’ minds - as are high-profile international initiatives undertaken by President Barack Obama. International negotiations on Iran’s nuclear program resume one week after Congress gavels in. Skeptics, like Republican Senator Bob Corker, have said lawmakers will consider tougher sanctions on Tehran in case negotiations fail. “There will be a desire very quickly after the first of the year for Congress to weigh in on the topic in some form or fashion. Congress will want to weigh in on the Iran deal,” he said. Congressional wariness over Iran’s nuclear ambitions is not new. What no one anticipated just weeks ago is that Congress would wrestle with President Obama’s surprise diplomatic opening with Cuba. Ending the U.S. embargo of Cuba would require an act of Congress, something Democratic Senator Ben Cardin supports. “There will be a need for Congress to take action, hopefully, as we move to a new chapter in our Cuban relations. And it is going to be an interesting debate,” said Cardin. Republican Senator Marco Rubio is ready for that debate. “This Congress is not going to lift the embargo,” he said. “The White House has conceded everything and gained little [from Havana]. They gained no commitment on the part of the Cuban regime to freedom of the press, or freedom of speech, or elections.” Republicans want to be seen as offering constructive criticism, according to political scientist William Howell. “On the one hand, they want to underscore failings on the part of the Obama administration, and on the other hand, they need to be seen as a responsible, mature party that can lead the nation,” said Howell. Majority status in both houses of Congress will give Republicans a louder megaphone to critique the president’s handling of crises from Ukraine to the Islamic State insurgency in Iraq and Syria. Obama is also not immune to dissent from his own Democratic Party, according to political analyst Stuart Rothenberg. “The president could have as many or more problems on the left, with Democrats, on international and national security issues as he could have with Republicans. There are lots of Democrats who are more concerned about the U.S. recommitting troops,” said Rothenberg. Whatever Congress’ concerns, the president appears determined to leave a stamp on America’s outreach to the world. In a recent interview, he said: “I believe in diplomacy. I believe in dialogue. I believe in engagement.”
2,643
<h4>Obama’s only spending PC on foreign policy issues- that means Iran- it comes first</h4><p><strong>VOA 1/1</strong>/2015 (Obama, Republican Congress Likely to Clash on Global Affairs, http://www.voanews.com/content/obama-to-confront-republican-congress-on-global-affairs/2581620.html)</p><p>The new, entirely Republican-led U.S. <u><mark>Congress will weigh in on global hotspots and America’s response to them when lawmakers return to Washington next week</u>. <u>Conflicts from Ukraine to the Middle East are on legislators’ minds - as are high-profile international initiatives undertaken b</mark>y</u> President Barack <u><mark>Obama</u></mark>. International <u><mark>negotiations on Iran’s nuclear program resume one week after Congress gavels in</u></mark>. Skeptics, like Republican Senator Bob Corker, have said <mark>law<u>makers will consider tougher sanctions on Tehran</u></mark> in case negotiations fail. “<u><strong><mark>There will be a desire very quickly</mark> </u></strong>after the first of the year <u><strong>f<mark>or Congress to weigh in</u></strong></mark> on the topic in some form or fashion. Congress will want to weigh in <u><strong><mark>on the Iran deal</u></strong></mark>,” he said. Congressional wariness over Iran’s nuclear ambitions is not new. What no one anticipated just weeks ago is that Congress would wrestle with President Obama’s surprise diplomatic opening with Cuba. Ending the U.S. embargo of Cuba would require an act of Congress, something Democratic Senator Ben Cardin supports. “There will be a need for Congress to take action, hopefully, as we move to a new chapter in our Cuban relations. And it is going to be an interesting debate,” said Cardin. Republican Senator Marco Rubio is ready for that debate. “This Congress is not going to lift the embargo,” he said. “The White House has conceded everything and gained little [from Havana]. They gained no commitment on the part of the Cuban regime to freedom of the press, or freedom of speech, or elections.” Republicans want to be seen as offering constructive criticism, according to political scientist William Howell. “On the one hand, they want to underscore failings on the part of the Obama administration, and on the other hand, they need to be seen as a responsible, mature party that can lead the nation,” said Howell. Majority status in both houses of Congress will give Republicans a louder megaphone to critique the president’s handling of crises from Ukraine to the Islamic State insurgency in Iraq and Syria. <u>Obama is</u> also <u>not immune to dissent from his own Democratic Party</u>, according to political analyst Stuart Rothenberg. “<u>The president could have as many or more problems on the left, with Democrats, on international and national security issues as he could have with Republicans</u>. There are lots of Democrats who are more concerned about the U.S. recommitting troops,” said Rothenberg. Whatever Congress’ concerns, <u><strong>t<mark>he president appears determined to leave a stamp on America’s outreach to the world</u></strong>.</mark> In a recent interview, he said: “I believe in diplomacy. I believe in dialogue. I believe in engagement.” </p>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Secret Prolif
430,548
6
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,043
The obsession with credibility is self-defeating – ensures serial policy failure.
Lebow 11 [Richard Ned, IR at Dartmouth, “Aggressive Democracies,” St Antony’s International Review 6, no. 2 (2011): 120–33]
Lebow 11 [Richard Ned, IR at Dartmouth, “Aggressive Democracies,” St Antony’s International Review 6, no. 2 (2011): 120–33]
presidents frequently sought to commit the country to activist policies through membership in international institutions that involved long-term obligations the imf and nato) executive actions intervention in the Korean War, and sending Marines to Lebanon and congressional resolutions secured on the basis of false info (the Gulf of Tonkin and Iraq War reso- lutions). concern for credibility promoted ill-considered and open-ended commitments like Vietnam and Iraq that led to public opposition and the congressional constraints that subsequent presidents considered detrimental to presidential credibility. Instead of prompting a reassessment of national security strategy, these setbacks appear to have strengthened the commitment of presidents and advisers to breaking free of constraints and asserting leadership in the world, thus ushering in a new cycle of overextension, failure, and renewed constraints.
null
Unlike other parvenu powers, the constraints on the United States were more internal than external. Congress, not other powers, kept American presidents from playing a more active role in European affairs in the 1920s and 1930s and forced a withdrawal from Indochina in the 1970s. The United States was never spurned or humiliated by other pow- ers, but some American presidents and their advisers did feel humili- ated by the constraints imposed upon them domestically. They frequently sought to commit the country to activist policies through membership in international institutions that involved long-term obligations (for ex- ample, the imf and nato), executive actions (for example, the 1940 destroyer deal, intervention in the Korean War, and sending Marines to Lebanon in 1958), and congressional resolutions secured on the basis of false or misleading information (the Gulf of Tonkin and Iraq War reso- lutions). Ironically, concern for credibility promoted ill-considered and open-ended commitments like Vietnam and Iraq that later led to public opposition and the congressional constraints that subsequent American presidents considered detrimental to presidential credibility. Instead of prompting a reassessment of national security strategy, these setbacks appear to have strengthened the commitment of at least some presidents and their advisers to breaking free of these constraints and asserting leadership in the world, thus ushering in a new cycle of overextension, failure, and renewed constraints.
1,597
<h4><strong>The obsession with credibility is self-defeating – ensures serial policy failure.</h4><p>Lebow 11<u> [Richard Ned, IR at Dartmouth, “Aggressive Democracies,” St Antony’s International Review 6, no. 2 (2011): 120–33]</p><p></u></strong>Unlike other parvenu powers, the constraints on the United States were more internal than external. Congress, not other powers, kept American presidents from playing a more active role in European affairs in the 1920s and 1930s and forced a withdrawal from Indochina in the 1970s. The United States was never spurned or humiliated by other pow- ers, but some American <u>presidents</u> and their advisers did feel humili- ated by the constraints imposed upon them domestically. They <u>frequently sought to commit the country to activist policies through membership in international institutions that involved long-term obligations</u> (for ex- ample, <u>the imf and nato)</u>, <u>executive actions</u> (for example, the 1940 destroyer deal, <u>intervention in the Korean War, and sending Marines to Lebanon</u> in 1958), <u>and congressional resolutions secured on the basis of false</u> or misleading <u>info</u>rmation<u> (the Gulf of Tonkin and Iraq War reso- lutions).</u> Ironically, <u>concern for credibility promoted ill-considered and open-ended commitments like Vietnam and Iraq that</u> later <u>led to public opposition and the congressional constraints that subsequent</u> American <u>presidents considered detrimental to presidential credibility. Instead of prompting a reassessment of national security strategy, these setbacks appear to have strengthened the commitment of</u> at least some <u>presidents and</u> their <u>advisers to breaking free of</u> these <u>constraints and asserting leadership in the world, thus ushering in a <strong>new cycle of overextension, failure, and renewed constraints.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 2—Climate
193,144
5
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,044
Other issues either come after the Iran vote or don’t actually involve PC use- our Politico ev says Obama is actively engaging Dems in the Senate to make sure they sustain a veto- he’s only engaging on foreign policy not things like Keystone
IBT 12/19
IBT 12/19/2014 (International Business Times, President Barack Obama Plans For Corporate Tax Reform, Keystone XL; Will 'Work With' Congress, http://www.ibtimes.com/president-barack-obama-plans-corporate-tax-reform-keystone-xl-will-work-congress-1763795)
Obama said he would stay engaged with Congress as they debate his decision to relax the embargo against Cuba he made clear that he won't just sit back Obama also hinted at the way he could play the biggest role in the legislative process: by using his veto pen. A veto of Keystone would remind Washington how very relevant the president still is.
Obama said he would stay engaged with Congress as they debate his decision to relax the embargo against Cuba he made clear that he won't just sit back. Obama also hinted at the way he could play the biggest role in the legislative process: by using his veto pen A veto of Keystone would remind Washington how very relevant the president still is.
Obama also said he would stay engaged with Congress as they debate his decision to relax the embargo against Cuba. To actually lift the embargo, Obama needs Congress -- and is unlikely to get the support. But he made clear that he won't just sit back. Obama also hinted at the way he could play the biggest role in the legislative process: by using his veto pen. Asked about the Keystone XL pipeline, a controversial proposal to build a connector from Canada to the Gulf Coast, Obama offered his most negative comments on the pipeline to date. He said the pipeline wouldn’t actually help Americans seeking lower-priced gasoline, but would help only the Canadians. He didn't explicitly promise to veto the pipeline, but his tone more than hinted that he would. Obama’s growing opposition to Keystone won’t have to wait long to play out. Sen. Mitch McConnell, R-Ky., who will become Senate majority leader in January, has vowed to make authorizing the pipeline the first bill the Senate votes on. A veto of Keystone would remind Washington how very relevant the president still is.
1,079
<h4>Other issues either come after the Iran vote or don’t actually involve PC use- our Politico ev says Obama is actively engaging Dems in the Senate to make sure they sustain a veto- he’s only engaging on foreign policy not things like Keystone</h4><p><strong>IBT 12/19</strong>/2014 (International Business Times, President Barack Obama Plans For<u> Corporate Tax Reform, Keystone XL; Will 'Work With' Congress, http://www.ibtimes.com/president-barack-obama-plans-corporate-tax-reform-keystone-xl-will-work-congress-1763795)</p><p><mark>Obama</u></mark> also <u><mark>said he would stay engaged with Congress as they debate his decision to relax the embargo against Cuba</u></mark>. To actually lift the embargo, Obama needs Congress -- and is unlikely to get the support. But <u><mark>he made clear that he won't just sit back</u>. <u>Obama also hinted at the way he could play the biggest role in the legislative process: by using his veto pen</mark>.</u> Asked about the Keystone XL pipeline, a controversial proposal to build a connector from Canada to the Gulf Coast, Obama offered his most negative comments on the pipeline to date. He said the pipeline wouldn’t actually help Americans seeking lower-priced gasoline, but would help only the Canadians. He didn't explicitly promise to veto the pipeline, but his tone more than hinted that he would. Obama’s growing opposition to Keystone won’t have to wait long to play out. Sen. Mitch McConnell, R-Ky., who will become Senate majority leader in January, has vowed to make authorizing the pipeline the first bill the Senate votes on. <u><mark>A veto of Keystone would remind Washington how very relevant the president still is.</p></u></mark>
1NR
adv 1
A2: Secret Prolif
430,549
2
17,067
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
565,285
N
Hurricanedebates2015
1
Indiana Tally-Liu
Weil
Ban OG CP Politics - Iran (2NR) Security K Heg bad (2NR)
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round1.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,045
“Inevitable competition”
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4><strong>“Inevitable competition” </h4></strong>
1nr
null
Link 4—China
430,547
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,046
Chinese threat mentality is racist and causes serial policy failure and war
Wei 12
Wei (Master’s at Dartmouth College) 12
The American China threat mentality has become an effective tool that perpetuates American exceptionalist practice China threat mentality evolved from racial nativism McCarthyist extremism and American exceptionalism The climax was the Chinese Exclusion Act With growing interdependence and interweaving economies, America can no longer operate its relations with China by virtue of the American China threat mentality and the dichotomous view of the world , lack of historical perspective and a completely shallow understanding of the roots of Chinese culture will only misguide America and create more problems than solve this threat was a selfcreated and selffulfilling fallacy predicated on the paranoiac aspect of American politics, which will only perpetuate actual conflicts or even wars.
The American China threat mentality has become a tool that perpetuates American exceptionalist practice With growing interdependence America can no longer operate its relations with China by virtue of the American China threat mentality lack of historical perspective and shallow understanding of Chinese culture will only misguide America and create more problems than solve this threat was a selfcreated and selffulfilling fallacy predicated on paranoiac politics, which will perpetuate actual wars
(Li Juan, THE AMERICAN CHINA THREAT MENTALITY, Master’s Thesis in Liberal Studies, March 2012, pg. 77-79) The American China threat mentality has become an effective tool that perpetuates American exceptionalist practice in respect to U.S. relations with China and their dichotomous view of the world. It also helps shape the future trajectory of ChinaU.S. relations.¶ The American China threat mentality basically evolved from three major trends including racial nativism in the late nineteen century, McCarthyist extremism in the Cold War and the new American exceptionalism in the postColdWar era. This evolution started in the late nineteenth century when racial nativism was in full swing, cultivating the fear of the Chinese immigrants. The climax of this nativist movement was the 1882 Chinese Exclusion Act. This fear and exclusion of the Chinese immediately morphed into the fear of Communism during the Cold War. McCarthyism definitely culminated in this paranoia of Communism or Chinese communism in particular. This extremist mindset and practice continued after the Cold War and was further reflected in the new American exceptionalism which supplied the American China threat mentality with the friendorfoe binary opposition and the exceptionalist norm that promoted the American political model and legitimized its transgressions of and exemptions from the rule of law. Moreover, as suggested by Galtung's oscillation model, Americans' misunderstanding of the stark realities of Chinese politics and economy from 1949 to 1958 also enhanced Americans' misperceptions of China and further contributed to this China threat mentality.¶ Grounded on the friendorfoe rationale and exceptionalist norm, the American China threat mentality not only was reflected in American public opinion of China as well as U.S.China policy, but also found its way into the discourse of American mainstream media and scholarly works. The scrutiny of the media discourse and scholarly publications concerning the four pivotal incidents in the history of ChinaU.S. relations reveals that mass media reified the American China threat mentality by virtue of using those events as a way to revive Americans' Cold War memory, criticize the Chinese government and therefore accentuate the enemy image of the Chinese government and communism.¶ In a bigger picture, the American China threat mentality followed a zigzag pattern similar to Galtung's oscillation model. This pattern featured alternating periods of the waxing and waning of the China threat mentality, corresponding to the fluctuation of American public opinion on China. To be specific, the waxing of this China threat mentality was parallel to the 9year distribution period and the waning to the 9year growth period.¶ In a similar fashion, ChinaU.S. relations showed a curvy pattern as well. From the confrontation and containment in the 1950s to the moderate improvements in the bilateral ties between the two in the 1960s, ChinaU.S. relations fluctuated widely. From the nascent opening contacts and rapprochement in 1970s to the increasing military and economic cooperation in the 1980s, the fluctuation of ChinaU.S. relations continued. From the strategic engagement in the 1990s to the widespread concerns over China's future economic trajectory and military prowess in the 2000s, ChinaU.S. relations oscillated in the same manner. With a clear sight on the similar zigzag patterns of the American China threat mentality and ChinaU.S. relations, one can predict that ChinaU.S. relations will continue to fluctuate the conceivable future.¶ With growing interdependence and interweaving economies, America can no longer operate its relations with China by virtue of the American China threat mentality and the dichotomous view of the world. It will be in the interest of our nations to seek common ground while reserving our differences. Moreover, lack of historical perspective and a completely shallow understanding of the roots of Chinese culture in Confucianism, Buddhism and Taoism will only misguide America and create more problems than solve.¶ Additionally, the misperception of Americans in viewing all Communism as the same lacks the understanding that postCultural Revolution communism in China was a system that while flawed in some ways, worked for the Chinese people. Americans did not dare to admit that the communism at that time in China was actually saving a country of over 500 million people'97 from foreign oppression, domestic tyranny, constant warfare and starvation. It was Americans' imperative in post World War II to contain all of communism in the world which led to American policy seeking to ring China with a circle of strategic holdings. Another reason for America perceiving communism in the world and Chinese communism in particular as a threat was that communism was frequently linked to notables such as Stalin, and this threat of communism was a selfcreated and selffulfilling fallacy predicated on the paranoiac aspect of American politics, which will only perpetuate actual conflicts or even wars.
5,088
<h4><strong>Chinese threat mentality is racist and causes serial policy failure and war</h4><p>Wei</strong> (Master’s at Dartmouth College) <strong>12</p><p></strong>(Li Juan, THE AMERICAN CHINA THREAT MENTALITY, Master’s Thesis in Liberal Studies, March 2012, pg. 77-79)</p><p><u><mark>The American China threat mentality has become a</mark>n effective <mark>tool that perpetuates American</mark> <mark>exceptionalist practice</u></mark> in respect to U.S. relations with China and their dichotomous view of the world. It also helps shape the future trajectory of ChinaU.S. relations.¶ The American <u>China threat mentality</u> basically <u>evolved from</u> three major trends including <u>racial nativism</u> in the late nineteen century, <u>McCarthyist extremism</u> in the Cold War <u>and</u> the new <u>American exceptionalism</u> in the postColdWar era. This evolution started in the late nineteenth century when racial nativism was in full swing, cultivating the fear of the Chinese immigrants. <u>The climax</u> of this nativist movement <u>was the</u> 1882 <u>Chinese Exclusion Act</u>. This fear and exclusion of the Chinese immediately morphed into the fear of Communism during the Cold War. McCarthyism definitely culminated in this paranoia of Communism or Chinese communism in particular. This extremist mindset and practice continued after the Cold War and was further reflected in the new American exceptionalism which supplied the American China threat mentality with the friendorfoe binary opposition and the exceptionalist norm that promoted the American political model and legitimized its transgressions of and exemptions from the rule of law. Moreover, as suggested by Galtung's oscillation model, Americans' misunderstanding of the stark realities of Chinese politics and economy from 1949 to 1958 also enhanced Americans' misperceptions of China and further contributed to this China threat mentality.¶ Grounded on the friendorfoe rationale and exceptionalist norm, the American China threat mentality not only was reflected in American public opinion of China as well as U.S.China policy, but also found its way into the discourse of American mainstream media and scholarly works. The scrutiny of the media discourse and scholarly publications concerning the four pivotal incidents in the history of ChinaU.S. relations reveals that mass media reified the American China threat mentality by virtue of using those events as a way to revive Americans' Cold War memory, criticize the Chinese government and therefore accentuate the enemy image of the Chinese government and communism.¶ In a bigger picture, the American China threat mentality followed a zigzag pattern similar to Galtung's oscillation model. This pattern featured alternating periods of the waxing and waning of the China threat mentality, corresponding to the fluctuation of American public opinion on China. To be specific, the waxing of this China threat mentality was parallel to the 9year distribution period and the waning to the 9year growth period.¶ In a similar fashion, ChinaU.S. relations showed a curvy pattern as well. From the confrontation and containment in the 1950s to the moderate improvements in the bilateral ties between the two in the 1960s, ChinaU.S. relations fluctuated widely. From the nascent opening contacts and rapprochement in 1970s to the increasing military and economic cooperation in the 1980s, the fluctuation of ChinaU.S. relations continued. From the strategic engagement in the 1990s to the widespread concerns over China's future economic trajectory and military prowess in the 2000s, ChinaU.S. relations oscillated in the same manner. With a clear sight on the similar zigzag patterns of the American China threat mentality and ChinaU.S. relations, one can predict that ChinaU.S. relations will continue to fluctuate the conceivable future.¶ <u><mark>With growing interdependence</mark> and interweaving economies, <mark>America can no longer operate its relations with China by virtue of the American China threat mentality</mark> and the dichotomous view of the world</u>. It will be in the interest of our nations to seek common ground while reserving our differences. Moreover<u>, <mark>lack of historical perspective and</mark> a completely <mark>shallow understanding of</mark> the roots of <mark>Chinese culture</u></mark> in Confucianism, Buddhism and Taoism <u><mark>will only misguide America and create more problems than solve</u></mark>.¶ Additionally, the misperception of Americans in viewing all Communism as the same lacks the understanding that postCultural Revolution communism in China was a system that while flawed in some ways, worked for the Chinese people. Americans did not dare to admit that the communism at that time in China was actually saving a country of over 500 million people'97 from foreign oppression, domestic tyranny, constant warfare and starvation. It was Americans' imperative in post World War II to contain all of communism in the world which led to American policy seeking to ring China with a circle of strategic holdings. Another reason for America perceiving communism in the world and Chinese communism in particular as a threat was that communism was frequently linked to notables such as Stalin, and <u><mark>this threat</u></mark> of communism <u><mark>was</u> <u>a selfcreated and selffulfilling fallacy predicated on</mark> the <mark>paranoiac</mark> aspect of American <mark>politics, which will</mark> only <mark>perpetuate actual</mark> conflicts or even <mark>wars<strong></mark>.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 4—China
430,519
5
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,047
It’s racist and leads to interventionism
Barnett 2k
Barnett (Senior Lecturer, School of Anthropology, Geography, and Environmental Studies, University of Melbourne; Ph.D., Centre for Resource and Environmental Studies) 2k
violent conflict over scarce resources scripts the 'South' as primeval Other, and as a consequence suggests the imposition of the North to maintain order we see most clearly the deployment of environment in the rewriting of security to justify longstanding interventions in regions of strategic importance, particularly the Middle East the environment-conflict literature reflects the intermingling of neorealist and liberal theories in North American security discours
null
(Jon, “Destabilizing the Environment-Conflict Thesis,” Review of International Studies 26(2): 271–288) The argument that environmental degradation will induce violent conflict over scarce resources recasts ecological problems in mainstream international relations terms; it scripts the 'South' as primeval Other, and as a consequence suggests the imposition of the North to maintain order. The water wars thesis is no less ethnocentric in outlook, and it is here that we see most clearly the deployment of environment in the rewriting of security to justify longstanding interventions in regions of strategic importance, particularly the Middle East. That it is uncon vincing in its assertion that there will be large scale violent conflict over water further highlights this article's claim that the environment-conflict thesis is a poor theoretical justification for security business-as-usual. The selective interpretation continues in the argument that when population growth exceeds ecological limits, conflict will ensue. Here, the most immediate development and human security issues are peripheral to strategic concerns about civil conflicts and refugees. Again, the interpretation is of the South, by the North. As a body of theory, the environment-conflict literature reflects the intermingling of neorealist and liberal theories in North American security discourse, a confluence which excludes alternative critical perspectives and which, ironically in the case of environmental security, serves to marginalize the insights of a Green theory. At this point some further critical observations about environment-conflict theory are warranted.
1,681
<h4><strong>It’s racist and leads to interventionism </h4><p>Barnett</strong> (Senior Lecturer, School of Anthropology, Geography, and Environmental Studies, University of Melbourne; Ph.D., Centre for Resource and Environmental Studies) <strong>2k</strong> </p><p>(Jon, “Destabilizing the Environment-Conflict Thesis,” Review of International Studies 26(2): 271–288)</p><p>The argument that environmental degradation will induce <u>violent conflict over scarce resources</u> recasts ecological problems in mainstream international relations terms; it <u>scripts the 'South' as primeval Other, and as a consequence suggests the imposition of the North to maintain order</u>. The water wars thesis is no less ethnocentric in outlook, and it is here that <u>we see most clearly the deployment of environment in the rewriting of security to justify longstanding interventions in regions of strategic importance, particularly the Middle East</u>. That it is uncon vincing in its assertion that there will be large scale violent conflict over water further highlights this article's claim that the environment-conflict thesis is a poor theoretical justification for security business-as-usual. The selective interpretation continues in the argument that when population growth exceeds ecological limits, conflict will ensue. Here, the most immediate development and human security issues are peripheral to strategic concerns about civil conflicts and refugees. Again, the interpretation is of the South, by the North. As a body of theory, <u>the environment-conflict literature reflects the intermingling of neorealist and liberal theories in North American security discours</u>e, a confluence which excludes alternative critical perspectives and which, ironically in the case of environmental security, serves to marginalize the insights of a Green theory. At this point<strong> some further critical observations about environment-conflict theory are warranted. </p></strong>
1nr
null
Link 5—Resource Wars
226,941
5
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,048
Floyd’s methodology makes security all-encompassing – ensures the logic of war permeates their politics and turns their specificity claims.
Rampp 9
Rampp 9 [Benjamin, University of Tübingen, Interdepartmental Centre for Ethics in the Sciences and Humanities (IZEW). Insecurity by Impreciseness Towards a Specific Concept of Security http://www.inter-disciplinary.net/ptb/wvw/wvw5/Rampp%20paper.pdf]
Floyd’s reasoning is not without problems. because of its lacking analytical preciseness the human security approach underachieves politically and at- tains results opposite to its goals. all relevant issues suffer from human security’s arbitrariness and are handled following the logic of security security becomes the ultimate principle of the social world Thus the logic of security is extended to other social fields, which lose specificity different situations are treated in a uniform way that might be counterproduc- tive the logic of war could be replayed metaphorically and extended to other sectors. When this happens the structure of the game is still derived from war.” (Wæver 1995: 54)
Floyd’s reasoning is not without problems. because of its lacking analytical preciseness the human security approach underachieves politically and at- tains results opposite to its goals. all relevant issues suffer from human security’s arbitrariness and are handled following the logic of security security becomes the ultimate principle of the social world Thus the logic of security is extended to other social fields, which lose specificity different situations are treated in a uniform way that might be counterproduc- tive the logic of war could be replayed metaphorically and extended to other sectors. When this happens the structure of the game is still derived from war.”
Although I encourage the combination of the human security and the securitization approach, I disagree with Floyd’s conclusion. Whereas she demonstrates that human security is also a form of securitization, she contents with the idea that both concepts just have different orien- tations: “Rather, each is important in its own unique way: one contributing to our understand- ing of how security is practiced, the other – on occasion and if successful – to its practice.” (Floyd 2007: 45f.). I will show in the following, that this reasoning is not without problems. 3 A criticism of the (broad) human security approach 3.1 The interconnectedness of the analytical and the political dimension I think however, that the approaches cannot be separated easily – even though Floyd ex- presses this correctly rather carefully; rather it shows, that because of its lacking analytical preciseness the human security approach underachieves also politically and respectively at- tains results opposite to its actual goals. Although it seems plausible that human security (in its broad interpretation) as general norma- tive-ethical position is of interest – it is however, not any more concrete than the Universal Declaration of Human Rights and thus holds little additional benefit. It clarifies that these human rights are part of security; by interpreting security in an extensively broad degree, hu- man security cannot surpass such a declaration and add to practical use. Because of its impre- ciseness, human security cannot be the aim in the sense of a concrete, political basis; exact statements which would render human security a meaningful political category are not con- tained in this concept. Defining human security as “political leitmotif” (Werthes/Bosold 2005, 2006) seems therefore exaggerated. Human security is even less a political route to this objective, since the concept exhibits too many weaknesses as a guideline for actions. Because what happens is simply the following: well-being or the good life are formulated as desirable goals and then immediately defined as security matters. This does not result in any additional insight (who doesn’t strive for well- being in general?), but creates the problem that from now on, all relevant issues suffer from human security’s arbitrariness and are handled following the logic of security – which is quite different to e.g. the logic of economic, food, health, environmental, or social issues. When this happens, dangerous consequences – intended or not – might occur. In this context, security becomes the ultimate principle of the social world (Wæver 1995: 48). Thus the logic of security is extended to other social fields, which lose specificity however (Wæver 1995: 50). If, for example, questions of human development or development of de- mocracy are seen through the eyes of security, then these questions will also be answered from a security’s point of view (and not in respect to the original aims). This evolution can be observed on all levels: Instead of focusing e.g. on long term development of democratic insti- tutions and culture, a system might be – in the name of (human) security – overthrown with military means to then try reconstruction from the left over ruins (see example of Iraq above). Or, regarding the domestic sphere, instead of providing homeless with sustainable support, consumption of alcoholic beverages in public places is forbidden in the name of public secu- rity – and the homeless therewith driven away from commercial areas, where they are re- garded as disturbing elements (Körner 2006, IPWB). Essentially different situations are thus treated in a uniform way that might be counterproduc- tive at times. Wæver expresses this even more drastically: “Consequently, the logic of war–of challenge-resistance(defense)-escalation-recognition/defeat– could be replayed metaphorically and extended to other sectors. When this happens, however, the structure of the game is still derived from the most classical of classical cases: war.” (Wæver 1995: 54)
4,085
<h4><strong>Floyd’s methodology makes security all-encompassing – ensures the logic of war permeates their politics and turns their specificity claims.</h4><p>Rampp 9</strong> [Benjamin, University of Tübingen, Interdepartmental Centre for Ethics in the Sciences and Humanities (IZEW). Insecurity by Impreciseness Towards a Specific Concept of Security http://www.inter-disciplinary.net/ptb/wvw/wvw5/Rampp%20paper.pdf]</p><p>Although I encourage the combination of the human security and the securitization approach, I disagree with <u><mark>Floyd’s</u></mark> conclusion. Whereas she demonstrates that human security is also a form of securitization, she contents with the idea that both concepts just have different orien- tations: “Rather, each is important in its own unique way: one contributing to our understand- ing of how security is practiced, the other – on occasion and if successful – to its practice.” (Floyd 2007: 45f.). I will show in the following, that this <u><mark>reasoning is not without problems.</u></mark> 3 A criticism of the (broad) human security approach 3.1 The interconnectedness of the analytical and the political dimension I think however, that the approaches cannot be separated easily – even though Floyd ex- presses this correctly rather carefully; rather it shows, that <u><mark>because of its lacking analytical preciseness the human security approach underachieves</u></mark> also <u><mark>politically and</u></mark> respectively <u><mark>at- tains results opposite to its</u></mark> actual <u><mark>goals.</u></mark> Although it seems plausible that human security (in its broad interpretation) as general norma- tive-ethical position is of interest – it is however, not any more concrete than the Universal Declaration of Human Rights and thus holds little additional benefit. It clarifies that these human rights are part of security; by interpreting security in an extensively broad degree, hu- man security cannot surpass such a declaration and add to practical use. Because of its impre- ciseness, human security cannot be the aim in the sense of a concrete, political basis; exact statements which would render human security a meaningful political category are not con- tained in this concept. Defining human security as “political leitmotif” (Werthes/Bosold 2005, 2006) seems therefore exaggerated. Human security is even less a political route to this objective, since the concept exhibits too many weaknesses as a guideline for actions. Because what happens is simply the following: well-being or the good life are formulated as desirable goals and then immediately defined as security matters. This does not result in any additional insight (who doesn’t strive for well- being in general?), but creates the problem that from now on, <u><mark>all relevant issues suffer from human security’s arbitrariness and are handled following the logic of security</u></mark> – which is quite different to e.g. the logic of economic, food, health, environmental, or social issues. When this happens, dangerous consequences – intended or not – might occur. In this context, <u><mark>security becomes the ultimate principle of the social world</u></mark> (Wæver 1995: 48). <u><mark>Thus the logic of security is extended to other social fields, which lose specificity</u></mark> however (Wæver 1995: 50). If, for example, questions of human development or development of de- mocracy are seen through the eyes of security, then these questions will also be answered from a security’s point of view (and not in respect to the original aims). This evolution can be observed on all levels: Instead of focusing e.g. on long term development of democratic insti- tutions and culture, a system might be – in the name of (human) security – overthrown with military means to then try reconstruction from the left over ruins (see example of Iraq above). Or, regarding the domestic sphere, instead of providing homeless with sustainable support, consumption of alcoholic beverages in public places is forbidden in the name of public secu- rity – and the homeless therewith driven away from commercial areas, where they are re- garded as disturbing elements (Körner 2006, IPWB). Essentially <u><mark>different situations are</u></mark> thus <u><mark>treated in a uniform way that might be counterproduc- tive</u></mark> at times. Wæver expresses this even more drastically: “Consequently, <u><mark>the logic of war</u></mark>–of challenge-resistance(defense)-escalation-recognition/defeat– <u><mark>could be replayed metaphorically and extended to other sectors. When this happens</u></mark>, however, <u><mark>the structure of the game is still derived from</u></mark> the most classical of classical cases: <u><mark>war.”<strong></mark> (Wæver 1995: 54)</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
Link 5—Resource Wars
430,551
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,049
Heres a bunch of counterexamples
Wright 5
Wright 5 Logan doctoral candidate in Chinese politics and U.S.-China relations at George Washington University in Washington, DC. http://survivedsars.typepad.com/survivedsars/2005/11/offensive_reali_1.html 11-18-05
Mearsheimer, the godfather of offensive realist theory provided a rejection of the idea of China's peaceful rise This article could have been written in 1985, 1995, or 2005. Mearsheimer was well-known for predicting the collapse of NATO and breakup of Europe Why would China have so few nuclear weapons? Why would Russia agree to sell China significant quantities of military hardware, if they were concerned about great power competition? Why would China's military modernization efforts be focused intensely on the Taiwan question, rather than larger issues of great-power competition Why would China attempt to join international institutions, Why would China have negotiated border settlements with India, Russia, and Kazakhstan on terms that were generally unfavorable to China How long do we have to wait, Dr. Mearsheimer, before your predictions begin to make sense? how do you explain the collapse of the Soviet Union again
offensive realist theory was well-known for predicting collapse of NATO and breakup of Europe Why would China have few nuclear weapons? Why would Russia sell China military hardware, Why would military modernization be focused on Taiwan rather than larger issues Why would China join international institutions Why would China negotiate settlements with India on terms that were unfavorable to China How long do we have to wait, Dr. Mearsheimer, before predictions make sense how do you explain collapse of the Soviet Union
It would take something like this to bring me out of my blogging slumber, which resulted from a trip to England and a general feeling that I'm behind on other work, so that I should stay away from blogging for a while. John Mearsheimer, the godfather of offensive realist theory, has provided a completely deductive, completely theoretical rejection of the idea of China's peaceful rise into the international system. When I read this article, I didn't even know where to start, and how to concisely summarize my criticism. I'm sure I'll fail to be brief, but I'll start this way: This article could have been written in 1985, 1995, or 2005. Mearsheimer was well-known for predicting the collapse of NATO at the end of the Cold War (he still claims he's right, given US-European tension) and the breakup of European integration into hypernationalist or ethnic conflict (again, Mearsheimer claims violence in the former Yugoslavia in the early 1990s provides support for his argument). There is a significant debate over whether theories should attempt to explain, predict, or contribute to understanding of international phenomena, but offensive realism is definitely in the "predictive" category, if only because its prescriptions are so unidirectional. In contrast to defensive realists like Robert Jervis, offensive realists argue that security, ultimately, is scarce, and states, in order to preserve their own security, must actually maximize their power. Note: not maintain, but maximize. This is what is so frustrating about this article. Mearsheimer lays out the case for great power competition between the United States and China. China - whether it remains authoritarian or becomes democratic - is likely to try to dominate Asia the way the US dominates the Western hemisphere. Specifically, China will seek to maximise the power gap between itself and its neighbours, especially Japan and Russia. China will want to make sure that it is so powerful that no state in Asia has the wherewithal to threaten it. It is unlikely that China will pursue military superiority so that it can go on a rampage and conquer other Asian countries, although that is always possible. Instead, it is more likely that it will want to dictate the boundaries of acceptable behaviour to neighbouring countries, much the way the US makes it clear to other states in the Americas that it is the boss. Gaining regional hegemony, I might add, is probably the only way that China will get Taiwan back. An increasingly powerful China is also likely to try to push the US out of Asia, much the way the US pushed the European great powers out of the Western hemisphere. We should expect China to come up with its own version of the Monroe Doctrine, as Japan did in the 1930s. These policy goals make good strategic sense for China. Beijing should want a militarily weak Japan and Russia as its neighbours, just as the US prefers a militarily weak Canada and Mexico on its borders. Note what Mearsheimer said. "China will seek to maximise the power gap between itself and its neighbours, especially Japan and Russia." Maximize? Really? Keep in mind, this is the essential prediction of this theory, which is parsimonious, to Mearsheimer's credit. In light of this, I have a number of questions for Dr. Mearsheimer. If your theory is correct... Why would China have so few nuclear weapons? Why would Russia agree to sell China significant quantities of military hardware, if they were concerned about great power competition? Why would China's military modernization efforts be focused intensely on the Taiwan question, rather than larger issues of great-power competition (a blue-water navy, more ICBMs, etc.)? Why would China attempt to join international institutions, if they are concerned that these institutions are part of the global economic and political order dominated by the United States? Why would Chinese officials openly claim that they are not interested in pushing the United States out of Asia, as the US presence provides a level of security essential for China's economic growth? Why would China have negotiated border settlements with India, Russia, and Kazakhstan on terms that were generally unfavorable to China, given their past historical positions? Why would China attempt to work within existing international institutions, and campaign actively to join them, rather than attempting to create their own? Why would a democratic China still be interested in a military solution to the Taiwan issue? Why would Taiwan be opposed to reunification in such a scenario? Keep in mind, in offensive realism, the character of the state involved is not relevant to the analysis. How long do we have to wait, Dr. Mearsheimer, before your predictions begin to make sense? How would this article have been different in 1985 or 1995, rather than 2005? Are we all just engaging in the Popperian "inductivist illusion" by having the audacity to look at empirical evidence, rather than living in our deductive theoretical cocoons? Or is the theory simply a cut too thin, designed to maximize parsimony at the expense of explaining independent observations? And by the way, how do you explain the collapse of the Soviet Union again?
5,289
<h4><strong>Heres a bunch of counterexamples</h4><p>Wright 5</strong> Logan doctoral candidate in Chinese politics and U.S.-China relations at George Washington University in Washington, DC. http://survivedsars.typepad.com/survivedsars/2005/11/offensive_reali_1.html 11-18-05</p><p>It would take something like this to bring me out of my blogging slumber, which resulted from a trip to England and a general feeling that I'm behind on other work, so that I should stay away from blogging for a while. John <u>Mearsheimer, the godfather of <mark>offensive realist theory</u></mark>, has <u>provided a </u>completely deductive, completely theoretical <u>rejection of the idea of China's peaceful rise </u>into the international system. When I read this article, I didn't even know where to start, and how to concisely summarize my criticism. I'm sure I'll fail to be brief, but I'll start this way: <u>This article could have been written in 1985, 1995, or 2005. Mearsheimer <mark>was well-known for predicting </mark>the <mark>collapse of NATO </u></mark>at the end of the Cold War (he still claims he's right, given US-European tension) <u><mark>and</u> </mark>the <u><mark>breakup of Europe</u></mark>an integration into hypernationalist or ethnic conflict (again, Mearsheimer claims violence in the former Yugoslavia in the early 1990s provides support for his argument). There is a significant debate over whether theories should attempt to explain, predict, or contribute to understanding of international phenomena, but offensive realism is definitely in the "predictive" category, if only because its prescriptions are so unidirectional. In contrast to defensive realists like Robert Jervis, offensive realists argue that security, ultimately, is scarce, and states, in order to preserve their own security, must actually maximize their power. Note: not maintain, but maximize. This is what is so frustrating about this article. Mearsheimer lays out the case for great power competition between the United States and China. China - whether it remains authoritarian or becomes democratic - is likely to try to dominate Asia the way the US dominates the Western hemisphere. Specifically, China will seek to maximise the power gap between itself and its neighbours, especially Japan and Russia. China will want to make sure that it is so powerful that no state in Asia has the wherewithal to threaten it. It is unlikely that China will pursue military superiority so that it can go on a rampage and conquer other Asian countries, although that is always possible. Instead, it is more likely that it will want to dictate the boundaries of acceptable behaviour to neighbouring countries, much the way the US makes it clear to other states in the Americas that it is the boss. Gaining regional hegemony, I might add, is probably the only way that China will get Taiwan back. An increasingly powerful China is also likely to try to push the US out of Asia, much the way the US pushed the European great powers out of the Western hemisphere. We should expect China to come up with its own version of the Monroe Doctrine, as Japan did in the 1930s. These policy goals make good strategic sense for China. Beijing should want a militarily weak Japan and Russia as its neighbours, just as the US prefers a militarily weak Canada and Mexico on its borders. Note what Mearsheimer said. "China will seek to maximise the power gap between itself and its neighbours, especially Japan and Russia." Maximize? Really? Keep in mind, this is the essential prediction of this theory, which is parsimonious, to Mearsheimer's credit. In light of this, I have a number of questions for Dr. Mearsheimer. If your theory is correct... <u><mark>Why would China have </mark>so <mark>few nuclear weapons? Why would Russia</mark> agree to <mark>sell China </mark>significant quantities of <mark>military hardware, </mark>if they were concerned </p><p>about great power competition? <mark>Why would</mark> China's <mark>military modernization</mark> efforts <mark>be focused</mark> intensely <mark>on</mark> the <mark>Taiwan</mark> question, <mark>rather than</mark> <mark>larger issues</mark> of great-power competition </u>(a blue-water navy, more ICBMs, etc.)? <u><mark>Why would China </mark>attempt to <mark>join international institutions</mark>, </u>if they are concerned that these institutions are part of the global economic and political order dominated by the United States? Why would Chinese officials openly claim that they are not interested in pushing the United States out of Asia, as the US presence provides a level of security essential for China's economic growth? <u><mark>Why would China </mark>have <mark>negotiate</mark>d border <mark>settlements with India</mark>, Russia, and Kazakhstan <mark>on terms that were </mark>generally <mark>unfavorable to China</u></mark>, given their past historical positions? Why would China attempt to work within existing international institutions, and campaign actively to join them, rather than attempting to create their own? Why would a democratic China still be interested in a military solution to the Taiwan issue? Why would Taiwan be opposed to reunification in such a scenario? Keep in mind, in offensive realism, the character of the state involved is not relevant to the analysis.<u> <mark>How long do we have to wait, Dr. Mearsheimer,</mark> <mark>before</mark> your <mark>predictions</mark> begin to <mark>make sense</mark>? </u>How would this article have been different in 1985 or 1995, rather than 2005? Are we all just engaging in the Popperian "inductivist illusion" by having the audacity to look at empirical evidence, rather than living in our deductive theoretical cocoons? Or is the theory simply a cut too thin, designed to maximize parsimony at the expense of explaining independent observations? And by the way,<u> <mark>how do you explain </mark>the <mark>collapse of the Soviet Union </mark>again</u><strong>?</p></strong>
1nr
null
AT:
430,552
6
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,050
Empirics Disprove Their Argument - State Dominance in Connected to Genocide, Ethnic Cleansing, and Mass Death
and McDonald ‘
Alex J. Bellamy, Lecturer in Peace and Conflict Studies at the University of Queenss, and Matt McDonald, Lecturer in the School of Politics and International Relations at the University of New South Wales, ‘4 [Australian Journal of Political Science 39.2, “'Securing international society: towards an English school discourse of security,” p. informaworld]
the pluralist account of security confronts a major empirical problem states fail to secure their citizens and even pursue policies that make them insecure? If states were ethical there would be no genocide, recent history teaches us that many states in the world do not provide the sort of relief from the Hobbesian state of nature that pluralists like Jackson suppose state security may sometimes be purchased at the expense of individuals. . although pluralist international society has succeeded in reducing premature deaths caused by inter-state war, it has failed to curb the increase in premature deaths caused by internal war, poverty and state repression. According to Hedley Bull (1977, 5), ‘order’ is an important good because it allows societies to pursue the three elementary goals of social life: life, truth and property. Without these three facets there can be no meaningful social life. However, in the name of the greater good, pluralists insist that we must accept that some societies cannot fulfill these goals and that in order to preserve the security that the wealthy parts of the world enjoy, we must not undermine the basic structures of the international system that create these two worlds. At this level, pluralism may certainly be viewed as a relatively conservative discourse of international relations.
null
More tellingly, however, the pluralist account of security put forward by Jackson confronts a major empirical problem: if the privileging of state security is based on the state’s ability to provide its citizens with security, what are we to do when—despite being given special treatment in international society—states fail to secure their citizens and even pursue policies that make them insecure? If all states were ethical states there would be no genocide, ethnic cleansing, malnutrition and the rest. Unfortunately, recent history teaches us that many states in the world do not provide the sort of relief from the Hobbesian state of nature that pluralists like Jackson suppose. Instead, we need to recognise three limitations to the pursuit of security by pluralist means. First, according to the pluralist logic, state security may sometimes be purchased at the expense of individuals. Second, the boundaries of the state and the community do not necessarily overlap. Third, although pluralist international society has succeeded in reducing premature deaths caused by inter-state war, it has failed to curb the increase in premature deaths caused by internal war, poverty and state repression. According to Hedley Bull (1977, 5), ‘order’ is an important good because it allows societies to pursue the three elementary goals of social life: life, truth and property. Without these three facets there can be no meaningful social life. However, in the name of the greater good, pluralists insist that we must accept that some societies cannot fulfill these goals and that in order to preserve the security that the wealthy parts of the world enjoy, we must not undermine the basic structures of the international system that create these two worlds. At this level, pluralism may certainly be viewed as a relatively conservative discourse of international relations.
1,871
<h4><strong>Empirics Disprove Their Argument - State Dominance in Connected to Genocide, Ethnic Cleansing, and Mass Death</h4><p></strong>Alex J. <u>Bellamy</u>, Lecturer in Peace and Conflict Studies at the University of Queenss, <strong>and</strong> Matt <strong>McDonald</strong>, Lecturer in the School of Politics and International Relations at the University of New South Wales, <strong>‘<u></strong>4</u> [Australian Journal of Political Science 39.2, “'Securing international society: towards an English school discourse of security,” p. informaworld]</p><p>More tellingly, however, <u>the pluralist account of security</u> put forward by Jackson <u>confronts a major empirical problem</u>: if the privileging of state security is based on the state’s ability to provide its citizens with security, what are we to do when—despite being given special treatment in international society—<u>states fail to secure their citizens and even pursue policies that make them insecure? If </u>all<u> states were ethical </u>states<u> there would be no genocide, </u>ethnic cleansing, malnutrition and the rest. Unfortunately, <u>recent history teaches us that many states in the world do not provide the sort of relief from the Hobbesian state of nature that pluralists like Jackson suppose</u>. Instead, we need to recognise three limitations to the pursuit of security by pluralist means. First, according to the pluralist logic, <u>state security may sometimes be purchased at the expense of individuals.</u> Second, the boundaries of the state and the community do not necessarily overlap<u>.</u> Third, <u>although <strong>pluralist international society has succeeded in reducing premature deaths caused by inter-state war, it has failed to curb the increase in premature deaths caused by internal war, poverty and state repression. According to Hedley Bull (1977, 5), ‘order’ is an important good because it allows societies to pursue the three elementary goals of social life: life, truth and property. Without these three facets there can be no meaningful social life. However, in the name of the greater good, pluralists insist that we must accept that some societies cannot fulfill these goals and that in order to preserve the security that the wealthy parts of the world enjoy, we must not undermine the basic structures of the international system that create these two worlds. At this level, pluralism may certainly be viewed as a relatively conservative discourse of international relations. </p></u></strong>
1nr
null
AT:
430,553
1
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,051
Their insistence that their form of leadership is somehow benign proves the link – the exercise of American power, even when well-intentioned, exacerbates security dilemmas and ensures conflict.
Tang and Long 12
Tang and Long 12 [Shiping Tang and S.R. Joey Long, School of International Relations and Public Affairs, Fudan University America's military interventionism: A social evolutionary interpretation European Journal of International Relations September 2012 vol. 18 no. 3 509-538]
Because no country can be insulated from America’s exercise of its vast power, other states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if American intentions are not malevolent. America’s elites and public, informed by an ethnocentric sense of providence and self-righteousness cannot appreciate why other countries fear America’s enormous power and its promotion of supposedly universal beliefs. This apathy toward other countries’ fears inevitably exacerbates the security dilemma and spiral between America and other countries.
no country can be insulated from America’s exercise states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if intentions are not malevolent elites informed by ethnocentric self-righteousness, cannot appreciate why countries fear America’s power This apathy toward other countries’ fears exacerbates the security dilemma
Indeed, the United States has been able to behave in an abrasive and proselytizing manner internationally because geography and preponderant power affords it a comforting sense of security. While a state’s foreign policy is necessarily informed by a set of beliefs, active exportation of one’s beliefs through hard power inevitably makes the state very threatening to others that do not share those beliefs. Because no country can be insulated from America’s exercise of its vast power, other states invariably fear it and question its motives, even if American intentions are not malevolent. America’s blessing again becomes a curse to other states and ultimately to the United States as well. Meanwhile, America’s elites and public, informed by an ethnocentric sense of providence and self-righteousness, often cannot appreciate why other countries fear America’s enormous power and its promotion of its supposedly universal beliefs. This apathy toward other countries’ fears inevitably exacerbates the security dilemma and/or spiral between America and other countries.
1,083
<h4>Their insistence that their form of leadership is somehow benign proves the link – the exercise of American power, even when well-intentioned, exacerbates security dilemmas and ensures conflict.</h4><p><strong>Tang and Long 12</strong> [Shiping Tang and S.R. Joey Long, School of International Relations and Public Affairs, Fudan University America's military interventionism: A social evolutionary interpretation European Journal of International Relations September 2012 vol. 18 no. 3 509-538]</p><p>Indeed, the United States has been able to behave in an abrasive and proselytizing manner internationally because geography and preponderant power affords it a comforting sense of security. While a state’s foreign policy is necessarily informed by a set of beliefs, active exportation of one’s beliefs through hard power inevitably makes the state very threatening to others that do not share those beliefs. <u>Because <mark>no country can be insulated from America’s exercise</mark> of its vast power, other <mark>states</mark> <mark>invariably fear it and question its motives, even if</mark> American <mark>intentions are not malevolent</mark>.</u> America’s blessing again becomes a curse to other states and ultimately to the United States as well. Meanwhile, <u>America’s <mark>elites</mark> and public, <mark>informed by</mark> an <mark>ethnocentric</mark> sense of providence and <mark>self-righteousness</u>,</mark> often <u><mark>cannot appreciate why</mark> other <mark>countries fear America’s</mark> enormous <mark>power</mark> and its promotion of</u> its <u>supposedly universal beliefs. <mark>This apathy</mark> <mark>toward other countries’ fears</mark> inevitably <mark>exacerbates the</mark> <mark>security dilemma</mark> and</u>/or <u><strong>spiral between America and other countries.</p></u></strong>
1nr
null
A2: 1AC Cross App
430,545
3
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,052
Analysis of IR data fails – doesn’t account for historical context and categorizes conflicts inconsistently
Lebow 10
Lebow 10 Richard Ned Lebow, James O. Freedman Presidential Professor Emeritus at Dartmouth College and Professor of International Political Theory at the Department of War Studies, King's College London, Centennial Professor of International Relations at the London School of Economics and Political Science, “Why Nations Fight: Past and Future Motives for War”, Cambridge University Press 2010
Correlational studies of war are primarily a postwar phenomenon. Statistical studies have not led to any theories of war, although they have been used to test a wide range of propositions To make any claims for external validity, statistical studies must meet two conditions individual cases must be comparable and independent Existing data sets of war fall short on both counts wars have occurred in widely varying cultural, political and technological contexts, making comparisons meaningless Great power war in the eighteenth century by dynastic rulers differed greatly from warfare among industrialized states our understanding of context must be approached through the understanding of relevant actors. Existing data sets rarely account for context, and never, code relevant variables from the perspective of actors. Wars are rarely independent, as they come in clusters. One war can trigger another, and one cluster can generate lessons that are applied to future challenges, World War II is really a general signifier for more closely related wars: the German and Soviet invasions Italian attack on France, components of World War I can be treated analytically as separate wars Conversely, World War II and I can be lumped together as part of a thirty-year continental war. Any of these descriptions is acceptable, and all pose problems for data sets. If general wars are broken down into their individual components, they will be treated as independent cases, which generally are not. as part of a single war, they hide the complexity and multiplicity of its several components
Statistical studies have not led to any theories of war they have been used to test a wide range of propositions for validity statistical studies must meet two conditions cases must be comparable and independent data sets of war fall short on both counts wars have occurred in varying contexts, making comparisons meaningless war in the eighteenth century differed greatly from warfare among industrialized states data sets rarely account for context, and never relevant variables from the perspective of actors Wars come in clusters components of World War I can be treated analytically as separate wars Any of these descriptions is acceptable, and all pose problems for data sets. If wars are broken down into their individual components, they will be treated as independent cases If as part of a single war, they hide the complexity
Correlational studies of war are primarily a postwar phenomenon. They were given a big boost by the Correlates of War (COW) project started in 1963 at the University of Michigan. The original approach of COW was inductive: its originators sought to cons‘truct a data set that would allow a search for regularities. In recent decades, researchers have used COW and other data sets, including those compiled by Jack Levy and the Peace Research Institute Oslo, to test a series of propositions about the causes and consequences of war. Statistical studies have not led to any theories of war, although they have been used to test a wide range of propositions and other theories. They have generated some interesting empirical findings. Summarizing this literature, Daniel Geller reports that: “Geographic proximity/contiguity, static parity in capabilities and shifts toward parity, unbalanced external alliance ties, and the presence of an enduring rivalry are factors substantially and positively associated with the occurrence of both militarized disputes and wars.” To make any claims for external validity, statistical studies must meet two fundamental conditions: individual cases must be comparable and independent of one another. Existing data sets of war fall short on both counts. Even post-1648, wars have occurred in widely varying cultural, political and technological contexts, making comparisons meaningless in the absence of some serious efforts to take these differences into account. Great power war in the eighteenth century, waged by dynastic rulers using a mix of mercenary and conscript armies, differed greatly from warfare among industrialized states in the early twentieth century, many of whose leaders were beholden, formally or informally, to public opinion. Both contexts differ from the Cold War, with its potential to go nuclear and destroy the states and peoples involved. Some of these differences are more apparent in retrospect than they were to policymakers at the time. So our understanding of context, as important as it is must be approached through the understanding of relevant actors. Existing data sets rarely account for context, and never, to my knowledge, code relevant variables from the perspective of actors. Wars are rarely independent, as they often come in clusters. One war can trigger another, and one cluster can generate a set of lessons that are applied to future challenges, whether germane or not. Japan’s invasion of China in 1931, Italy’s attack of Abyssinia in 1935, Italian, German and Soviet intervention in the Spanish Civil War, the Soviet-Japanese clash in Mongolia in 1939 and the Russo-Finnish War of the same year wet part of the run-up to and inseparable from World War II. That war in turn is really a general signifier for even more closely related wars: the German and Soviet invasions of Poland, Germany’s war in the West, the Italian attack on France, German subjugation of Yugoslavia, Albania and Greece, the German invasion of the Soviet Union, the undeclared naval war in the Atlantic between the US and Germany, the Japanese attack on the Western powers in the Pacific, and official US entry into the war. Many of these components of World War I can be treated analytically as separate wars, the same way the various coalitions in the French and Napoleonic Wars are routinely described as separate, it related, wars. Conversely, World War II and World war I, or at least their European components, can be lumped together as part of a thirty-year continental war. The precedent here is the Peloponnesian War (415-404 BCE), which Thucydides treats as a single conflict but contemporaries considered a successor war to the Archdamian War (431-421 BCE). The Thirty Years War and the French Revolutionary Wars, often used to described a series of related wars, continue the tradition. Any of these descriptions is acceptable, and all pose problems for data sets. If general wars are broken down into their individual components, they will be treated as independent cases, which generally are not. If they are coded as part of a single war, they hide the complexity and multiplicity of its several components. Both choices privilege efficient causes of different kinds. The first encourages us to look for general explanations for a war cluster, and the latter more idiosyncratic explanations for its individual components.
4,395
<h4><strong>Analysis of IR data fails – doesn’t account for historical context and categorizes conflicts inconsistently</h4><p>Lebow 10</p><p></strong>Richard Ned Lebow, James O. Freedman Presidential Professor Emeritus at Dartmouth College and Professor of International Political Theory at the Department of War Studies, King's College London, Centennial Professor of International Relations at the London School of Economics and Political Science, “Why Nations Fight: Past and Future Motives for War”, Cambridge University Press 2010 </p><p><u>Correlational studies of war are primarily a postwar phenomenon.</u> They were given a big boost by the Correlates of War (COW) project started in 1963 at the University of Michigan. The original approach of COW was inductive: its originators sought to cons‘truct a data set that would allow a search for regularities. In recent decades, researchers have used COW and other data sets, including those compiled by Jack Levy and the Peace Research Institute Oslo, to test a series of propositions about the causes and consequences of war. <u><mark>Statistical studies have not led to any theories of war</mark>, although <mark>they have been used to test a wide range of propositions</u></mark> and other theories. They have generated some interesting empirical findings. Summarizing this literature, Daniel Geller reports that: “Geographic proximity/contiguity, static parity in capabilities and shifts toward parity, unbalanced external alliance ties, and the presence of an enduring rivalry are factors substantially and positively associated with the occurrence of both militarized disputes and wars.”</p><p><u>To make any claims <mark>for</mark> external <mark>validity</mark>, <mark>statistical studies must meet two</u></mark> fundamental <u><mark>conditions</u></mark>: <u>individual <mark>cases must be comparable and independent</u></mark> of one another. <u>Existing <mark>data sets of war fall short on both counts</u></mark>. Even post-1648, <u><mark>wars have occurred in</mark> widely <mark>varying</mark> cultural, political and technological <mark>contexts, making comparisons meaningless</u></mark> in the absence of some serious efforts to take these differences into account. <u>Great power <mark>war in the eighteenth century</u></mark>, waged <u>by dynastic rulers</u> using a mix of mercenary and conscript armies, <u><mark>differed greatly from warfare among industrialized states</u></mark> in the early twentieth century, many of whose leaders were beholden, formally or informally, to public opinion. Both contexts differ from the Cold War, with its potential to go nuclear and destroy the states and peoples involved. Some of these differences are more apparent in retrospect than they were to policymakers at the time. So <u>our understanding of context</u>, as important as it is <u>must be approached through the understanding of relevant actors. Existing <mark>data sets rarely account for context, and never</mark>,</u> to my knowledge,<u> code <mark>relevant variables from the perspective of actors</mark>.</p><p><mark>Wars</mark> are rarely independent, as they</u> often <u><mark>come in clusters</mark>. One war can trigger another, and one cluster can generate</u> a set of <u>lessons that are applied to future challenges,</u> whether germane or not. Japan’s invasion of China in 1931, Italy’s attack of Abyssinia in 1935, Italian, German and Soviet intervention in the Spanish Civil War, the Soviet-Japanese clash in Mongolia in 1939 and the Russo-Finnish War of the same year wet part of the run-up to and inseparable from <u>World War II</u>. That war in turn <u>is really a general signifier for </u>even <u>more closely related wars: the German and Soviet invasions</u> of Poland, Germany’s war in the West, the <u>Italian attack on France,</u> German subjugation of Yugoslavia, Albania and Greece, the German invasion of the Soviet Union, the undeclared naval war in the Atlantic between the US and Germany, the Japanese attack on the Western powers in the Pacific, and official US entry into the war. Many of these <u><mark>components of World War I can be treated analytically as separate wars</u></mark>, the same way the various coalitions in the French and Napoleonic Wars are routinely described as separate, it related, wars. <u>Conversely, World War II and </u>World war <u>I</u>, or at least their European components, <u>can be lumped together as part of a thirty-year continental war.</u> The precedent here is the Peloponnesian War (415-404 BCE), which Thucydides treats as a single conflict but contemporaries considered a successor war to the Archdamian War (431-421 BCE). The Thirty Years War and the French Revolutionary Wars, often used to described a series of related wars, continue the tradition.</p><p><u><mark>Any of these descriptions is acceptable, and all pose problems for data sets.</mark> <mark>If</mark> general <mark>wars are broken down into their individual components, they will be treated as independent cases</mark>, which generally are not.</u> <mark>If</mark> they are coded <u><mark>as part of a single war, they hide the complexity</mark> and multiplicity of its several components</u>. Both choices privilege efficient causes of different kinds. The first encourages us to look for general explanations for a war cluster, and the latter more idiosyncratic explanations for its individual components.</p>
1nr
null
A2: Data
430,554
2
17,066
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
565,286
N
Hurricanedebates2015
3
Vanderbilt Bilgi-Mitchell
Harrigan
Security K (2NR) SCOTUS MSD CP Politics - Iran T - Cadavers == nearly all Heg Bad
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrAh/Dartmouth-Kreus-Ahmad-Neg-Hurricanedebates2015-Round3.docx
null
48,457
KrAh
Dartmouth KrAh
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Pi.....
Ah.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,053
Obama can hold off an Iran bill now but it’s close- PC’s key to keep enough Dems to sustain a veto
Bloomberg 4/2
Bloomberg 4/2/2015 (Obama’s Next Negotiation on Iran Is With Critics in Congress, http://www.bloomberg.com/politics/articles/2015-04-02/obama-s-next-negotiation-on-iran-is-with-critics-in-congress)
Obama is tantalizingly close to a legacy-defining moment with the preliminary nuclear accord struck with Iran and now must fend off congressional critics pushing legislation that could scuttle it. we have a historic opportunity to prevent the spread of nuclear weapons in Iran and to do so peacefully while negotiators haggle with Iranian counterparts over crucial details, Obama will be under the gun to make a case critics of the deal have been more active in shaping the public debate the administration has to get more aggressive in shaping that discussion The White House telegraphed its strategy earlier this week: briefings for lawmakers and a campaign to paint opponents as more interested in politics that the national interest Congress will be responsible for the risk posed if it kills the deal before it’s finalized The administration’s main goal is keeping enough Democrats behind Obama to prevent Congress from being able to override a promised veto of the legislation sponsored by Corker and Menendez Corker has said his committee will take up the bill on April 14 Republicans hold 54 seats in the Senate and would need 13 more votes to override Obama. So far, eight Democrats and one independent have signed on as cosponsors The reaction of lawmakers will depend largely on how convincing the White House is If the administration can make a case they’ll get a reprieve in terms of voting on new legislation Sick, a former National Security Council official who specialized on Iran said that Republicans will struggle to get a veto-proof majority. When people begin to see their actions have real consequences and those consequences could be historic, they think twice A lot of Democrats would find it extremely difficult to vote against their own president in a situation like that
Obama is tantalizingly close with the preliminary nuclear accord and now must fend off congress pushing legislation that could scuttle it. the administration has to get more aggressive in shaping that discussion The White House telegraphed its strategy briefings for lawmakers and a campaign to paint opponents as more interested in politics Republicans hold 54 seats and would need 13 more votes to override So far, eight Democrats and one independent have signed on The reaction of lawmakers will depend largely on how convincing the White House is Sick a former N S C official said that Republicans will struggle to get a veto-proof majority.
President Barack Obama is tantalizingly close to a legacy-defining moment with the preliminary nuclear accord struck with Iran and now must fend off congressional critics pushing legislation that could scuttle it. Striking an agreement that pulls Iran back from the brink of building a nuclear weapon would be a capstone achievement for Obama’s second term and vindicate his pursuit of diplomacy over military action and engagement with enemies, one of the central arguments of his first campaign for the presidency. “Success is not guaranteed,” Obama said at the White House on Thursday a short time after the framework was announced in Switzerland. “But we have a historic opportunity to prevent the spread of nuclear weapons in Iran and to do so peacefully. We should seize that chance.” Over the next three months, while negotiators for the U.S. and five other world powers haggle with Iranian counterparts over crucial details, Obama and his aides will be under the gun to make a case to voters and their representatives that Iran’s nuclear ambitions will be curbed and that the Tehran regime’s compliance can be verified. “What has happened so far is that critics of the deal have been more active in shaping the public debate,” said Robert Einhorn, a senior fellow with the Arms Control and Non-Proliferation Initiative at the Brookings Institution. Now, the administration has to get more aggressive in shaping that discussion, he said. Administration Strategy The White House telegraphed its strategy earlier this week: briefings for lawmakers and a campaign to paint opponents as more interested in politics that the national interest. White House press secretary Josh Earnest implored lawmakers to evaluate a deal “solely on the national security interests of the United States.” While some Democrats are backing legislation to give Congress the final say on an agreement or to impose new sanctions on Iran, Earnest singled out Republicans for engaging in “rank partisanship” and trying to throw roadblocks in front of any deal. “It may be, in the minds of some of them, the best way to try to seek a partisan advantage,” Earnest said on Tuesday. “But what we’re looking for is an American advantage.” One of the legislative proposals would give Congress authority to approve or reject any deal. Senate Foreign Relations Committee Chairman Bob Corker of Tennessee, one of the chief sponsors, said the U.S. “must remain clear-eyed” about Iran’s history of deception, support of terrorism and attempts to destabilize the region. Public Input “If a final agreement is reached,” Corker said in a statement, “the American people, through their elected representatives must have the opportunity to weigh in to ensure the deal truly can eliminate the threat of Iran’s nuclear program and hold the regime accountable.” Other Republicans were more critical. Representative Peter Roskam of Illinois, co-chairman of the House Republican Israel Caucus, blasted the statement released by the negotiators in Switzerland, saying it “promises the Iranian regime everything it wants.” In exchange, Roskam said in a statement, the U.S. and its partners get, at best, minimal restrictions on “peripheral aspects of Iran’s nuclear program,” and more “empty promises.” During his remarks, Obama acknowledged the concerns of lawmakers and said he looks “forward to a robust debate in the days and weeks to come.” Making Calls He said he’s instructed his staff to brief lawmakers and plans to talk with the leaders of the House and Senate himself on Thursday. Obama also planned to call Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu, a vocal critic of the negotiations who has lobbied Republicans to keep up pressure on the White House. “I will underscore that the issues at stake are bigger than politics,” Obama said. “They are about war and peace.” Obama said Congress will be responsible for the risk posed if it kills the deal before it’s finalized. He cited the agreements reached by Republican Presidents Richard Nixon and Ronald Reagan with the Soviet Union during the Cold War. “Those agreements were not perfect,” he said. “They did not end all threats. But they made our world safer. A good deal with Iran will do the same.” As it became clear that a deal had been struck, Obama delayed his scheduled departure for a speech in Kentucky by almost three hours so that he could address the accord. Courting Democrats The administration’s main goal is keeping enough Democrats behind Obama to prevent Congress from being able to override a promised veto of the legislation sponsored by Corker and Robert Menendez, a New Jersey Democrat. The bill would require the administration to wait 60 days before suspending any sanctions against Iran, during which time lawmakers would have the opportunity to approve, reject, or take no action on the deal. Corker has said his committee will take up the bill on April 14. Republicans hold 54 seats in the Senate and would need 13 more votes to override Obama. So far, eight Democrats and one independent have signed on as cosponsors of the Corker-Menendez bill. Among them is Senator Chuck Schumer of New York, who’s emerged as the likely successor to Senate Democratic leader Harry Reid in 2017. Menendez, who has been more willing than most prominent Democrats to challenge the White House on Iran, was indicted Wednesday on federal corruption charges and stepped down as the ranking Democrat on the Foreign Relations Committee. That isn’t likely to slow down consideration of the legislation. Sanctions Issue He also is the co-sponsor on another measure with Republican Senator Mark Kirk of Illinois to put new sanctions on Iran if there’s no agreement by June 30. Kirk, who’s facing a re-election challenge in 2016, said Wednesday that the administration has made “a series of dangerous nuclear concessions” in the course of negotiations. Jim Manley, a former top aide to Reid, said Republican leaders are under pressure from their members “to just stick it to the president.” If Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell overplays his hand by pushing for a quick floor vote on the legislation, that may give Obama an opening to peel off Democratic votes, he said. “They’re going to have to sell it but in a way that is understandable to the average man or woman,” Manley said of the administration. The details of any nuclear agreement “are mind-numbing in their complexity,” Manley said. Critical Briefings The reaction of lawmakers will depend largely on how convincing the White House is in briefings planned to explain the agreement struck in Lausanne, according to Einhorn. “If the administration can make a case that significant progress is being made toward a sound agreement, then it’s likely that they’ll get a reprieve in terms of voting on new legislation,” Einhorn said before the deal was announced. One way for Obama to make his case would be to frame the agreement as an international accord rather than just between the U.S. and Iran, said Patricia Degennaro, an adjunct professor of international security at New York University. “This is an international negotiation. It’s not just American,” she said. Bringing in international supporters of an agreement to talk with lawmakers could also help win their support, she said. Netanyahu, an opponent of an agreement, addressed Congress earlier this month. British Prime Minister David Cameron previously had telephoned U.S. lawmakers to lobby for an agreement when he visited the U.S. Gary Sick, a former National Security Council official who specialized on Iran during the Iranian revolution and the hostage crisis, said that Republicans will struggle to get a veto-proof majority. “When people begin to see their actions have real consequences and those consequences could be historic, they think twice,” said Sick, now an adjunct professor at Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs. “A lot of Democrats would find it extremely difficult to vote against their own president in a situation like that.”
8,027
<h4>Obama can hold off an Iran bill now but it’s close- PC’s key to keep enough Dems to sustain a veto</h4><p><strong>Bloomberg 4/2</strong>/2015 (Obama’s Next Negotiation on Iran Is With Critics in Congress, http://www.bloomberg.com/politics/articles/2015-04-02/obama-s-next-negotiation-on-iran-is-with-critics-in-congress)</p><p>President Barack <u><mark>Obama is tantalizingly close </mark>to a legacy-defining moment <mark>with the preliminary nuclear accord</mark> struck with Iran <mark>and now must fend off</mark> <mark>congress</mark>ional critics <mark>pushing legislation that could scuttle it.</mark> </u>Striking an agreement that pulls Iran back from the brink of building a nuclear weapon would be a capstone achievement for Obama’s second term and vindicate his pursuit of diplomacy over military action and engagement with enemies, one of the central arguments of his first campaign for the presidency. “Success is not guaranteed,” Obama said at the White House on Thursday a short time after the framework was announced in Switzerland. “But <u>we have a historic opportunity to prevent the spread of nuclear weapons in Iran and to do so peacefully</u>. We should seize that chance.” Over the next three months, <u>while negotiators</u> for the U.S. and five other world powers <u>haggle with Iranian counterparts over crucial details, Obama </u>and his aides<u> will be under the gun to make a case</u> to voters and their representatives that Iran’s nuclear ambitions will be curbed and that the Tehran regime’s compliance can be verified. “What has happened so far is that <u>critics of the deal have been more active in shaping the public debate</u>,” said Robert Einhorn, a senior fellow with the Arms Control and Non-Proliferation Initiative at the Brookings Institution. Now, <u><strong><mark>the administration has to get more aggressive in shaping that discussion</u></strong></mark>, he said. Administration Strategy <u><mark>The White House telegraphed its strategy</mark> earlier this week: <mark>briefings for lawmakers and a campaign to paint opponents as</mark> <mark>more</mark> <mark>interested in politics</mark> that the national interest</u>. White House press secretary Josh Earnest implored lawmakers to evaluate a deal “solely on the national security interests of the United States.” While some Democrats are backing legislation to give Congress the final say on an agreement or to impose new sanctions on Iran, Earnest singled out Republicans for engaging in “rank partisanship” and trying to throw roadblocks in front of any deal. “It may be, in the minds of some of them, the best way to try to seek a partisan advantage,” Earnest said on Tuesday. “But what we’re looking for is an American advantage.” One of the legislative proposals would give Congress authority to approve or reject any deal. Senate Foreign Relations Committee Chairman Bob Corker of Tennessee, one of the chief sponsors, said the U.S. “must remain clear-eyed” about Iran’s history of deception, support of terrorism and attempts to destabilize the region. Public Input “If a final agreement is reached,” Corker said in a statement, “the American people, through their elected representatives must have the opportunity to weigh in to ensure the deal truly can eliminate the threat of Iran’s nuclear program and hold the regime accountable.” Other Republicans were more critical. Representative Peter Roskam of Illinois, co-chairman of the House Republican Israel Caucus, blasted the statement released by the negotiators in Switzerland, saying it “promises the Iranian regime everything it wants.” In exchange, Roskam said in a statement, the U.S. and its partners get, at best, minimal restrictions on “peripheral aspects of Iran’s nuclear program,” and more “empty promises.” During his remarks, Obama acknowledged the concerns of lawmakers and said he looks “forward to a robust debate in the days and weeks to come.” Making Calls He said he’s instructed his staff to brief lawmakers and plans to talk with the leaders of the House and Senate himself on Thursday. Obama also planned to call Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu, a vocal critic of the negotiations who has lobbied Republicans to keep up pressure on the White House. “I will underscore that the issues at stake are bigger than politics,” Obama said. “They are about war and peace.” Obama said <u>Congress will be responsible for the risk posed if it kills the deal before it’s finalized</u>. He cited the agreements reached by Republican Presidents Richard Nixon and Ronald Reagan with the Soviet Union during the Cold War. “Those agreements were not perfect,” he said. “They did not end all threats. But they made our world safer. A good deal with Iran will do the same.” As it became clear that a deal had been struck, Obama delayed his scheduled departure for a speech in Kentucky by almost three hours so that he could address the accord. Courting Democrats <u>The administration’s main goal is keeping enough Democrats behind Obama to prevent Congress from being able to override a promised veto of the legislation sponsored by Corker and</u> Robert <u>Menendez</u>, a New Jersey Democrat. The bill would require the administration to wait 60 days before suspending any sanctions against Iran, during which time lawmakers would have the opportunity to approve, reject, or take no action on the deal. <u>Corker has said his committee will take up the bill on April 14</u>. <u><mark>Republicans hold 54 seats</mark> in the Senate <mark>and would need 13 more votes to override</mark> Obama. <mark>So far, eight Democrats and one independent have signed on</mark> as cosponsors</u> of the Corker-Menendez bill. Among them is Senator Chuck Schumer of New York, who’s emerged as the likely successor to Senate Democratic leader Harry Reid in 2017. Menendez, who has been more willing than most prominent Democrats to challenge the White House on Iran, was indicted Wednesday on federal corruption charges and stepped down as the ranking Democrat on the Foreign Relations Committee. That isn’t likely to slow down consideration of the legislation. Sanctions Issue He also is the co-sponsor on another measure with Republican Senator Mark Kirk of Illinois to put new sanctions on Iran if there’s no agreement by June 30. Kirk, who’s facing a re-election challenge in 2016, said Wednesday that the administration has made “a series of dangerous nuclear concessions” in the course of negotiations. Jim Manley, a former top aide to Reid, said Republican leaders are under pressure from their members “to just stick it to the president.” If Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell overplays his hand by pushing for a quick floor vote on the legislation, that may give Obama an opening to peel off Democratic votes, he said. “They’re going to have to sell it but in a way that is understandable to the average man or woman,” Manley said of the administration. The details of any nuclear agreement “are mind-numbing in their complexity,” Manley said. Critical Briefings <u><strong><mark>The reaction of lawmakers will depend largely on how convincing the White House is</u></strong></mark> in briefings planned to explain the agreement struck in Lausanne, according to Einhorn. “<u>If the administration can make a case</u> that significant progress is being made toward a sound agreement, then it’s likely that <u>they’ll get a reprieve in terms of voting on new legislation</u>,” Einhorn said before the deal was announced. One way for Obama to make his case would be to frame the agreement as an international accord rather than just between the U.S. and Iran, said Patricia Degennaro, an adjunct professor of international security at New York University. “This is an international negotiation. It’s not just American,” she said. Bringing in international supporters of an agreement to talk with lawmakers could also help win their support, she said. Netanyahu, an opponent of an agreement, addressed Congress earlier this month. British Prime Minister David Cameron previously had telephoned U.S. lawmakers to lobby for an agreement when he visited the U.S. Gary <u><mark>Sick</mark>, <mark>a</mark> <mark>former</mark> <mark>N</mark>ational <mark>S</mark>ecurity <mark>C</mark>ouncil <mark>official</mark> who specialized on Iran</u> during the Iranian revolution and the hostage crisis, <u><mark>said that</mark> <strong><mark>Republicans will struggle to get a veto-proof majority.</mark> </u></strong>“<u>When people begin to see their actions have real consequences and those consequences could be historic, they think twice</u>,” said Sick, now an adjunct professor at Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs. “<u>A lot of Democrats would find it extremely difficult to vote against their own president in a situation like that</u>.”</p>
null
null
DA
430,555
3
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,054
Federal legalization has unpopular—no support
Kleiman 2014
Kleiman 2014 (Mark, professor of public policy at the University of California Los Angeles, How Not to Make a Hash out of Cannabis legalization, Washington Monthly, http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/magazine/march_april_may_2014/features/how_not_to_make_a_hash_out_of049291.php?page=all)
The federal government would recognize the legal status of cannabis under a state system Could such a plan garner support in Washington Certainly not given a dysfunctional Congress, an administration with no taste for engaging one more culture war issue, and in the absence of a powerful national organization with a nuanced view of cannabis policy and the muscle to make that view politically salient. legalization it’s been slow going in other states in which legalization has to go through the legislature, where anti-pot law enforcement groups can easily block it. it could be many years before legalization reaches the rest of the country or gets formal federal approval that removes the stigma no national-level figure of any standing is willing to speak out for change.
The federal government would recognize the legal status of cannabis Could such a plan garner support in Washington Certainly not given a dysfunctional Congress, an administration with no taste for engaging culture war and in the absence of a powerful national organization with the muscle to make that view politically salient anti-pot law enforcement groups can easily block it it could be many years before legalization removes the stigma no national-level figure of any standing is willing to speak out for change
How could the federal government get the states to structure their pot markets in ways like these? By giving a new twist to a tried-and-true tool that the Obama administration has wielded particularly effectively: the policy waiver. The federal government would recognize the legal status of cannabis under a state system—making the activities permitted under that system actually legal, not merely tolerated, under federal law—only if the state system contained adequate controls to protect public health and safety, as determined by the attorney general and the secretary of the department of health and human services. That would change the politics of legalization at the state level, with legalization advocates and the cannabis industry supporting tight controls in order to get, and keep, the all-important waiver. Then we would see the laboratories of democracy doing some serious experimentation. Could such a plan garner enough support in Washington to become law? Certainly not now, given a dysfunctional Congress, an administration with no taste for engaging one more culture war issue, and in the absence of a powerful national organization with a nuanced view of cannabis policy and the muscle to make that view politically salient. But there is a mutually beneficial deal waiting to be made. Though legalization has made headway in states with strong initiative provisions in their constitutions, it’s been slow going in other states in which legalization has to go through the legislature, where anti-pot law enforcement groups can easily block it. So it could be many years before legalization reaches the rest of the country or gets formal federal approval that removes the stigma of (even unpunished) lawbreaking from cannabis users. Rather than wait, legalization advocates might be willing to accept something short of full commercialization; some of them actually prefer a noncommercial system. Meanwhile, those who have been opponents of legalization heretofore might—with the writing now on the wall—decide that a tightly regulated and potentially reversible system of legal availability is the least-bad out-come available. The current political situation seems anomalous. Public opinion continues to move against cannabis prohibition, but no national-level figure of any standing is willing to speak out for change. That’s unlikely to last. Soon enough, candidates for president are going to be asked their positions on marijuana legalization. They’re going to need a good answer. I suggest something like this: “I’m not against all legalization; I’m against dumb legalization.”
2,604
<h4>Federal legalization has unpopular—no support</h4><p><strong>Kleiman 2014</strong> (Mark, professor of public policy at the University of California Los Angeles, How Not to Make a Hash out of Cannabis legalization, Washington Monthly, http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/magazine/march_april_may_2014/features/how_not_to_make_a_hash_out_of049291.php?page=all)</p><p>How could the federal government get the states to structure their pot markets in ways like these? By giving a new twist to a tried-and-true tool that the Obama administration has wielded particularly effectively: the policy waiver. <u><mark>The federal government would recognize the legal status of cannabis</mark> under a state system</u>—making the activities permitted under that system actually legal, not merely tolerated, under federal law—only if the state system contained adequate controls to protect public health and safety, as determined by the attorney general and the secretary of the department of health and human services. That would change the politics of legalization at the state level, with legalization advocates and the cannabis industry supporting tight controls in order to get, and keep, the all-important waiver. Then we would see the laboratories of democracy doing some serious experimentation. <u><mark>Could such a plan garner</u></mark> enough <u><mark>support in Washington</u></mark> to become law? <u><strong><mark>Certainly not</u></strong></mark> now, <u><mark>given a dysfunctional Congress, an administration with no taste for engaging</mark> one more <mark>culture war</mark> issue, <mark>and in the absence of a powerful national organization</mark> <mark>with</mark> a nuanced view of cannabis policy and <mark>the muscle to make that view politically salient</mark>.</u> But there is a mutually beneficial deal waiting to be made. Though <u>legalization</u> has made headway in states with strong initiative provisions in their constitutions, <u>it’s been slow going in other states in which legalization has to go through the legislature, where <mark>anti-pot law enforcement groups can easily block it</mark>.</u> So <u><mark>it could be many years before legalization</mark> reaches the rest of the country or gets formal federal approval that <mark>removes the stigma</u></mark> of (even unpunished) lawbreaking from cannabis users. Rather than wait, legalization advocates might be willing to accept something short of full commercialization; some of them actually prefer a noncommercial system. Meanwhile, those who have been opponents of legalization heretofore might—with the writing now on the wall—decide that a tightly regulated and potentially reversible system of legal availability is the least-bad out-come available. The current political situation seems anomalous. Public opinion continues to move against cannabis prohibition, but <u><strong><mark>no national-level figure of any standing is willing to speak out for change</mark>.</u></strong> That’s unlikely to last. Soon enough, candidates for president are going to be asked their positions on marijuana legalization. They’re going to need a good answer. I suggest something like this: “I’m not against all legalization; I’m against dumb legalization.”</p>
null
null
DA
64,830
174
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,055
bill tanks Iran negotiations
Cohen 3/4
Cohen 3/4 (Rachel M, The American Prospect, 3/4/15, “how to sabotage iran negotiations in the name of avoiding war”, http://prospect.org/article/how-sabotage-iran-negotiations-name-avoiding-war)
Corker-Menendez bill Edward Levine, an advisory board member for the Center for Arms Control and Non-Proliferation, a nonprofit research organization dedicated to international peace and security, argues that the bill is more harmful than helpful: send a message to Tehran that the President may be unable to fulfill his commitments move the goalposts by adding support for terrorism to the list of reasons for reinstating sanctions? The Corker bill will endanger both the negotiations and the sanctions regime; it does not merit support Let’s just hope that the Iranians do not take this as a signal that the negotiators’ commitment to ease sanctions in exchange for good behavior is feeble. Because if the negotiations fail, the war that everyone is trying to avoid is that much more likely
Corker-Menendez bill Edward Levine, an advisory board member for the Center for Arms Control and Non-Proliferation, argues that the bill is harmful t send a message to Tehran that the President may be unable to fulfill his commitments move the goalposts by adding support for terrorism to the list of reasons for reinstating sanctions will endanger both the negotiations and the sanctions regime hope that the Iranians do not take this as a signal Because if the negotiations fail, the war that everyone is trying to avoid is that much more likely.
Passing the Corker-Menendez bill might be an easier sell in Congress than imposing additional sanctions, because it is easier to argue that Congress should have “a voice” in the negotiating process. However, Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell announced Tuesday night that he wants to fast-track the bill, which might complicate its ability to garner enough Democratic support in time. Menendez has threatened to vote against his own bill, “outraged” at McConnell’s political move. Edward Levine, an advisory board member for the Center for Arms Control and Non-Proliferation, a nonprofit research organization dedicated to international peace and security, argues that the bill is more harmful than helpful: Do [Senators] really want to send a message to Tehran that the President may be unable to fulfill his commitments? Do they really want to move the goalposts by adding support for terrorism to the list of reasons for reinstating sanctions? The Corker bill will endanger both the negotiations and the sanctions regime; it does not merit support. AIPAC is also trying to bolster Congress’s role in the negotiations by minimizing the fact that there has always been significant presidential authority built into U.S. sanctions legislation. The authority comes through various mechanisms, such as “waivers,” special rules, and legislative exemptions, which allow a president to decide, often unilaterally, whether and to what degree to lift or implement sanctions. He can make these choices if he believes doing so is in the national security interest of the United States. On Capitol Hill on Tuesday, AIPAC’s legions of supporters pressured Congress to impose more sanctions and to reduce the executive branch’s power to lift sanctions. Let’s just hope that the Iranians do not take this as a signal that the negotiators’ commitment to ease sanctions in exchange for good behavior is feeble. Because if the negotiations fail, the war that everyone is trying to avoid is that much more likely.
2,000
<h4>bill tanks Iran negotiations </h4><p><strong>Cohen 3/4</strong> (Rachel M, The American Prospect, 3/4/15, “how to sabotage iran negotiations in the name of avoiding war”, http://prospect.org/article/how-sabotage-iran-negotiations-name-avoiding-war)</p><p>Passing the <u><mark>Corker-Menendez bill</u></mark> might be an easier sell in Congress than imposing additional sanctions, because it is easier to argue that Congress should have “a voice” in the negotiating process. However, Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell announced Tuesday night that he wants to fast-track the bill, which might complicate its ability to garner enough Democratic support in time. Menendez has threatened to vote against his own bill, “outraged” at McConnell’s political move. <u><mark>Edward Levine, an advisory board member for the Center for Arms Control and Non-Proliferation,</mark> a nonprofit research organization dedicated to international peace and security, <mark>argues that the bill is</mark> more <mark>harmful t</mark>han helpful: </u>Do [Senators] really want to <u><mark>send a message to Tehran that the President may be unable to fulfill his commitments</u></mark>? Do they really want to <u><mark>move the goalposts by adding support for terrorism to the list of reasons for reinstating sanctions</mark>? The Corker bill <mark>will endanger both the negotiations and the sanctions regime</mark>; it does not merit support</u>. AIPAC is also trying to bolster Congress’s role in the negotiations by minimizing the fact that there has always been significant presidential authority built into U.S. sanctions legislation. The authority comes through various mechanisms, such as “waivers,” special rules, and legislative exemptions, which allow a president to decide, often unilaterally, whether and to what degree to lift or implement sanctions. He can make these choices if he believes doing so is in the national security interest of the United States. On Capitol Hill on Tuesday, AIPAC’s legions of supporters pressured Congress to impose more sanctions and to reduce the executive branch’s power to lift sanctions. <u>Let’s just <mark>hope that the Iranians do not take this as a signal</mark> that the negotiators’ commitment to ease sanctions in exchange for good behavior is feeble. <mark>Because if the negotiations fail, the war that everyone is trying to avoid is that much more likely</u>.</mark> </p>
null
null
DA
430,304
2
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,056
Extinction - Negotiations failure triggers military strikes and regional proliferation-causes escalatory wars and collapses the economy
Cordesman, , 2013
Cordesman, CSIS, 2013 (Anthony, “Negotiating with Iran: The Strategic Case for Pragmatism and Real Progress”, 9-23, http://csis.org/publication/negotiating-iran-strategic-case-pragmatism-and-real-progress)
Nevertheless, it makes no sense at all to reject Hassan Rouhani’s opening or condemn the Obama Administration’s response Iran’s grams have moved to the point where it is extremely doubtful that there will be another chance to begin a difficult process and an attempt at resolution is far better than any of the real world alternatives. As long as any negotiations that follow are realistic in terms of their content they offer what will be the last real hope of avoiding preventive strikes or a process of containment that would lock the region into an Iranian-Israeli nuclear arms race, a probable Saudi effort to acquire its own nuclear weapons, and a U.S. commitment to extended deterrence. Iran may well face a series of preventive strikes – triggered by Israel or planned by the United States – that will destroy far more than its nuclear facilities. A limited set of Israeli preventive strikes could either force the United States to follow up, or create a situation in which Iran rejects all arms control and UN inspection and carries out a massive new disperse nuclear program or a crash basis. It could also drive Iran to lash out into a new wave of confrontation with the United States and Iran’s neighbors. result would be years more of a regional arms race, military tension, and Iranian efforts to find ways to attack or pressure the Arab states, Israel, and United States. no one can predict limits to Iran’s reactions, ability to use third parties, and willingness to confront the United States and the region with new nuclear, missile, and asymmetric threats. If there are no preventive strikes – or preventive strikes fail to halt Iran – what is now a largely quiet one-sided nuclear arms race would become far more threatening At one level, this arms race would become one between Iran and any allies it could find and the United States and its Arab allies in or near the Gulf. A nuclear Iran could change the balance in terms of the credibility of U.S. and Arab willingness to engage against Iranian threats, intimidation, and use of its asymmetric forces It would inevitably make Gulf petroleum exports the scene of an ongoing arms race and constant tension, and risk a clash that might escalate in untended ways. Israel would scarcely be passive however, and Israel already has far more capable missiles than Iran Israel will pose more of an existentialist threat to an Iran as dependent on the survival of Tehran than Iran can pose to an Israel dependent on the survival of Tel Aviv. The problem with mutually assured destruction is that no state can ever win an existential strike contest. the resulting threat to world oil exports and the world economy is not likely to intimidate to any degree that will benefit Iran. It will push both the United States and Arab states into responding. Iran can only vastly increase the scale of the resulting destruction that the United States and its allies inflict if Iran ever actually escalates to the use of nuclear weapons. But the United States, the Arab allies, Israel, and other regional states will suffer as well – along with the global economy – if the end result is a major interruption in the flow of Gulf petroleum exports.
Iran moved to where it is doubtful there will be another chance and resolution is better than alternatives they offer the last hope of avoiding strikes or containment that would lock in nuclear arms race Israeli preventive strikes force the U S to follow up, or create a situation in which Iran rejects arms control carries out a massive nuclear program or a crash basis. It could drive Iran to lash out result would be a regional arms race, military tension If there are no strikes what is a one-sided nuclear race would become more threatening between Iran and allies in the Gulf It would make Gulf petroleum exports the scene of an ongoing arms race and tension, and risk a clash that might escalate The problem with m a d is no state can ever win an existential strike the resulting threat to the world economy is not likely to intimidate Iran Iran vastly increase the resulting destruction the U S Arab allies, Israel, and regional states will suffer as well – along with the global economy
Nevertheless, it makes no sense at all to reject Hassan Rouhani’s opening or condemn the Obama Administration’s response. Iran’s nuclear programs have moved to the point where it is extremely doubtful that there will be another chance to begin what may be a long and difficult process for all nations involved, and an attempt at resolution is far better than any of the real world alternatives. As long as any negotiations that follow are realistic in terms of their content, and do not endorse indefinite delay in a U.S. response while Iran’s nuclear programs move forward, they offer what will be the last real hope of avoiding preventive strikes or a process of containment that would lock the region into an Iranian-Israeli nuclear arms race, a probable Saudi effort to acquire its own nuclear weapons, and a U.S. commitment to extended deterrence. The Uncertain Outcome of Preventive Strikes The United States, Iran, and all the other nations involved need to be far more pragmatic about what will happen if time does run out and Iran does go nuclear. Iran may well face a series of preventive strikes – triggered by Israel or planned by the United States – that will destroy far more than its nuclear facilities. This may or may not actually halt the Iranian nuclear effort. A limited set of Israeli preventive strikes could either force the United States to follow up, or create a situation in which Iran rejects all arms control and UN inspection and carries out a massive new disperse nuclear program or a crash basis. It could also drive Iran to lash out into a new wave of confrontation with the United States and Iran’s neighbors. A U.S.-led set of preventive strikes would be more successful, but the United States could only be sure of suppressing a meaningful Iran nuclear effort if it quickly re-strikes any known target it fails to destroy the first time, carries out constant surveillance of Iran, and repeatedly and thoroughly strikes at the targets created by any new Iranian initiatives. The United States would need regional support to do this and probably prolonged regional agreement to U.S. basing. At a minimum, the result would be years more of a regional arms race, military tension, and Iranian efforts to find ways to attack or pressure the Arab states, Israel, and United States. As the current conflict in Syria makes all too clear, no one can predict how much support the United States will really get from any of its allies, its own U.S. Congress, and no one can predict the limits to Iran’s reactions, ability to use third parties, and willingness to confront the United States and the region with new nuclear, missile, and asymmetric threats. The United States would face an almost certain challenge in the UN from Russia and China, and there is no way any U.S. action against Iran could be separated from Iran’s efforts in Iraq, Syria, or Lebanon; Afghanistan, or any other issue where Iran could try to find some form of revenge. This is not an argument for not acting. The risk of a fully nuclear Iran is simply too great. It is a very strong argument for finding a good alternative if one can be negotiated on realistic terms. The Uncertain Outcome of Iran Nuclear Weapons and Containment: The Most Likely Outcome is a No Win Escalation Ladder Contest If there are no preventive strikes – or preventive strikes fail to halt Iran – what is now a largely quiet one-sided nuclear arms race would become far more threatening. At one level, this arms race would become one between Iran and any allies it could find and the United States and its Arab allies in or near the Gulf. A nuclear Iran could change the balance in terms of the credibility of U.S. and Arab willingness to engage against Iranian threats, intimidation, and use of its asymmetric forces. It would inevitably make Gulf petroleum exports the scene of an ongoing arms race and constant tension, and risk a clash that might escalate in untended ways. What is less apparent – and needs far more realistic attention in Iran and outside assessments of the Iranian nuclear threat – is the impact of Iran actually going nuclear. One or several crude nuclear devices do not create a nuclear force. Iran cannot produce enough capable nuclear forces for at least the next decade to pose more of an existential threat to Israel than Israel can pose to Iran. Israel would scarcely be passive, however, and Israel already has far more capable missiles than Iran. Israel also has thermonuclear weapons, rather than the early fission devices Iran will probably be limited to for at least the next half-decade. As a result Israel will pose more of an existentialist threat to an Iran as dependent on the survival of Tehran than Iran can pose to an Israel dependent on the survival of Tel Aviv. As the United States and former Soviet Union both learned during the Cold War, even Iranian parity or superiority would be meaningless. The problem with mutually assured destruction is that no state can ever win an existential strike contest. As for the rest of the Middle East, if Iran shows it is going nuclear to enhance its power and dominate the Gulf region – as may be Iran’s real motive – the resulting threat to world oil exports and the world economy is not likely to intimidate to any degree that will benefit Iran. It will push both the United States and Arab states into responding. The fact Iran succeeded in acquiring nuclear weapons might increase the level of deterrence of a direct invasion, but would not lead the United States, or surrounding Arab states to passively accept the result. The United States already is transferring more than ten times the value of Iran’s total arms imports to its Gulf allies. Its ties to Kuwait, Bahrain, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the UAE, and Oman already give the United States and its Gulf allies the ability to devastatingly defeat Iran in any direct military confrontation. Iran can only vastly increase the scale of the resulting destruction that the United States and its allies inflict if Iran ever actually escalates to the use of nuclear weapons. But the United States, the Arab allies, Israel, and other regional states will suffer as well – along with the global economy – if the end result is a major interruption in the flow of Gulf petroleum exports.
6,292
<h4>Extinction - Negotiations failure triggers <u>military strikes and regional proliferation</u><strong>-causes escalatory wars and collapses the economy</h4><p>Cordesman, </strong>CSIS<strong>, 2013</p><p></strong>(Anthony, “Negotiating with Iran: The Strategic Case for Pragmatism and Real Progress”, 9-23, http://csis.org/publication/negotiating-iran-strategic-case-pragmatism-and-real-progress<u><strong>)</p><p></strong>Nevertheless, it makes no sense at all to reject Hassan Rouhani’s opening or condemn the Obama Administration’s response</u>. <u><mark>Iran</mark>’s</u> nuclear pro<u>grams have <mark>moved to </mark>the point <mark>where it is</mark> extremely <mark>doubtful</mark> that <mark>there will be another chance</mark> to begin </u>what may be <u>a</u> long and <u>difficult process</u> for all nations involved, <u><strong><mark>and </mark>an attempt at <mark>resolution is</mark> far <mark>better than</mark> any of the real world <mark>alternatives</mark>. </strong>As long as any negotiations that follow are realistic in terms of their content</u>, and do not endorse indefinite delay in a U.S. response while Iran’s nuclear programs move forward, <u><strong><mark>they offer</mark> what will be <mark>the last</mark> real <mark>hope of avoiding </mark>preventive <mark>strikes or</mark> a process of <mark>containment that would lock </mark>the region <mark>in</mark>to an Iranian-Israeli <mark>nuclear arms race</mark>, a probable Saudi effort to acquire its own nuclear weapons, and a U.S. commitment to extended deterrence. </u></strong>The Uncertain Outcome of Preventive Strikes The United States, Iran, and all the other nations involved need to be far more pragmatic about what will happen if time does run out and Iran does go nuclear. <u>Iran may well face a series of preventive strikes – triggered by Israel or planned by the United States – that will destroy far more than its nuclear facilities.</u> This may or may not actually halt the Iranian nuclear effort. <u>A limited set of <mark>Israeli preventive strikes </mark>could either <mark>force the U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates <mark>to follow up, or create a situation in which Iran rejects </mark>all <mark>arms control</mark> and UN inspection and <mark>carries out a massive</mark> new disperse <mark>nuclear program <strong>or a crash basis. It could</mark> also <mark>drive Iran to lash out </mark>into a new wave of confrontation with the United States and Iran’s neighbors. </u></strong>A U.S.-led set of preventive strikes would be more successful, but the United States could only be sure of suppressing a meaningful Iran nuclear effort if it quickly re-strikes any known target it fails to destroy the first time, carries out constant surveillance of Iran, and repeatedly and thoroughly strikes at the targets created by any new Iranian initiatives. The United States would need regional support to do this and probably prolonged regional agreement to U.S. basing. At a minimum, the <u><mark>result would be </mark>years more of <mark>a regional arms race, military tension</mark>, and Iranian efforts to find ways to attack or pressure the Arab states, Israel, and United States. </u>As the current conflict in Syria makes all too clear, <u>no one can predict</u> how much support the United States will really get from any of its allies, its own U.S. Congress, and no one can predict the <u>limits to Iran’s reactions, ability to use third parties, and willingness to confront the United States and the region with new nuclear, missile, and asymmetric threats. </u>The United States would face an almost certain challenge in the UN from Russia and China, and there is no way any U.S. action against Iran could be separated from Iran’s efforts in Iraq, Syria, or Lebanon; Afghanistan, or any other issue where Iran could try to find some form of revenge. This is not an argument for not acting. The risk of a fully nuclear Iran is simply too great. It is a very strong argument for finding a good alternative if one can be negotiated on realistic terms. The Uncertain Outcome of Iran Nuclear Weapons and Containment: The Most Likely Outcome is a No Win Escalation Ladder Contest <u><mark>If there are no </mark>preventive <mark>strikes</mark> – or preventive strikes fail to halt Iran – <mark>what is</mark> now <mark>a</mark> largely quiet <mark>one-sided nuclear </mark>arms <mark>race would <strong>become</mark> far <mark>more threatening</u></strong></mark>. <u><strong>At one level, this arms race would become one <mark>between Iran and</mark> any <mark>allies</mark> it could find and the United States and its Arab allies <mark>in</mark> or near <mark>the Gulf</mark>. </strong>A nuclear Iran could change the balance in terms of the credibility of U.S. and Arab willingness to engage against Iranian threats, intimidation, and use of its asymmetric forces</u>. <u><strong><mark>It would</mark> inevitably <mark>make Gulf petroleum exports the scene of an ongoing arms race and </mark>constant <mark>tension, and risk a clash that might escalate</mark> in untended ways. </u></strong>What is less apparent – and needs far more realistic attention in Iran and outside assessments of the Iranian nuclear threat – is the impact of Iran actually going nuclear. One or several crude nuclear devices do not create a nuclear force. Iran cannot produce enough capable nuclear forces for at least the next decade to pose more of an existential threat to Israel than Israel can pose to Iran. <u>Israel would scarcely be passive</u>, <u>however, and Israel already has far more capable missiles than Iran</u>. Israel also has thermonuclear weapons, rather than the early fission devices Iran will probably be limited to for at least the next half-decade. As a result <u>Israel will pose more of an existentialist threat to an Iran as dependent on the survival of Tehran than Iran can pose to an Israel dependent on the survival of Tel Aviv. </u>As the United States and former Soviet Union both learned during the Cold War, even Iranian parity or superiority would be meaningless. <u><strong><mark>The problem with m</mark>utually <mark>a</mark>ssured<mark> d</mark>estruction<mark> is </mark>that <mark>no state can ever win an existential strike </mark>contest. </u></strong>As for the rest of the Middle East, if Iran shows it is going nuclear to enhance its power and dominate the Gulf region – as may be Iran’s real motive – <u><mark>the resulting threat to</mark> world oil exports and <mark>the world economy is not likely to intimidate</mark> to any degree that will benefit <mark>Iran</mark>. It will push both the United States and Arab states into responding. </u>The fact Iran succeeded in acquiring nuclear weapons might increase the level of deterrence of a direct invasion, but would not lead the United States, or surrounding Arab states to passively accept the result. The United States already is transferring more than ten times the value of Iran’s total arms imports to its Gulf allies. Its ties to Kuwait, Bahrain, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the UAE, and Oman already give the United States and its Gulf allies the ability to devastatingly defeat Iran in any direct military confrontation. <u><strong><mark>Iran </mark>can only <mark>vastly increase the </mark>scale of the <mark>resulting destruction</mark> that the United States and its allies inflict if Iran ever actually escalates to the use of nuclear weapons.</u></strong> <u>But <mark>the</mark> <mark>U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates, the <mark>Arab allies, Israel, and </mark>other <mark>regional states will suffer as well – along with the global economy</mark> – if the end result is a major interruption in the flow of Gulf petroleum exports.</p></u>
null
null
DA
247,504
18
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,057
The fifty United States and relevant territories should legalize nearly all marihuana through sustainably produced outdoor cultivation.
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>The fifty United States and relevant territories should legalize nearly all marihuana through sustainably produced outdoor cultivation.</h4>
null
null
CP
430,556
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,058
The United States Supreme Court should apply a clear statement rule to enforcement of provisions of the Controlled Substances Act relating to marihuana, finding that it does not contain a clear statement intended to preempt state marihuana laws nor a clear statement authorizing commandeering of state resources for enforcement of federal marihuana laws. The United States Attorney General should offer each state government a contract stipulating that the Justice Department will exercise prosecutorial discretion in its enforcement of federal marihuana laws, specifically taking no enforcement action against entities clearly following the marihuana laws of that state. The United States federal government should prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks and credit unions for providing financial services to state-licensed marihuana businesses.
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>The United States Supreme Court should apply a clear statement rule to enforcement of provisions of the Controlled Substances Act relating to marihuana, finding that it does not contain a clear statement intended to preempt state marihuana laws nor a clear statement authorizing commandeering of state resources for enforcement of federal marihuana laws. The United States Attorney General should offer each state government a contract stipulating that the Justice Department will exercise prosecutorial discretion in its enforcement of federal marihuana laws, specifically taking no enforcement action against entities clearly following the marihuana laws of that state. The United States federal government should prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks and credit unions for providing financial services to state-licensed marihuana businesses.</h4>
null
null
CP
430,557
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,059
CP solves- only 1% of marijuana cases are federal- we end virtually all enforcement
Schwartz 2013
Schwartz 2013 (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)
forcing Congress to internalize the fiscal costs of federal regulation is a significant check, and allowing it to externalize costs is a significant incentive to commandeer. marijuana legalization provides a salient example the shifting of fiscal costs onto the states through commandeering is potentially enormous there were approximately 120,000 federal law enforcement agents in the United States, compared to 765,000 at the state level only 1 percent of the roughly 800,000 marijuana cases generated every year are handled by federal authorities commandeering state officials to enforce the CSA could create a massive shift in law enforcement costs onto the states The idea that the courts might have the power to accomplish this large-scale commandeering through an aggressive CSA-preemption ruling should alarm anyone who believes in political safeguards of federalism Such a judicial application of preemption doctrine would bypass the significant political obstacles that would likely prevent Congress from taking such a step directly
only 1 percent of marijuana cases generated every year are handled by federal authorities commandeering state officials to enforce the CSA could create a massive shift in law enforcement costs a judicial application of preemption doctrine would bypass political obstacles that would prevent Congress from taking such a step directly
Still, to convince proponents of the political safeguards of federalism to overcome their resistance to a categorical anti-commandeering rule may take some work. Young and others have explained the rule as serving state autonomy interests by forcing Congress to internalize the costs - political and fiscal - of federal legislation. n236 The New York and Printz Courts both made much of the "democratic accountability" problem created by commandeering, which could be used by Congress to make an unpopular policy look like it emanated from the state. n237 This problem can be overblown, of course. Externalizing political costs - making the state the bad guy through commandeering - might be an issue in the case of an obscure, complex regulatory scheme like that involved in New York; but it would hardly have been an issue in Printz, where it would have been a simple matter for local police chiefs to inform the public that they were reluctantly enforcing a federal law that they strongly opposed, where the law had been well publicized, and where it would be easy for the public to understand the point. A much stronger rationale for anti-commandeering is its tendency to prevent Congress from externalizing the financial costs of the law: By forcing state governments to absorb the financial burden of implementing a federal regulatory program, Members of Congress can take credit for "solving" problems without having to ask their constituents to pay for the solutions with higher federal taxes. n238 Given the culture of resistance to taxes and government spending, forcing Congress to internalize the fiscal costs of federal regulation is a significant check, and allowing it to externalize costs is a significant incentive to commandeer. [*633] The marijuana legalization issue provides a salient example. The accountability issue is minimal: Any reasonably well-informed person in a marijuana legalization state knows that it is federal law that imposes the strict prohibition. But the shifting of fiscal costs onto the states through commandeering is potentially enormous. As of 2008, there were approximately 120,000 federal law enforcement agents in the United States, compared to 765,000 at the state level. n239 Professor Mikos reports that "only 1 percent of the roughly 800,000 marijuana cases generated every year are handled by federal authorities." n240 Thus, commandeering state officials to enforce the CSA could create a massive shift in law enforcement costs onto the states. The idea that the courts might have the power to accomplish this large-scale commandeering through an aggressive CSA-preemption ruling should alarm anyone who believes in political safeguards of federalism. Such a judicial application of preemption doctrine would bypass the significant political obstacles that would likely prevent Congress from taking such a step directly.
2,875
<h4>CP solves- only 1% of marijuana cases are federal- we end virtually all enforcement</h4><p><strong>Schwartz 2013</strong> (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)</p><p>Still, to convince proponents of the political safeguards of federalism to overcome their resistance to a categorical anti-commandeering rule may take some work. Young and others have explained the rule as serving state autonomy interests by forcing Congress to internalize the costs - political and fiscal - of federal legislation. n236 The New York and Printz Courts both made much of the "democratic accountability" problem created by commandeering, which could be used by Congress to make an unpopular policy look like it emanated from the state. n237 This problem can be overblown, of course. Externalizing political costs - making the state the bad guy through commandeering - might be an issue in the case of an obscure, complex regulatory scheme like that involved in New York; but it would hardly have been an issue in Printz, where it would have been a simple matter for local police chiefs to inform the public that they were reluctantly enforcing a federal law that they strongly opposed, where the law had been well publicized, and where it would be easy for the public to understand the point. A much stronger rationale for anti-commandeering is its tendency to prevent Congress from externalizing the financial costs of the law: By forcing state governments to absorb the financial burden of implementing a federal regulatory program, Members of Congress can take credit for "solving" problems without having to ask their constituents to pay for the solutions with higher federal taxes. n238 Given the culture of resistance to taxes and government spending, <u>forcing Congress to internalize the fiscal costs of federal regulation is a significant check, and allowing it to externalize costs is a significant incentive to commandeer. </u>[*633] The <u>marijuana legalization</u> issue <u>provides a salient example</u>. The accountability issue is minimal: Any reasonably well-informed person in a marijuana legalization state knows that it is federal law that imposes the strict prohibition. But <u>the shifting of fiscal costs onto the states through commandeering is potentially enormous</u>. As of 2008, <u>there were approximately 120,000 federal law enforcement agents in the United States, compared to 765,000 at the state level</u>. n239 Professor Mikos reports that "<u><strong><mark>only 1 percent of </mark>the roughly 800,000 <mark>marijuana cases generated every year are handled by federal authorities</u></strong></mark>." n240 Thus, <u><mark>commandeering state officials to enforce the CSA could create a massive shift in law enforcement costs </mark>onto the states</u>. <u>The idea that the courts might have the power to accomplish this large-scale commandeering through an aggressive CSA-preemption ruling should alarm anyone who believes in political safeguards of federalism</u>. <u>Such <mark>a judicial application of preemption doctrine would bypass </mark>the significant <mark>political obstacles that would </mark>likely <mark>prevent Congress from taking such a step directly</u></mark>.</p>
null
null
CP
430,416
19
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,060
Contracting solves certainty- provides safe harbor
Kleiman 2013 (Mark, professor of public policy at UCLA, “Federalism and cannabis policy: the terms of a bargain,” August 23rd, http://www.samefacts.com/2013/08/drug-policy/federalism-and-cannabis-policy-the-terms-of-a-bargain/)
Kleiman 2013 (Mark, professor of public policy at UCLA, “Federalism and cannabis policy: the terms of a bargain,” August 23rd, http://www.samefacts.com/2013/08/drug-policy/federalism-and-cannabis-policy-the-terms-of-a-bargain/)
I offer two alternatives to the options as to how the federal government can deal with state-level cannabis legalization. Washington and Colorado would like the feds to let their new commercial systems operate the Controlled Substances Act orders the Attorney General to cooperate with state and local officials in enforcing the law, and authorizes contractual arrangements with states formal deals in which the Justice Department would agree to keep hands off state-licensed businesses in return for the states’ active help in suppressing interstate trade That wouldn’t make the state-authorized activity legal but formalize a program of selective enforcement that would give state licensees an effective safe harbor.
two alternatives the Controlled Substances Act orders the Attorney General to cooperate with state and local officials contractual arrangements” with states in which the Justice Department would agree to keep hands off businesses in return for the states’ active help in suppressing interstate trade That wouldn’t make the state-authorized activity legal, but formalize selective enforcement that would give state licensees a safe harbor
The Journal of Drug Policy Analysis has just published a new paper (behind a paywall) in which I offer two alternatives to the options currently in public discussion as to how the federal government can deal with state-level cannabis legalization. This fall, Washington and Colorado intend to start licensing businesses to produce and sell cannabis under voter-passed initiatives, even though the stuff remains illegal under federal law. The federal government has not yet said what it plans to do about it, and its three obvious options – acquiescing, cracking down, and muddling through – all have fairly serious drawbacks. A number of what Keith calls Formerly Important Persons have demanded that the feds crush the state-legal Colorado and Washington markets. Since every participant in those markets needs a license, that wouldn’t be hard to do: any federal judge would cheerfully enjoin someone applying for license to commit a federal felony from doing so. But the state-legal commercial markets represent only one of three systems that can deliver cannabis to customers. The loosely-regulated “medical marijuana” markets would be a far tougher nut for the feds to crack. And the purely illicit system, which handles the vast bulk of transactions today, is way too big for 4000 DEA agents to suppress without help. More than 90% of arrests for growing and dealing marijuana are made by state and local cops. So the feds need state and local authorities in Washington and Colorado to maintain pressure on illegal growing. Constitutionally, the states have no mandate to even have drug laws, let alone enforce them. In this case, federalism is more than a legal doctrine: it’s a brute fact. So: Washington and Colorado would like the feds to let their new commercial systems operate. And the feds would like Washington and Colorado to suppress production for out-of-state sale. When each of two parties has something the other wants, that’s the basis for a bargain. And the Controlled Substances Act (Sec. 873, if you’re keeping score at home) orders the Attorney General to cooperate with state and local officials in enforcing the law, and authorizes him, “notwithstanding any other provision of law,” to enter into “contractual arrangements” with states and localities. The paper proposes that he use that authority to make formal deals with Colorado and Washington in which the Justice Department would agree to keep hands off state-licensed businesses in return for the states’ active help in suppressing interstate trade. That wouldn’t make the state-authorized activity legal, but it could formalize a program of targeted, selective enforcement that would give state licensees an effective safe harbor.
2,715
<h4>Contracting solves certainty- provides safe harbor</h4><p><strong>Kleiman 2013</strong> <u><strong>(Mark, professor of public policy at UCLA, “Federalism and cannabis policy: the terms of a bargain,” August 23rd, http://www.samefacts.com/2013/08/drug-policy/federalism-and-cannabis-policy-the-terms-of-a-bargain/)</p><p></u></strong>The Journal of Drug Policy Analysis has just published a new paper (behind a paywall) in which <u>I offer <mark>two alternatives</mark> to the options </u>currently in public discussion <u>as to how the federal government can deal with state-level cannabis legalization. </u>This fall, Washington and Colorado intend to start licensing businesses to produce and sell cannabis under voter-passed initiatives, even though the stuff remains illegal under federal law. The federal government has not yet said what it plans to do about it, and its three obvious options – acquiescing, cracking down, and muddling through – all have fairly serious drawbacks. A number of what Keith calls Formerly Important Persons have demanded that the feds crush the state-legal Colorado and Washington markets. Since every participant in those markets needs a license, that wouldn’t be hard to do: any federal judge would cheerfully enjoin someone applying for license to commit a federal felony from doing so. But the state-legal commercial markets represent only one of three systems that can deliver cannabis to customers. The loosely-regulated “medical marijuana” markets would be a far tougher nut for the feds to crack. And the purely illicit system, which handles the vast bulk of transactions today, is way too big for 4000 DEA agents to suppress without help. More than 90% of arrests for growing and dealing marijuana are made by state and local cops. So the feds need state and local authorities in Washington and Colorado to maintain pressure on illegal growing. Constitutionally, the states have no mandate to even have drug laws, let alone enforce them. In this case, federalism is more than a legal doctrine: it’s a brute fact. So: <u>Washington and Colorado would like the feds to let their new commercial systems operate</u>. And the feds would like Washington and Colorado to suppress production for out-of-state sale. When each of two parties has something the other wants, that’s the basis for a bargain. And <u><mark>the Controlled Substances Act</u></mark> (Sec. 873, if you’re keeping score at home) <u><mark>orders the Attorney General to cooperate with state and local officials</mark> in enforcing the law, and authorizes</u> him, “notwithstanding any other provision of law,” to enter into “<u><mark>contractual arrangements</u>” <u>with states</u></mark> and localities. The paper proposes that he use that authority to make <u>formal deals</u> with Colorado and Washington <u><mark>in which the Justice Department would agree to keep hands off</mark> state-licensed <mark>businesses in return for the states’ active help in suppressing interstate trade</u></mark>. <u><strong><mark>That wouldn’t make the state-authorized activity legal</u></strong>, <u><strong>but</u></strong></mark> it could <u><strong><mark>formalize</mark> a program of</u></strong> targeted, <u><strong><mark>selective enforcement</mark> <mark>that would give state licensees</mark> <mark>a</mark>n effective <mark>safe harbor</mark>.</p></u></strong>
null
null
CP
56,742
9
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,061
Solves banking access for marijuana businesses and avoids politics
American Banker 2014
American Banker 7/18/2014 (House Gives Thumbs-Up to Marijuana Banking, lexis)
The House gave a thumbs-up to allowing the marijuana industry into the banking system The legislation, which passed by a 231-192 margin, would prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks and credit unions for providing financial services to state-licensed pot businesses. the House vote marks another step in the direction of bringing marijuana enterprises into the financial mainstream The House measure passed with the support of 186 Democrats and 45 Republicans and was hailed by the marijuana industry as a landmark This is a huge step forward for the legal cannabis industry The legislation has yet to pass in the Senate Since recreational marijuana was legalized in Colorado and Washington state, a coalition that includes the pot industry, elected officials, and law enforcement agencies in those states have been calling for marijuana businesses to be brought into the banking system
The House gave a thumbs-up to allowing the marijuana industry into the banking system legislation would prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks for providing financial services to state-licensed pot businesses The measure passed with the support of 186 Democrats and 45 Republicans, and was hailed by the industry as a landmark a coalition that includes the pot industry, elected officials, and law enforcement agencies have been calling for marijuana businesses to be brought into the banking system
The House of Representatives gave a thumbs-up Wednesday to allowing the marijuana industry into the banking system. The legislation, which passed by a 231-192 margin, would prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks and credit unions for providing financial services to state-licensed pot businesses. It is unclear if the measure will make a difference for banks and credit unions that are weighing the risks involved with serving the pot business. Marijuana remains illegal under federal law, but numerous states have legalized its medicinal or recreational use, and that conflict puts banks in a difficult position. Still, the House vote marks another step in the direction of bringing marijuana enterprises into the financial mainstream. In February, the Financial Crimes Enforcement Network released guidance for banks interested in serving the pot industry. The House measure passed with the support of 186 Democrats and 45 Republicans, and was hailed by the marijuana industry as a landmark. "This is a huge step forward for the legal cannabis industry," Aaron Smith, executive director of the National Cannabis Industry Association, said in a news release. The legislation, which was introduced as an amendment to a financial services appropriations bill, has yet to pass in the Senate. The House version was sponsored by Democratic Reps. Denny Heck, Ed Perlmutter and Barbara Lee and GOP Rep. Dana Rohrabacher. A competing amendment, which would have blocked the implementation of the Fincen guidance on marijuana, was defeated by a 236-186 margin. Since recreational marijuana was legalized in Colorado and Washington state, a coalition that includes the pot industry, elected officials, and law enforcement agencies in those states have been calling for marijuana businesses to be brought into the banking system. They argue that as long as pot enterprises operate as cash-only businesses, they are susceptible to threats such as armed robbery and money laundering.
1,984
<h4>Solves banking access for marijuana businesses and avoids politics</h4><p><strong>American Banker</strong> 7/18/<strong>2014</strong> (House Gives Thumbs-Up to Marijuana Banking, lexis)</p><p><u><mark>The House</u></mark> of Representatives <u><mark>gave a thumbs-up</u></mark> Wednesday <u><mark>to allowing the marijuana industry into the banking system</u></mark>. <u>The <mark>legislation</mark>, which passed by a 231-192 margin, <mark>would prohibit the use of federal funds to penalize banks</mark> and credit unions <mark>for providing financial services to state-licensed pot businesses</mark>. </u>It is unclear if the measure will make a difference for banks and credit unions that are weighing the risks involved with serving the pot business. Marijuana remains illegal under federal law, but numerous states have legalized its medicinal or recreational use, and that conflict puts banks in a difficult position. Still, <u>the House vote marks another step in the direction of bringing marijuana enterprises into the financial mainstream</u>. In February, the Financial Crimes Enforcement Network released guidance for banks interested in serving the pot industry. <u><strong><mark>The</mark> House <mark>measure passed</strong> with the support of <strong>186 Democrats and 45 Republicans</u></strong>, <u>and was hailed by the</mark> marijuana <mark>industry as a landmark</u></mark>. "<u><strong>This is a huge step forward for the legal cannabis industry</u></strong>," Aaron Smith, executive director of the National Cannabis Industry Association, said in a news release. <u>The legislation</u>, which was introduced as an amendment to a financial services appropriations bill, <u>has yet to pass in the Senate</u>. The House version was sponsored by Democratic Reps. Denny Heck, Ed Perlmutter and Barbara Lee and GOP Rep. Dana Rohrabacher. A competing amendment, which would have blocked the implementation of the Fincen guidance on marijuana, was defeated by a 236-186 margin. <u>Since recreational marijuana was legalized in Colorado and Washington state, <mark>a coalition that includes the pot industry, elected officials, and law enforcement agencies</mark> in those states <mark>have been calling for marijuana</mark> <mark>businesses</mark> <mark>to be brought into the banking system</u></mark>. They argue that as long as pot enterprises operate as cash-only businesses, they are susceptible to threats such as armed robbery and money laundering.</p>
null
null
CP
430,418
16
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,062
The CP is key to judicial protection against commandeering- that’s the single biggest issue of federalism
Schwartz 2013
Schwartz 2013 (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)
The anti-commandeering rule after Reno provides less guidance than one might hope for courts to apply the CSA to state marijuana legalization Doctrines come and go, their contours, strength, and existence tested by hard cases We need to ask whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong enough and clear enough to overcome a strong belief possibly held by key justices that constitutional law must somehow accommodate the imposition of a federal anti-drug policy on the states. the anti-commandeering doctrine is not exactly entrenched; the vote of just one of the five conservative justices could produce a decision qualifying or limiting the anti-commandeering doctrine, if not entirely scrapping it in order to make room for de facto commandeering of state officials under the CSA Possible qualifications and loopholes can be found in Printz and Reno such a loophole would make it easier to characterize the CSA - even the arrest/seizure hypothetical - as "not commandeering" Requiring state police officers to make the arrest and seizure, and perhaps to transfer the suspect or the marijuana or both to federal custody, would constitute a regulatory adjustment ultimately designed to regulate would-be consumers of marijuana, just as Reno required state compliance with federal regulations controlling would-be consumers of drivers' data while it is easy to distinguish the CSA from the DPPA, it is also possible to emphasize important similarities The point here is not that the anti-commandeering doctrine is incoherent and theoretically incapable of answering the arrest/seizure problem or other marijuana federalism questions the question is whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong and clear enough to constrain justices from indulging in an anti-marijuana-legalization policy preference by fitting the CSA into easily conceived loopholes in the anti-commandeering doctrine if a federal command to state police to make arrests and seizures for CSA violations is not impermissible commandeering, nothing is
We need to ask whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is clear enough to overcome a strong belief by key justices that constitutional law must accommodate the imposition of federal anti-drug policy on the states the vote of just one conservative justice could limit the anti-commandeering doctrine, in order to make room for commandeering a loophole would make it easier to characterize the as "not commandeering" Requiring state police officers to make the arrest perhaps transfer the suspect to federal custody, the question is whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong and clear enough to constrain justices from indulging in loopholes , if a federal command to state police to make arrests for CSA violations is not impermissible commandeering, nothing is.
B. The Anti-Commandeering Rule After Reno: Limits and Loopholes The anti-commandeering rule after Reno provides less guidance than one might hope for courts to apply the CSA to state marijuana legalization. We can start by asking whether Reno's doctrinal formulas supply an answer. To be sure, a federal law requiring a state police officer to arrest a suspect under the CSA appears to be a "federal [*617] regulation of the state's regulation of private parties." If this is the current definition of what is forbidden by the anti-commandeering doctrine, or even the hard core of a broader concept that is fuzzy around the edges, perhaps the anti-commandeering doctrine does indeed resolve the arrest-seizure hypothetical and other aspects of the marijuana federalism crisis besides. But the question becomes more complicated when posed in a more pragmatic form. Doctrines come and go, their contours, strength, and existence tested by hard cases. Cases are hard when case-specific considerations of justice or public policy go against the pre-existing doctrine. We need to ask whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong enough and clear enough to overcome a strong belief possibly held by key justices that constitutional law must somehow accommodate the imposition of a federal anti-drug policy on the states. Given the 5-4 margin in Printz and continuing scholarly criticism, the anti-commandeering doctrine is not exactly entrenched; the vote of just one of the five conservative justices could produce a decision qualifying or limiting the anti-commandeering doctrine, if not entirely scrapping it, in order to make room for de facto commandeering of state officials under the CSA. n193 [*618] So just how strong and clear is the anti-commandeering doctrine? Possible qualifications and loopholes can be found in Printz and Reno. To begin with, Printz characterized its holding as one invalidating a law whose "whole object" was "to direct the functioning of the state executive." n194 Plainly, that is not the "whole object" of the CSA, most of which is aimed at direct federal regulation of drug users, manufacturers, and distributors. If "whole object" is the test of impermissible commandeering laws, then the CSA - indeed most federal laws - could escape that net. Control over state officials is rarely, if ever, a federal regulatory end in itself. The description is not particularly applicable even to the law at issue in Printz: If the Brady Act had any identifiable "whole object," it was to require background checks of gun purchasers, not to regulate state police. Reno's definition of prohibited commandeering - laws that regulate the states' regulation of private parties - is undoubtedly more robust than the "whole object" formula, yet even that seems less than ironclad on close scrutiny. On the one hand, it makes sense to distinguish Reno from Printz by saying that the Brady Act conscripted state officials in the regulation of private gun purchasers (by requiring the state CLEOs to participate in background checks), whereas the DPPA in Reno regulated the state's primary conduct in selling drivers' data. While the DPPA aimed at protecting the privacy rights of private drivers' licensees, that is not the same thing as regulating them, if "regulation of private parties" in the Reno anti-commandeering formula means subjecting private behavior to restrictions - a reasonable definition - rather than providing private parties with protections or benefits. n195 On the other hand, such a view of Reno requires that we ignore the would-be purchasers of the drivers' data, who certainly experience their behavior as significantly restricted by rules, since their efforts to purchase data will be limited or denied. Does it make sense to say that the would-be purchasers are "unregulated" or "merely incidentally regulated" by the law? Perhaps. But, at the same time, it would be far from absurd to say that they are regulated by the law. The DPPA's regulation of the state is merely a means to regulate the sale of drivers' [*619] information to the private data-miners; indeed, the purpose of the DPPA was to crack down on lax state regulation of the sale of private data to private parties - by the state and by private data sellers. It is thus quite easy to characterize the DPPA as a regulation of the state's regulation of private parties. n196 By focusing on the case's facts rather than the Court's effort to doctrinalize them, Reno can be read to permit some significant federal regulation of states that Printz seemed to have taken off the table. "Regulating the states' regulation of private parties" is a pithy and seemingly clear definition of prohibited commandeering, but it blurs considerably when we try to apply it carefully to the facts of Reno. We can next try to excavate an anti-commandeering rule from the facts of Reno by making further qualifications - perhaps by saying that laws like the DPPA are not commandeering if they primarily regulate state official behavior and at most incidentally regulate private conduct. We might thereby succeed in harmonizing Reno as a correctly decided anti-commandeering case, but only at the cost of widening the loophole in the previously clear and straightforward anti-commandeering doctrine. Significantly for present purposes, however, such a loophole would make it easier to characterize the CSA - even the arrest/seizure hypothetical - as "not commandeering" under Reno. Requiring state police officers to make the arrest and seizure, and perhaps to transfer the suspect or the marijuana or both to federal custody, would constitute a regulatory adjustment ultimately designed to regulate would-be consumers of marijuana, just as Reno required state compliance with federal regulations controlling would-be consumers of drivers' data. Put another way, while it is easy to distinguish the CSA from the DPPA, it is also possible to emphasize important similarities. Perhaps even the result deemed impermissible in Printz - requiring local law enforcement officers to conduct background checks on gun purchasers - could itself be upheld post-Reno if the law were patterned more closely on the DPPA. n197 [*620] Reno's treatment of the "general applicability" doctrine further complicates the anti-commandeering rule. A future Court might well decide that Reno will jettison the "general applicability" doctrine as the touchstone of permissible federal regulation of states, expanding permissible regulation to extend to anything that does not "regulate the states' regulation of private parties." But the Reno Court did not make this move; it assumed arguendo that general applicability was a bottom line constitutional requirement and found the DPPA to be generally applicable. That aspect of the ruling is itself noteworthy. In prior general applicability cases, the law in question regulated the state's relationships with its own employees or instrumentalities in a manner analogous to the federal regulation of private relationships - such as employing workers or running a transit company. In Reno, however, the DPPA was deemed generally applicable even though it governed the state's interactions with private parties. The point here is not that the anti-commandeering doctrine is incoherent and theoretically incapable of answering the arrest/seizure problem or other marijuana federalism questions. Rather the question is whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong and clear enough to constrain justices from indulging in an anti-marijuana-legalization policy preference by fitting the CSA into easily conceived loopholes in the anti-commandeering doctrine. If there is a coherent core to an anti-commandeering doctrine, then the arrest/seizure hypothetical lies squarely within it. Put another way, if a federal command to state police to make arrests and seizures for CSA violations is not impermissible commandeering, nothing is. I take it as a given that a state's control over the arrest authority of its police is so fundamental that any anti-commandeering rule that allows the federal commandeering of state police to enforce federal criminal law is not worth the trouble. The Court showed a continued commitment to the anti-commandeering rule in National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, n198 where seven justices relied on it as a premise for the conclusion that states cannot be coerced under the conditional spending power. n199 But Reno muddies the waters by suggesting the existence of significant qualifications or loopholes in the anti-commandeering rule.
8,598
<h4>The CP is key to judicial protection against commandeering- that’s the single biggest issue of federalism</h4><p><strong>Schwartz 2013</strong> (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)</p><p>B. The Anti-Commandeering Rule After Reno: Limits and Loopholes <u>The anti-commandeering rule after Reno provides less guidance than one might hope for courts to apply the CSA to state marijuana legalization</u>. We can start by asking whether Reno's doctrinal formulas supply an answer. To be sure, a federal law requiring a state police officer to arrest a suspect under the CSA appears to be a "federal [*617] regulation of the state's regulation of private parties." If this is the current definition of what is forbidden by the anti-commandeering doctrine, or even the hard core of a broader concept that is fuzzy around the edges, perhaps the anti-commandeering doctrine does indeed resolve the arrest-seizure hypothetical and other aspects of the marijuana federalism crisis besides. But the question becomes more complicated when posed in a more pragmatic form. <u>Doctrines come and go, their contours, strength, and existence tested by hard cases</u>. Cases are hard when case-specific considerations of justice or public policy go against the pre-existing doctrine. <u><strong><mark>We need to ask whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is </mark>strong enough</strong> and <mark>clear enough <strong>to overcome a strong belief</strong> </mark>possibly held <strong><mark>by key justices that constitutional law must </mark>somehow <mark>accommodate the imposition of </mark>a <mark>federal anti-drug</mark> <mark>policy on the states</mark>.</u></strong> Given the 5-4 margin in Printz and continuing scholarly criticism, <u>the <strong>anti-commandeering doctrine is not</strong> exactly <strong>entrenched</strong>; <mark>the vote of just one </mark>of the five <mark>conservative justice</mark>s<mark> could </mark>produce a decision qualifying or <mark>limit</mark>ing<mark> the anti-commandeering doctrine,</mark> if not entirely scrapping it</u>, <u><mark>in order to make room for </mark>de facto <mark>commandeering </mark>of state officials under the CSA</u>. n193 [*618] So just how strong and clear is the anti-commandeering doctrine? <u>Possible qualifications and loopholes can be found in Printz and Reno</u>. To begin with, Printz characterized its holding as one invalidating a law whose "whole object" was "to direct the functioning of the state executive." n194 Plainly, that is not the "whole object" of the CSA, most of which is aimed at direct federal regulation of drug users, manufacturers, and distributors. If "whole object" is the test of impermissible commandeering laws, then the CSA - indeed most federal laws - could escape that net. Control over state officials is rarely, if ever, a federal regulatory end in itself. The description is not particularly applicable even to the law at issue in Printz: If the Brady Act had any identifiable "whole object," it was to require background checks of gun purchasers, not to regulate state police. Reno's definition of prohibited commandeering - laws that regulate the states' regulation of private parties - is undoubtedly more robust than the "whole object" formula, yet even that seems less than ironclad on close scrutiny. On the one hand, it makes sense to distinguish Reno from Printz by saying that the Brady Act conscripted state officials in the regulation of private gun purchasers (by requiring the state CLEOs to participate in background checks), whereas the DPPA in Reno regulated the state's primary conduct in selling drivers' data. While the DPPA aimed at protecting the privacy rights of private drivers' licensees, that is not the same thing as regulating them, if "regulation of private parties" in the Reno anti-commandeering formula means subjecting private behavior to restrictions - a reasonable definition - rather than providing private parties with protections or benefits. n195 On the other hand, such a view of Reno requires that we ignore the would-be purchasers of the drivers' data, who certainly experience their behavior as significantly restricted by rules, since their efforts to purchase data will be limited or denied. Does it make sense to say that the would-be purchasers are "unregulated" or "merely incidentally regulated" by the law? Perhaps. But, at the same time, it would be far from absurd to say that they are regulated by the law. The DPPA's regulation of the state is merely a means to regulate the sale of drivers' [*619] information to the private data-miners; indeed, the purpose of the DPPA was to crack down on lax state regulation of the sale of private data to private parties - by the state and by private data sellers. It is thus quite easy to characterize the DPPA as a regulation of the state's regulation of private parties. n196 By focusing on the case's facts rather than the Court's effort to doctrinalize them, Reno can be read to permit some significant federal regulation of states that Printz seemed to have taken off the table. "Regulating the states' regulation of private parties" is a pithy and seemingly clear definition of prohibited commandeering, but it blurs considerably when we try to apply it carefully to the facts of Reno. We can next try to excavate an anti-commandeering rule from the facts of Reno by making further qualifications - perhaps by saying that laws like the DPPA are not commandeering if they primarily regulate state official behavior and at most incidentally regulate private conduct. We might thereby succeed in harmonizing Reno as a correctly decided anti-commandeering case, but only at the cost of widening the loophole in the previously clear and straightforward anti-commandeering doctrine. Significantly for present purposes, however, <u>such <mark>a loophole would make it easier to characterize the </mark>CSA - even the arrest/seizure hypothetical - <mark>as "not commandeering"</u></mark> under Reno. <u><mark>Requiring state police officers to make the arrest </mark>and seizure, and <mark>perhaps </mark>to <mark>transfer the suspect </mark>or the marijuana or both <mark>to federal custody, </mark>would constitute a regulatory adjustment ultimately designed to regulate would-be consumers of marijuana, just as Reno required state compliance with federal regulations controlling would-be consumers of drivers' data</u>. Put another way, <u>while it is easy to distinguish the CSA from the DPPA, it is also possible to emphasize important similarities</u>. Perhaps even the result deemed impermissible in Printz - requiring local law enforcement officers to conduct background checks on gun purchasers - could itself be upheld post-Reno if the law were patterned more closely on the DPPA. n197 [*620] Reno's treatment of the "general applicability" doctrine further complicates the anti-commandeering rule. A future Court might well decide that Reno will jettison the "general applicability" doctrine as the touchstone of permissible federal regulation of states, expanding permissible regulation to extend to anything that does not "regulate the states' regulation of private parties." But the Reno Court did not make this move; it assumed arguendo that general applicability was a bottom line constitutional requirement and found the DPPA to be generally applicable. That aspect of the ruling is itself noteworthy. In prior general applicability cases, the law in question regulated the state's relationships with its own employees or instrumentalities in a manner analogous to the federal regulation of private relationships - such as employing workers or running a transit company. In Reno, however, the DPPA was deemed generally applicable even though it governed the state's interactions with private parties. <u>The point here is not that the anti-commandeering doctrine is incoherent and theoretically incapable of answering the arrest/seizure problem or other marijuana federalism questions</u>. Rather <u><mark>the question is whether the anti-commandeering doctrine is strong and clear enough to constrain justices from indulging in </mark>an anti-marijuana-legalization policy preference by fitting the CSA into easily conceived <mark>loopholes </mark>in the anti-commandeering doctrine</u>. If there is a coherent core to an anti-commandeering doctrine, then the arrest/seizure hypothetical lies squarely within it. Put another way<mark>, <u><strong>if a federal command to state police to make arrests </mark>and seizures <mark>for CSA violations is not impermissible commandeering, nothing is</u></strong>.</mark> I take it as a given that a state's control over the arrest authority of its police is so fundamental that any anti-commandeering rule that allows the federal commandeering of state police to enforce federal criminal law is not worth the trouble. The Court showed a continued commitment to the anti-commandeering rule in National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, n198 where seven justices relied on it as a premise for the conclusion that states cannot be coerced under the conditional spending power. n199 But Reno muddies the waters by suggesting the existence of significant qualifications or loopholes in the anti-commandeering rule.</p>
null
null
CP
430,417
18
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,063
Federalism model solves Ukraine war
Sasse and Hughes 2014
Sasse and Hughes 2014 (Gwendolyn Sasse and James Hughes 3-19-2014; Professorial Fellow, Nuffield College & University Reader in Comparative Politics at Oxford and London School of Economics political scientist “Building a federal Ukraine?” Washington Post http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-cage/wp/2014/03/19/building-a-federal-ukraine/)
The idea of a remaking of Ukraine’s constitutional order along federal lines is beginning to gain traction. Yatsenyuk reached out to Russophones announcing that “new measures linked to decentralization of power will be reflected in a new constitution Senior U.S. administration officials have encouraged the Ukrainian leadership to consider constitutional reform along federal lines. Until recently the federal idea was an anathema The turmoil in Ukraine suggests that now is a good time to reassess the potential for federalism, “ethno-” or otherwise, for managing divided places like Ukraine. The de facto loss of Crimea could provide the momentum needed for Ukraine’s political elites to embark on a more fundamental reform of the Ukrainian state Overall, Ukraine’s elites have been moderate in their approach to state- and nation-building. Ukraine now needs to reestablish regional balance and has the opportunity to formalize a hitherto informal mechanism. a state-wide comprehensive federalization or decentralization of more powers to all regions We could expect greater powers to include self-government reform process could be achieved by either a constitutional convention, or a constitutional committee in parliament, followed by a state-wide referendum. These steps would generate a democratic process of debate, dialogue and engagement, and hopefully reunite Ukrainian society. There would be international monitoring and advice This would be no bad thing, since one thing that the United States and the E.U. are not short of is experts on , federalism implementation depends critically on leadership The causal link between ethnically defined federalism and state instability appears to be misdirected. In reality, it was precisely the “de-institutionalization of autonomy” by titular nationalities in the successor states that often provoked ethnic conflict The Ukraine crisis offers an opportune moment to reassess the value of autonomy and federalism to peacefully manage conflict and enhance state stability federal concept is now central to how policymakers see the way forward in Ukraine
U.S. officials have encouraged leadership to consider constitutional reform along federal lines Ukraine’s elites have been moderate Ukraine now needs regional balance and has the opportunity to formalize a mechanism decentralization could be achieved by con con These steps would generate engagement, and reunite Ukrainian society. There would be international monitoring and advice. This would be no bad thing, since one thing that the U S are not short of is experts on federalism implementation depends critically on leadership Ukraine offers an opportune moment to reassess the value of federalism to peacefully manage conflict
The idea of a remaking of Ukraine’s constitutional order along federal lines is beginning to gain traction. On March 18, Ukrainian Prime Minister Arseniy Yatsenyuk reached out to Russophones in the eastern and southern regions, announcing that “new measures linked to decentralization of power will be reflected in a new constitution.” Senior U.S. administration officials have encouraged the Ukrainian leadership to consider constitutional reform along federal lines. On March 17, the Russian Foreign Ministry proposed the establishment of an international “support group” to manage the crisis. The list of items that Russia wants to be the basis for negotiation in Ukraine includes a new federal structure for Ukraine and the recognition of Russian as a second language. Until recently the federal idea was an anathema among the greater part of Ukraine’s political elite. As a constitutional form it was largely rejected in the 1990s, partly as a negative reaction to the experience of Soviet federalism, and partly from fear of its centrifugal potential for splitting the country along ethnolinguistic fault lines. The negative view of federalism as a destabilizing constitutional order in ethnically divided places was one that was not only perceived by elites as a lived experience in former communist federations, such as the Soviet Union successor states Yugoslavia and Czechoslovakia, but was also prevalent among scholars studying the collapse of communism. Federalism, or “ethnofederalism” as it was usually termed by political scientists, came to be seen as part of the problem of “mismanaging” ethnically diverse countries, not part of the solution. The turmoil in Ukraine suggests that now is a good time to reassess the potential for federalism, “ethno-” or otherwise, for managing divided places like Ukraine. Prospects for federalism in Ukraine The de facto loss of Crimea could provide the momentum needed for Ukraine’s political elites to embark on a more fundamental reform of the Ukrainian state. The ideas of decentralization and federalism have undulated in the Ukrainian political discourse since the early 1990s. At first these ideas were an agenda of the western regions. Rukh leader Vyacheslav Chornovil and the ‘national-democratic’ forces he represented promoted federalism as a means to protect the cultural distinctiveness of Western Ukraine. From the mid-to late 1990s, after independence, calls for autonomy or federalism came from the mainly Russophone south-east and Crimea, in particular in crisis situations like the Orange Revolution or the recent protests. Overall, Ukraine’s elites have been moderate in their approach to state- and nation-building. The first president of Ukraine, Leonid Kravchuk, did not impose the state language on the southeast or Crimea as envisaged by the Ukrainian language law. The cautious approach continued after the 1994 presidential elections, which saw the “eastern” candidate Leonid Kuchma defeat Kravchuk. Although Kuchma ran on an election platform of more power to the regions and the recognition of the Russian language as an official language, he actually did not deliver on this agenda during his two terms in office between 1994 and 2004. The implicit consensus on balancing regional interests helped to preserve political stability during Ukraine’s transition, while also slowing economic reforms and adjustment. It was also evident in the ambivalent foreign policy approaches toward Russia and the European Union/ NATO. Ukraine now needs to reestablish this important regional balance and has the opportunity to formalize a hitherto informal mechanism. There are two scenarios: First, there could be an asymmetric decentralization (that is, different agreements with different regions of the country). The new government in Kiev could engage in bilateral negotiations with individual regions in the south-east. Given the long-standing inability of Ukrainian elites to agree on the reform of center-regional relations as whole, a selective divide and rule strategy offers the advantages of fragmenting the “Russophone” bloc, and the potential for making deals on a case-by-case basis. Such a process would inevitably be largely non-transparent. This asymmetric federal approach, as with Russian President Boris Yeltsin’s approach to ethnic republics in Russia in the mid-1990s, might generate some short-term stability but it would also antagonize other regions and would be vulnerable to unraveling. Second, there could be a state-wide process of constitutional reform with the aim of either a comprehensive federalization, or decentralization of more powers to all regions. We could expect greater powers to include self-government in culture (including language and education), economic management, taxation, and policing. The election (rather than the presidential appointment) of regional governors is an important aspect of reform. This could be part of a synchronization of regional elections, including for governors, with early parliamentary elections. This reform process could be achieved by either a constitutional convention, or a constitutional committee in parliament, followed by a state-wide referendum. These steps would generate a democratic process of debate, dialogue and engagement, and hopefully reunite Ukrainian society. There would almost certainly be international monitoring and advice. This would be no bad thing, since one thing that the United States and the E.U. are not short of is legal experts on autonomy, federalism and minority rights. The implementation of constitutional reform depends critically on political will and leadership, and it would have to be championed by the new president to be elected in May. Constitutional reform will be on the agenda in any event, as Ukraine currently finds itself between constitutions (2004 and 2010) – and neither of these constitutions was clearly defined. Regional oligarchs will also have to be part of this process. Just how they are to be managed in the new Ukraine will be one of the greatest challenges facing the political elites. A properly functioning constitutional court that is insulated better against political interference is crucial for decentralization or federalization to be lasting. Opponents of federalization will no doubt raise the dangers of state disintegration and secession that might flow from such a constitutional reform process, especially given the Crimea example and the ongoing unrest in the southeast. The fact that Russia has indicated that greater autonomy is its own preferred outcome for Ukraine means, however, that there is now potential for substantive negotiations to move forward – assuming that Russia can switch off the Russian nationalist mobilization that it has so far been promoting. Reassessing the turn against “ethnofederalism” There was a turn against ethnofederalism in the 1990s that is ripe for a reassessment. Prior to the collapse of communism, there was a dominant paradigm that federalism as “self rule and shared rule” has positive “win-win” effects on promoting stable politics, and indeed, that it was the constitutional order (following the U.S. example) that was most conducive to democracy. Federalism was also seen as an essential constitutional design for the “politics of accommodation” in “deeply divided” or “plural” societies. From the early 1990s this paradigm was shaken by critiques which argued that federalism and autonomy more generally were highly destabilizing in ethnically divided states where the federal administrative architecture and boundaries were drawn to reflect ethnic divisions. The three socialist ethnofederations (USSR, Yugoslavia and Czechoslovakia) were used as cases to demonstrate this thesis. The argument is that the mode of socialist federalism, which while it was intrinsically a “sham” in terms of power distribution given that real power resided in communist parties, was flawed because of its “ethnic” structure leading to a mismanagement of nationalism. Consequently, a major cause of the collapse was the fact that the previously disempowered federal architecture became a platform for ethnonational mobilization. Socialist-era federal structures were essentially “subversive institutions”. The negative thesis was developed further in perspectives on the “frozen conflicts” to include even the prospect of autonomy and decentralization. In the Caucasus region, autonomy was seen as “a root cause of conflict” and a driver for secession. The causal link between ethnically defined federalism and state instability appears to be misdirected. In reality, it was precisely the “de-institutionalization of autonomy” by titular nationalities in the successor states that often provoked ethnic conflict. The Russian Federation is partially divided into ethnic units, and only Chechnya posed a serious threat to its territorial integrity. If one analyzes the case of Tatarstan and other ethnic republics of the Russian Federation the fact is that the asymmetric federalism and autonomy in key areas relating to self-rule, culture and, to some extent, economic power, was sufficient to quash secessionist demands and maintain state stability. That stability has persisted even when Putin recentralized powers from the ethnic republics to create his “power vertical” (see this recent Monkey Cage post). A similar argument holds with regard to conflict-prevention in Crimea in the 1990s (see the recent Monkey Cage post). The Ukraine crisis offers an opportune moment to reassess the value of autonomy and federalism to peacefully manage conflict and enhance state stability. It is of note that the federal concept is now central to how policymakers see the way forward not just in Ukraine but in other places of conflict in the post-communist space, and beyond (for example, Iraq, Syria, and Libya).
9,859
<h4>Federalism model solves Ukraine war </h4><p><strong>Sasse and Hughes 2014</strong> (Gwendolyn Sasse and James Hughes 3-19-2014; Professorial Fellow, Nuffield College & University Reader in Comparative Politics at Oxford and London School of Economics political scientist “Building a federal Ukraine?” Washington Post http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-cage/wp/2014/03/19/building-a-federal-ukraine/)</p><p><u>The idea of a <strong>remaking</strong> of Ukraine’s constitutional order along federal lines is beginning to gain traction.</u> On March 18, Ukrainian Prime Minister Arseniy <u>Yatsenyuk</u> <u>reached out to Russophones</u> in the eastern and southern regions, <u>announcing that “new measures linked to decentralization of power will be reflected in a new constitution</u>.” <u>Senior <mark>U.S.</mark> administration <mark>officials have <strong>encouraged</strong></mark> the Ukrainian <mark>leadership to consider constitutional reform <strong>along federal lines</mark>. </u></strong>On March 17, the Russian Foreign Ministry proposed the establishment of an international “support group” to manage the crisis. The list of items that Russia wants to be the basis for negotiation in Ukraine includes a new federal structure for Ukraine and the recognition of Russian as a second language. <u>Until recently the federal idea was an anathema</u> among the greater part of Ukraine’s political elite. As a constitutional form it was largely rejected in the 1990s, partly as a negative reaction to the experience of Soviet federalism, and partly from fear of its centrifugal potential for splitting the country along ethnolinguistic fault lines. The negative view of federalism as a destabilizing constitutional order in ethnically divided places was one that was not only perceived by elites as a lived experience in former communist federations, such as the Soviet Union successor states Yugoslavia and Czechoslovakia, but was also prevalent among scholars studying the collapse of communism. Federalism, or “ethnofederalism” as it was usually termed by political scientists, came to be seen as part of the problem of “mismanaging” ethnically diverse countries, not part of the solution. <u>The turmoil in Ukraine suggests that now <strong>is a good time to reassess the potential for federalism</strong>, “ethno-” or otherwise, for managing divided places like Ukraine. </u>Prospects for federalism in Ukraine <u>The de facto loss of Crimea could provide the momentum needed for Ukraine’s political elites to embark on a more fundamental reform of the Ukrainian state</u>. The ideas of decentralization and federalism have undulated in the Ukrainian political discourse since the early 1990s. At first these ideas were an agenda of the western regions. Rukh leader Vyacheslav Chornovil and the ‘national-democratic’ forces he represented promoted federalism as a means to protect the cultural distinctiveness of Western Ukraine. From the mid-to late 1990s, after independence, calls for autonomy or federalism came from the mainly Russophone south-east and Crimea, in particular in crisis situations like the Orange Revolution or the recent protests. <u>Overall, <mark>Ukraine’s elites have been moderate</mark> in their approach to state- and nation-building. </u>The first president of Ukraine, Leonid Kravchuk, did not impose the state language on the southeast or Crimea as envisaged by the Ukrainian language law. The cautious approach continued after the 1994 presidential elections, which saw the “eastern” candidate Leonid Kuchma defeat Kravchuk. Although Kuchma ran on an election platform of more power to the regions and the recognition of the Russian language as an official language, he actually did not deliver on this agenda during his two terms in office between 1994 and 2004. The implicit consensus on balancing regional interests helped to preserve political stability during Ukraine’s transition, while also slowing economic reforms and adjustment. It was also evident in the ambivalent foreign policy approaches toward Russia and the European Union/ NATO. <u><mark>Ukraine now needs</mark> to reestablish</u> this important <u><mark>regional balance</u> <u>and has the opportunity to <strong>formalize a</strong> </mark>hitherto informal <mark>mechanism</mark>. </u>There are two scenarios: First, there could be an asymmetric decentralization (that is, different agreements with different regions of the country). The new government in Kiev could engage in bilateral negotiations with individual regions in the south-east. Given the long-standing inability of Ukrainian elites to agree on the reform of center-regional relations as whole, a selective divide and rule strategy offers the advantages of fragmenting the “Russophone” bloc, and the potential for making deals on a case-by-case basis. Such a process would inevitably be largely non-transparent. This asymmetric federal approach, as with Russian President Boris Yeltsin’s approach to ethnic republics in Russia in the mid-1990s, might generate some short-term stability but it would also antagonize other regions and would be vulnerable to unraveling. Second, there could be <u>a state-wide</u> process of constitutional reform with the aim of either a <u>comprehensive federalization</u>, <u>or <mark>decentralization</mark> of more powers to all regions</u>. <u>We could expect greater powers to include self-government</u> in culture (including language and education), economic management, taxation, and policing. The election (rather than the presidential appointment) of regional governors is an important aspect of reform. This could be part of a synchronization of regional elections, including for governors, with early parliamentary elections. This <u>reform process <mark>could be achieved by </mark>either a <mark>con</mark>stitutional <mark>con</mark>vention, or a constitutional committee in parliament, followed by a state-wide referendum. <mark>These steps would generate </mark>a democratic process of debate, dialogue and <mark>engagement, and</mark> hopefully <strong><mark>reunite Ukrainian society. There would</strong></mark> </u>almost certainly<u><strong><mark> be</strong> <strong>international monitoring and advice</u></strong>. <u>This would be no bad thing, since one thing that the U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates and the E.U. <mark>are <strong>not short of is</strong></mark> </u>legal<u> <strong><mark>experts on</strong></mark> </u>autonomy<u>, <strong><mark>federalism</strong></mark> </u>and minority rights. The<u> <mark>implementation</mark> </u>of constitutional reform<u> <mark>depends critically on</mark> </u>political will and <u><mark>leadership</u></mark>, and it would have to be championed by the new president to be elected in May. Constitutional reform will be on the agenda in any event, as Ukraine currently finds itself between constitutions (2004 and 2010) – and neither of these constitutions was clearly defined. Regional oligarchs will also have to be part of this process. Just how they are to be managed in the new Ukraine will be one of the greatest challenges facing the political elites. A properly functioning constitutional court that is insulated better against political interference is crucial for decentralization or federalization to be lasting. Opponents of federalization will no doubt raise the dangers of state disintegration and secession that might flow from such a constitutional reform process, especially given the Crimea example and the ongoing unrest in the southeast. The fact that Russia has indicated that greater autonomy is its own preferred outcome for Ukraine means, however, that there is now potential for substantive negotiations to move forward – assuming that Russia can switch off the Russian nationalist mobilization that it has so far been promoting. Reassessing the turn against “ethnofederalism” There was a turn against ethnofederalism in the 1990s that is ripe for a reassessment. Prior to the collapse of communism, there was a dominant paradigm that federalism as “self rule and shared rule” has positive “win-win” effects on promoting stable politics, and indeed, that it was the constitutional order (following the U.S. example) that was most conducive to democracy. Federalism was also seen as an essential constitutional design for the “politics of accommodation” in “deeply divided” or “plural” societies. From the early 1990s this paradigm was shaken by critiques which argued that federalism and autonomy more generally were highly destabilizing in ethnically divided states where the federal administrative architecture and boundaries were drawn to reflect ethnic divisions. The three socialist ethnofederations (USSR, Yugoslavia and Czechoslovakia) were used as cases to demonstrate this thesis. The argument is that the mode of socialist federalism, which while it was intrinsically a “sham” in terms of power distribution given that real power resided in communist parties, was flawed because of its “ethnic” structure leading to a mismanagement of nationalism. Consequently, a major cause of the collapse was the fact that the previously disempowered federal architecture became a platform for ethnonational mobilization. Socialist-era federal structures were essentially “subversive institutions”. The negative thesis was developed further in perspectives on the “frozen conflicts” to include even the prospect of autonomy and decentralization. In the Caucasus region, autonomy was seen as “a root cause of conflict” and a driver for secession. <u>The causal link between ethnically defined federalism and state instability appears to be misdirected.</u> <u>In reality, it was precisely the “de-institutionalization of autonomy” by titular nationalities in the successor states that often provoked ethnic conflict</u>. The Russian Federation is partially divided into ethnic units, and only Chechnya posed a serious threat to its territorial integrity. If one analyzes the case of Tatarstan and other ethnic republics of the Russian Federation the fact is that the asymmetric federalism and autonomy in key areas relating to self-rule, culture and, to some extent, economic power, was sufficient to quash secessionist demands and maintain state stability. That stability has persisted even when Putin recentralized powers from the ethnic republics to create his “power vertical” (see this recent Monkey Cage post). A similar argument holds with regard to conflict-prevention in Crimea in the 1990s (see the recent Monkey Cage post). <u>The <mark>Ukraine</mark> crisis <mark>offers an opportune moment to reassess the value of</mark> autonomy and <mark>federalism to <strong>peacefully manage conflict</mark> </strong>and <strong>enhance state stability</u></strong>. It is of note that the <u>federal concept is now central to how policymakers see the way forward</u> not just <u>in Ukraine</u> but in other places of conflict in the post-communist space, and beyond (for example, Iraq, Syria, and Libya).</p>
null
null
CP
242,776
13
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,064
Nuke war
Thompson 14
Loren Thompson 4-24-2014 “Four Ways The Ukraine Crisis Could Escalate To Use Of Nuclear Weapons” http://www.forbes.com/sites/lorenthompson/2014/04/24/four-ways-the-ukraine-crisis-could-escalate-to-use-of-nuclear-weapons/
this year’s crisis over Ukraine is a reminder that Russia remains a nuclear superpower, and that the geopolitical sources of its security concerns have not vanished Moscow may have greater reason for worrying today, because it has lost the buffer of allies that insulated it from Western attack during the Cold War, and now finds its capital only a few minutes from the eastern border of Ukraine it is easy to see why Moscow might fear aggression. the Obama Administration credibility is on the line with regional allies and Russian leader Vladimir Putin has not been helpful in defusing the fears of his neighbors Having fomented revolt in eastern Ukraine Moscow now says it might be forced to come to the aid of ethnic Russians Meanwhile, the U.S. has increased its own military presence in the neighborhood reiterating security guarantees to local members of NATO tensions are ratcheting up. successive revisions of Russian military strategy appear “to place a greater reliance on nuclear weapons” to balance the U.S. advantage in high-tech conventional weapons. Russian doctrine explicitly recognizes the possibility of using nuclear weapons in response to conventional aggression Not only does Moscow see nuclear use as a potential escalatory option in a regional war, but it also envisions using nuclear weapons to de-escalate a conflict. This isn’t just Russian saber-rattling The U.S. and its NATO partners too envision the possibility of nuclear use in a European war The Obama Administration had the opportunity to back away and instead decided it would retain forward-deployed nuclear weapons improbable though it may seem, doctrine and capabilities exist on both sides that could lead to nuclear use in a confrontation over Ukraine what started out as a local crisis could turn into something much worse. It is easy to imagine misjudgments in Ukraine which Washington and Moscow approach from very different perspectives Any deployment could provoke Russian escalation. Misinterpretation of signals can become a reciprocal process that sends both sides up the “ladder of escalation” quickly, to a point where nuclear use seems like the logical next step. Whichever side found itself losing would have to weigh the drawbacks of losing against those of escalating to the use of tactical nuclear weapons U.S. policy even envisions letting allies deliver tactical warheads against enemy targets. Russian doctrine endorses nuclear-weapons use in response to conventional aggression threatening the homeland, and obstacles to local initiative often break down once hostilities commence. When you consider all the processes working to degrade restraint in wartime — poor intelligence, garbled communication, battlefield setbacks, command attenuation, and a host of other influences — it seems reasonable to consider that a military confrontation between NATO and Russia might in some manner escalate out of control, even to the point of using nuclear weapons. because Ukraine is so close to the Russian heartland there’s no telling what might happen once the nuclear “firebreak” is crossed. All this terminology — firebreaks, ladders of escalation, extended deterrence — was devised during the Cold War to deal with potential warfighting scenarios in Europe. So if there is a renewed possibility of tensions leading to war over Ukraine (or some other former Soviet possession), perhaps the time has come to revive such thinking.
this year’s crisis is a reminder that geopolitical concerns have not vanished Putin might be forced to aid ethnic Russians Meanwhile, the U.S. has increased its own military presence tensions are ratcheting up revisions of Russian military strategy place a greater reliance on nuclear weapons” in response to conventional aggression it also envisions using nuclear weapons to de-escalate This isn’t saber-rattling It is easy to imagine misjudgments Misinterpretation can become a reciprocal process that sends both sides up the “ladder of escalation” quickly U.S. policy even envisions letting allies deliver tactical warheads When you consider all the processes working to degrade restraint — poor intel battlefield setbacks, command attenuation, and other influences — it seems reasonable to consider because Ukraine is so close there’s no telling what might happen once the nuclear “firebreak” is crossed
Americans haven’t thought much about such scenarios since the Cold War ended, because the Soviet Union dissolved and the ideological rivalry between Washington and Moscow ceased. However, this year’s crisis over Ukraine is a reminder that Russia remains a nuclear superpower, and that the geopolitical sources of its security concerns have not vanished. In fact, Moscow may have greater reason for worrying today, because it has lost the buffer of allies that insulated it from Western attack during the Cold War, and now finds its capital only a few minutes from the eastern border of Ukraine by jet (less by missile). If you know the history of the region, then it is easy to see why Moscow might fear aggression. Although the Obama Administration is responding cautiously to Moscow’s annexation of Ukraine’s province of Crimea in March, its credibility is on the line with regional allies and Russian leader Vladimir Putin has not been helpful in defusing the fears of his neighbors. Having fomented revolt in eastern Ukraine, Moscow now says it might be forced to come to the aid of ethnic Russians there (it has massed 40,000 troops on the other side of the border, in what was first called an exercise). Meanwhile, the U.S. has increased its own military presence in the neighborhood, reiterating security guarantees to local members of NATO. So little by little, tensions are ratcheting up. One facet of the regional military balance that bears watching is the presence of so-called nonstrategic nuclear weapons on both sides. Once called tactical nuclear weapons, these missiles, bombs and other devices were bought during the Cold War to compensate for any shortfalls in conventional firepower during a conflict. According to Amy Woolf of the Congressional Research Service, the U.S. has about 200 such weapons in Europe, some of which are available for use by local allies in a war. Woolf says Russia has about 2,000 nonstrategic nuclear warheads in its active arsenal — many of them within striking distance of Ukraine — and that successive revisions of Russian military strategy appear “to place a greater reliance on nuclear weapons” to balance the U.S. advantage in high-tech conventional weapons. A 2011 study by the respected RAND Corporation came to much the same conclusion, stating that Russian doctrine explicitly recognizes the possibility of using nuclear weapons in response to conventional aggression. Not only does Moscow see nuclear use as a potential escalatory option in a regional war, but it also envisions using nuclear weapons to de-escalate a conflict. This isn’t just Russian saber-rattling. The U.S. and its NATO partners too envision the possibility of nuclear use in a European war. The Obama Administration had the opportunity to back away from such thinking in a 2010 Nuclear Posture Review, and instead decided it would retain forward-deployed nuclear weapons in Europe under a doctrine known as extended deterrence. Eastern European nations that joined NATO after the Soviet collapse have been especially supportive of having U.S. nuclear weapons nearby. So improbable though it may seem, doctrine and capabilities exist on both sides that could lead to nuclear use in a confrontation over Ukraine. Here are four ways that what started out as a local crisis could turn into something much worse. Bad intelligence. As the U.S. has stumbled from one military mis-adventure to another over the last several decades, it has become clear that Washington isn’t very good at interpreting intelligence. Even when vital information is available, it gets filtered by preconceptions and bureaucratic processes so that the wrong conclusions are drawn. Similar problems exist in Moscow. For instance, the Cuban missile crisis of 1962 arose partly from Soviet leader Khrushchev’s assessment that President Kennedy was weaker than he turned out to be, and the U.S. Navy nearly provoked use of a nuclear torpedo by a Russian submarine during the blockade because it misjudged the enemy’s likely reaction to being threatened. It is easy to imagine similar misjudgments in Ukraine, which Washington and Moscow approach from very different perspectives. Any sizable deployment of U.S. forces in the region could provoke Russian escalation. Defective signaling. When tensions are high, rival leaders often seek to send signals about their intentions as a way of shaping outcomes. But the meaning of such signals can easily be confused by the need of leaders to address multiple audiences at the same time, and by the different frames of reference each side is applying. Even the process of translation can change the apparent meaning of messages in subtle ways. So when Russian foreign minister Lavrov spoke this week (in English) about the possible need to come to the aid of ethnic Russians in eastern Ukraine, Washington had to guess whether he was stating the public rationale for an invasion, sending a warning signal to Kiev about its internal counter-terror campaign, or trying to accomplish some other purpose. Misinterpretation of such signals can become a reciprocal process that sends both sides up the “ladder of escalation” quickly, to a point where nuclear use seems like the logical next step. Looming defeat. If military confrontation between Russia and NATO gave way to conventional conflict, one side or the other would eventually face defeat. Russia has a distinct numerical advantage in the area around Ukraine, but its military consists mainly of conscripts and is poorly equipped compared with Western counterparts. Whichever side found itself losing would have to weigh the drawbacks of losing against those of escalating to the use of tactical nuclear weapons. Moscow would have to contemplate the possibility of a permanent enemy presence near its heartland, while Washington might face the collapse of NATO, its most important alliance. In such circumstances, the use of “only” one or two tactical nuclear warheads to avert an outcome with such far-reaching consequences might seem reasonable — especially given the existence of relevant capabilities and supportive doctrine on both sides. Command breakdown. Strategic nuclear weapons like intercontinental ballistic missiles are tightly controlled by senior military leaders in Russia and America, making their unauthorized or accidental use nearly impossible. That is less the case with nonstrategic nuclear weapons, which at some point in the course of an escalatory process need to be released to the control of local commanders if they are to have military utility. U.S. policy even envisions letting allies deliver tactical warheads against enemy targets. Moscow probably doesn’t trust its allies to that degree, but with more tactical nuclear weapons in more locations, there is a greater likelihood that local Russian commanders might have the latitude to initiate nuclear use in the chaos of battle. Russian doctrine endorses nuclear-weapons use in response to conventional aggression threatening the homeland, and obstacles to local initiative often break down once hostilities commence. When you consider all the processes working to degrade restraint in wartime — poor intelligence, garbled communication, battlefield setbacks, command attenuation, and a host of other influences — it seems reasonable to consider that a military confrontation between NATO and Russia might in some manner escalate out of control, even to the point of using nuclear weapons. And because Ukraine is so close to the Russian heartland (about 250 miles from Moscow) there’s no telling what might happen once the nuclear “firebreak” is crossed. All this terminology — firebreaks, ladders of escalation, extended deterrence — was devised during the Cold War to deal with potential warfighting scenarios in Europe. So if there is a renewed possibility of tensions leading to war over Ukraine (or some other former Soviet possession), perhaps the time has come to revive such thinking.
7,969
<h4>Nuke war </h4><p>Loren <strong>Thompson</strong> 4-24-20<strong>14</strong> “Four Ways The Ukraine Crisis Could Escalate To Use Of Nuclear Weapons” http://www.forbes.com/sites/lorenthompson/2014/04/24/four-ways-the-ukraine-crisis-could-escalate-to-use-of-nuclear-weapons/</p><p>Americans haven’t thought much about such scenarios since the Cold War ended, because the Soviet Union dissolved and the ideological rivalry between Washington and Moscow ceased. However, <u><mark>this year’s crisis</mark> over Ukraine <mark>is a reminder that </mark>Russia remains a nuclear superpower, and that the <mark>geopolitical</mark> sources of its security <mark>concerns have not vanished</u></mark>. In fact, <u>Moscow may have greater reason for worrying today, because it has lost the buffer of allies that insulated it from Western attack during the Cold War, and now finds its capital only a few minutes from the eastern border of Ukraine</u> by jet (less by missile). If you know the history of the region, then <u>it is easy to see why Moscow might fear aggression. </u>Although <u>the Obama Administration</u> is responding cautiously to Moscow’s annexation of Ukraine’s province of Crimea in March, its <u>credibility is on the line with regional allies and Russian leader Vladimir <mark>Putin</mark> has not been helpful in defusing the fears of his neighbors</u>. <u>Having fomented <strong>revolt</strong> in eastern Ukraine</u>, <u>Moscow now says it <mark>might be forced to</mark> <strong>come to the <mark>aid</mark> of <mark>ethnic Russians</u></strong></mark> there (it has massed 40,000 troops on the other side of the border, in what was first called an exercise). <u><mark>Meanwhile, the U.S. has increased its own military presence</mark> in the neighborhood</u>, <u>reiterating security guarantees to local members of NATO</u>. So little by little,<u> <strong><mark>tensions</strong> are <strong>ratcheting up</mark>. </u></strong>One facet of the regional military balance that bears watching is the presence of so-called nonstrategic nuclear weapons on both sides. Once called tactical nuclear weapons, these missiles, bombs and other devices were bought during the Cold War to compensate for any shortfalls in conventional firepower during a conflict. According to Amy Woolf of the Congressional Research Service, the U.S. has about 200 such weapons in Europe, some of which are available for use by local allies in a war. Woolf says Russia has about 2,000 nonstrategic nuclear warheads in its active arsenal — many of them within striking distance of Ukraine — and that <u>successive <mark>revisions of Russian military strategy</mark> appear “to <mark>place a <strong>greater reliance on nuclear</mark> <mark>weapons”</strong> </mark>to balance the U.S. advantage in high-tech conventional weapons. </u>A 2011 study by the respected RAND Corporation came to much the same conclusion, stating that <u>Russian doctrine explicitly recognizes the possibility of using nuclear weapons <mark>in response to conventional aggression</u></mark>. <u>Not only does Moscow see nuclear use as a potential escalatory option in a regional war, but <mark>it also envisions using nuclear weapons to de-escalate</mark> a conflict. <mark>This <strong>isn’t</strong></mark> just Russian <strong><mark>saber-rattling</u></strong></mark>. <u>The U.S. and its NATO partners too envision the possibility of nuclear use in a European war</u>. <u>The Obama Administration had the opportunity to back away</u> from such thinking in a 2010 Nuclear Posture Review, <u>and instead decided it would retain forward-deployed nuclear weapons</u> in Europe under a doctrine known as extended deterrence. Eastern European nations that joined NATO after the Soviet collapse have been especially supportive of having U.S. nuclear weapons nearby. So <u>improbable though it may seem, doctrine and capabilities exist on both sides that could lead to nuclear use in a confrontation over Ukraine</u>. Here are four ways that <u>what started out as a local crisis could turn into something <strong>much worse.</strong> </u>Bad intelligence. As the U.S. has stumbled from one military mis-adventure to another over the last several decades, it has become clear that Washington isn’t very good at interpreting intelligence. Even when vital information is available, it gets filtered by preconceptions and bureaucratic processes so that the wrong conclusions are drawn. Similar problems exist in Moscow. For instance, the Cuban missile crisis of 1962 arose partly from Soviet leader Khrushchev’s assessment that President Kennedy was weaker than he turned out to be, and the U.S. Navy nearly provoked use of a nuclear torpedo by a Russian submarine during the blockade because it misjudged the enemy’s likely reaction to being threatened. <u><mark>It is easy to imagine</u></mark> similar <u><strong><mark>misjudgments</strong></mark> in Ukraine</u>, <u>which Washington and Moscow approach from very different perspectives</u>. <u>Any</u> sizable <u>deployment</u> of U.S. forces in the region <u>could provoke Russian escalation. </u>Defective signaling. When tensions are high, rival leaders often seek to send signals about their intentions as a way of shaping outcomes. But the meaning of such signals can easily be confused by the need of leaders to address multiple audiences at the same time, and by the different frames of reference each side is applying. Even the process of translation can change the apparent meaning of messages in subtle ways. So when Russian foreign minister Lavrov spoke this week (in English) about the possible need to come to the aid of ethnic Russians in eastern Ukraine, Washington had to guess whether he was stating the public rationale for an invasion, sending a warning signal to Kiev about its internal counter-terror campaign, or trying to accomplish some other purpose. <u><mark>Misinterpretation</mark> of </u>such<u> signals <mark>can become a reciprocal process that sends both sides <strong>up the “ladder of escalation” quickly</strong></mark>, to a point where nuclear use seems like the logical next step. </u>Looming defeat. If military confrontation between Russia and NATO gave way to conventional conflict, one side or the other would eventually face defeat. Russia has a distinct numerical advantage in the area around Ukraine, but its military consists mainly of conscripts and is poorly equipped compared with Western counterparts. <u>Whichever side found itself losing would have to weigh the drawbacks of losing against those of escalating to the use of tactical nuclear weapons</u>. Moscow would have to contemplate the possibility of a permanent enemy presence near its heartland, while Washington might face the collapse of NATO, its most important alliance. In such circumstances, the use of “only” one or two tactical nuclear warheads to avert an outcome with such far-reaching consequences might seem reasonable — especially given the existence of relevant capabilities and supportive doctrine on both sides. Command breakdown. Strategic nuclear weapons like intercontinental ballistic missiles are tightly controlled by senior military leaders in Russia and America, making their unauthorized or accidental use nearly impossible. That is less the case with nonstrategic nuclear weapons, which at some point in the course of an escalatory process need to be released to the control of local commanders if they are to have military utility. <u><mark>U.S. policy even envisions <strong>letting allies deliver tactical warheads</strong></mark> against enemy targets.</u> Moscow probably doesn’t trust its allies to that degree, but with more tactical nuclear weapons in more locations, there is a greater likelihood that local Russian commanders might have the latitude to initiate nuclear use in the chaos of battle. <u>Russian doctrine endorses nuclear-weapons use in response to conventional aggression threatening the homeland, and obstacles to local initiative often break down once hostilities commence. <mark>When you consider all the processes working to degrade restraint</mark> in wartime</u> <u><mark>— poor intel</mark>ligence, garbled communication, <mark>battlefield setbacks, command attenuation, and</mark> a host of <mark>other influences — it seems reasonable to consider</mark> that a military confrontation between NATO and Russia might in some manner escalate out of control, even to the point of using nuclear weapons.</u> And <u><mark>because Ukraine is so close</mark> to the Russian heartland</u> (about 250 miles from Moscow) <u><mark>there’s no telling what might happen <strong>once the nuclear “firebreak” is crossed</mark>. All this terminology — firebreaks, ladders of escalation, extended deterrence — was devised during the Cold War to deal with potential warfighting scenarios in Europe. So if there is a renewed possibility of tensions leading to war over Ukraine (or some other former Soviet possession), perhaps the time has come to revive such thinking.</p></u></strong>
null
null
CP
22,852
87
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,065
Countries will stay within the treaty regime now despite push for change
Bewley-Taylor et al 2014
Bewley-Taylor et al 2014 (Dave Bewley-Taylor, Tom Blickman and Martin Jelsma, Professor of International Relations and Public Policy at Swansea University and founding Director of the Global Drug Policy Observatory, The Rise and Decline of Cannabis Prohibition, http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/rise_and_decline_intro.pdf)
All these policy practices were interpreted by the implementing countries as respecting the confines of treaty latitude. Most have a solid legal basis, others employ a certain legal creativity The strictures of the conventions and the near impossibility to amend them have impelled some countries to stretching their inbuilt flexibility and escape clauses while a fundamental change in cannabis policy is increasingly viewed as a legitimate option to consider in various parts of the world reputational costs of treaty breach are likely to deter most states from moving beyond soft defection
The strictures of the conventions and the near impossibility to amend them have impelled some countries to stretching their inbuilt flexibility and escape clauses while a fundamental change in cannabis policy is increasingly viewed as a legitimate option reputational costs of treaty breach are likely to deter most states from moving beyond soft defection
All these policy practices were interpreted by the implementing countries as respecting the confines of treaty latitude. Most have a solid legal basis, others employ a certain legal creativity, not always acknowledged by the INCB. And sometimes schemes perfectly justifiable in principle have been applied with a “pragmatic” dose of hypocrisy. The strictures of the conventions and the near impossibility to amend them have impelled some countries to stretching their inbuilt flexibility and escape clauses to questionable limits. Examples are the legal contradictions around the backdoor of the Dutch coffeeshops; the expansion of medical marijuana schemes in some U.S. states into recreational use; and the establishment of large-scale commercial cannabis social clubs in Spain. Indeed, while a fundamental change in cannabis policy is increasingly viewed as a legitimate option to consider in various parts of the world, the reputational (and possibly economic) costs of treaty breach are likely to deter most states from moving beyond some form of soft defection.
1,067
<h4>Countries will stay within the treaty regime now despite push for change</h4><p><strong>Bewley-Taylor et al 2014</strong> (Dave Bewley-Taylor, Tom Blickman and Martin Jelsma, Professor of International Relations and Public Policy at Swansea University and founding Director of the Global Drug Policy Observatory, The Rise and Decline of Cannabis Prohibition, http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/rise_and_decline_intro.pdf)</p><p><u>All these policy practices were interpreted by the implementing countries as respecting the confines of treaty latitude. Most have a solid legal basis, others employ a certain legal creativity</u>, not always acknowledged by the INCB. And sometimes schemes perfectly justifiable in principle have been applied with a “pragmatic” dose of hypocrisy. <u><mark>The</mark> <mark>strictures of the conventions and the near impossibility to amend them have impelled some countries to stretching their inbuilt flexibility and escape clauses</u></mark> to questionable limits. Examples are the legal contradictions around the backdoor of the Dutch coffeeshops; the expansion of medical marijuana schemes in some U.S. states into recreational use; and the establishment of large-scale commercial cannabis social clubs in Spain. Indeed, <u><mark>while a fundamental change in cannabis policy is increasingly viewed as a legitimate option</mark> to consider in various parts of the world</u>, the <u><strong><mark>reputational</u></strong></mark> (and possibly economic) <u><strong><mark>costs of treaty breach are likely to deter most states from moving beyond</u></strong></mark> some form of <u><strong><mark>soft defection</u></strong></mark>.</p>
null
null
DA
430,419
39
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,066
Federal legalization violates the 1961 Single Convention
Rico 2014 )
Rico 2014 (Bernardo, international banker and Central America development specialist, INROADS OR DETOURS in the Drug Debate?, Americas Quarterly8.1 (Winter 2014): 40-45, proquest)
marijuana remains on the U.S. federal government's list of "controlled substances" as an illegal narcotic marijuana legalization violates UN drug treaties, primarily the 1961 Single Convention on Narcotic Drugs.
marijuana legalization violates UN drug treaties, primarily the 1961 Single Convention on Narcotic Drugs
It's important, first of all, to understand that neither of these options has anything to do with "legalization." Legalizing a drug removes the prohibition on its production, sale or consumption, albeit with government regulation. Uruguay is the only nation to have recently approved legislation to legalize marijuana, which will allow the government to control most of the stages from production to consumption. Colorado and Washington are the only U.S. states to have legalized the recreational use of marijuana; possession and sale for medical purposes is permitted in 20 other states. However, marijuana remains on the U.S. federal government's list of "controlled substances" as an illegal narcotic. Even though the U.S. Department of Justice has indicated it is reconsidering whether it will enforce federal penalties, marijuana legalization still violates UN drug treaties, primarily the 1961 Single Convention on Narcotic Drugs.
936
<h4>Federal legalization violates the 1961 Single Convention</h4><p><strong>Rico 2014</strong> (Bernardo, international banker and Central America development specialist, INROADS OR DETOURS in the Drug Debate?, Americas Quarterly8.1 (Winter 2014): 40-45, proquest<u><strong>)</p><p></u></strong>It's important, first of all, to understand that neither of these options has anything to do with "legalization." Legalizing a drug removes the prohibition on its production, sale or consumption, albeit with government regulation. Uruguay is the only nation to have recently approved legislation to legalize marijuana, which will allow the government to control most of the stages from production to consumption. Colorado and Washington are the only U.S. states to have legalized the recreational use of marijuana; possession and sale for medical purposes is permitted in 20 other states. However, <u>marijuana remains on the U.S. federal government's list of "controlled substances" as an illegal narcotic</u>. Even though the U.S. Department of Justice has indicated it is reconsidering whether it will enforce federal penalties, <u><mark>marijuana legalization</u></mark> still <u><strong><mark>violates UN drug treaties, primarily the 1961 Single Convention on Narcotic Drugs</strong></mark>.</p></u>
null
null
DA
430,420
24
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,067
CP keeps the treaty regime intact but the plan the destroys it
Bewley-Taylor et al 2014
Bewley-Taylor et al 2014 (Dave Bewley-Taylor, Tom Blickman and Martin Jelsma, Professor of International Relations and Public Policy at Swansea University and founding Director of the Global Drug Policy Observatory, The Rise and Decline of Cannabis Prohibition, http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/rise_and_decline_web.pdf)
The United States invested more effort than any other nation to influence the design of the global control regime If the U.S. now proclaims it can no longer live by the regime’s rules, it risks undermining the legal instrument Officials in Washington have been trying to develop a legal argument regarding enforcement priorities claiming that the U.S. is not violating the treaties because cultivation, trade and possession are still criminal offences under federal drug law and because the treaty provisions allow flexibility regarding law enforcement practices, especially when there are conflicts with a party’s constitution and domestic legal system. if, the U.S. interpretation attracted political acceptance and became part of an extended practice of flexible treaty interpretation significantly more room for manoeuvre would open up Other countries would be able to apply similar arguments Accepting such an argumentation would come close to a de facto amendment by means of broad interpretation If the U.S. now asserts that the treaties are sufficiently flexible to allow state control and taxed regulation the Netherlands could comfortably extend the expediency principle to include coffeeshops
The United States invested more than any other nation to influence the global control regime If the U.S. proclaims it can no longer live by the regime’s rules, it risks undermining the legal instrument Officials in Washington have been trying to develop a legal argument that the U.S. is not violating the treaties because cultivation, trade and possession are still criminal offences under federal drug law and because the treaty provisions allow flexibility regarding law enforcement practices when there are conflicts with a party’s constitution if, the U.S. interpretation attracted ceptance and became part of an extended practice of flexible treaty interpretation, significantly more room for manoeuvre would open up the Netherlands could comfortably extend the expediency principle to include coffeeshops
The United States has invested probably more effort than any other nation over the past century to influence the design of the global control regime and enforce its almost universal adherence. If the U.S. now proclaims it can no longer live by the regime’s rules, it risks undermining the legal instrument it has used so often in the past to coerce other countries to operate in accordance with U.S. drug control policies and principles. Officials in Washington have been trying to develop a legal argument, based on the August 2013 memorandum from the Justice Department regarding enforcement priorities, claiming that the U.S. is not violating the treaties because cultivation, trade and possession of cannabis are still criminal offences under federal drug law; and because the treaty provisions allow for considerable flexibility regarding law enforcement practices, especially when there are conflicts with a party’s constitution and domestic legal system. Using the expediency principle, the argument continues, federal law enforcement intervention in state-level cannabis regulation is simply not high priority; but by allowing states de facto to regulate the cannabis market, the federal government would not be violating its international treaty obligations because the approaches pursued in Washington and Colorado are still prohibited under federal law. In legal terms, such a line of argumentation is easily contestable. The INCB has pointed out in recent annual reports in reference to cannabis developments at state level in the U.S., a party is obliged “to ensure the full implementation of the international drug control treaties on its entire territory”. Hence law enforcement priority isn’t a valid consideration; rather the law needs to be in conformity with the treaties at all levels of jurisdiction. Any reference regarding treaty flexibility based on the premise that the manner in which a party implements the provisions is “subject to its constitutional principles and the basic concepts of its legal system” is also very problematic. While that principle applied to the 1961 Convention as a whole, the escape clause was deliberately deleted from the 1988 Convention with regard to the obligation to establish cultivation, trade and possession as a criminal offence, except in relation to personal consumption mainly due to U.S. pressure during the negotiations. Washington’s rationale was that it wanted to limit the flexibility the preceding conventions had left to nation states. And finally (as mentioned in the section on Dutch coffeeshops in the previous chapter), the 1988 Convention restricted the use of discretionary legal powers regarding cultivation and trafficking offences (article 3, paragraph 6). All that notwithstanding, if, the U.S. interpretation attracted a certain level of political acceptance and became part of an extended practice of flexible treaty interpretation, significantly more room for manoeuvre would open up. Other countries would be able to apply similar arguments, not only to legally justify cannabis regulation, but for other currently contested policies as well, such as drug consumption rooms or legally regulated markets for coca leaf. Accepting such an argumentation would come close to a de facto amendment by means of broad interpretation that would restore the escape clause for the entire 1988 Convention (including for article 3, paragraph 1 (a) and (b) offences), and simultaneously annul the restrictions placed on the exercise of discretionary powers under domestic law. The Netherlands, for example, made a special reservation upon ratification of the 1988 Convention, exempting the country from the limitations on prosecutorial discretion the treaty intended to impose. Even with such a reservation in hand, however, the Dutch government has maintained thus far that the expediency principle under which the coffeeshops are operating, could not be used to justify non-enforcement guidelines with regard to cannabis cultivation. That position has often been challenged in the domestic policy debate as an excessively restrictive legal interpretation of existing treaty flexibility. If the U.S. now asserts that the treaties are sufficiently flexible to allow state control and taxed regulation of cultivation and trade for non-medical purposes on its territory, accordingly the Netherlands could comfortably extend the expediency principle to include the cultivation of cannabis destined to supply the coffeeshops by issuing additional nonprosecution guidelines.
4,540
<h4>CP keeps the treaty regime intact but the plan the destroys it</h4><p><strong>Bewley-Taylor et al 2014</strong> (Dave Bewley-Taylor, Tom Blickman and Martin Jelsma, Professor of International Relations and Public Policy at Swansea University and founding Director of the Global Drug Policy Observatory, The Rise and Decline of Cannabis Prohibition, http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/rise_and_decline_web.pdf)</p><p><u><mark>The United States</u></mark> has <u><mark>invested</u></mark> probably <u><mark>more</mark> effort <mark>than any other nation</u></mark> over the past century <u><mark>to</u> <u>influence the</mark> design of the <mark>global control regime</u></mark> and enforce its almost universal adherence. <u><strong><mark>If the U.S.</mark> now <mark>proclaims it can no longer live by the regime’s rules, it risks undermining the legal instrument</u></strong></mark> it has used so often in the past to coerce other countries to operate in accordance with U.S. drug control policies and principles. <u><mark>Officials in Washington have been trying to develop a legal argument</u></mark>, based on the August 2013 memorandum from the Justice Department <u>regarding</u> <u><strong>enforcement priorities</u></strong>, <u>claiming <mark>that the U.S. is not violating the treaties</mark> <mark>because</mark> <mark>cultivation, trade and possession</u></mark> of cannabis <u><mark>are <strong>still criminal offences under federal drug law</u></strong></mark>; <u><mark>and</mark> <mark>because the treaty provisions allow</u></mark> for considerable <u><mark>flexibility regarding law enforcement practices</mark>, especially <mark>when there are conflicts with a party’s constitution</mark> and domestic legal system.</u> Using the expediency principle, the argument continues, federal law enforcement intervention in state-level cannabis regulation is simply not high priority; but by allowing states de facto to regulate the cannabis market, the federal government would not be violating its international treaty obligations because the approaches pursued in Washington and Colorado are still prohibited under federal law. In legal terms, such a line of argumentation is easily contestable. The INCB has pointed out in recent annual reports in reference to cannabis developments at state level in the U.S., a party is obliged “to ensure the full implementation of the international drug control treaties on its entire territory”. Hence law enforcement priority isn’t a valid consideration; rather the law needs to be in conformity with the treaties at all levels of jurisdiction. Any reference regarding treaty flexibility based on the premise that the manner in which a party implements the provisions is “subject to its constitutional principles and the basic concepts of its legal system” is also very problematic. While that principle applied to the 1961 Convention as a whole, the escape clause was deliberately deleted from the 1988 Convention with regard to the obligation to establish cultivation, trade and possession as a criminal offence, except in relation to personal consumption mainly due to U.S. pressure during the negotiations. Washington’s rationale was that it wanted to limit the flexibility the preceding conventions had left to nation states. And finally (as mentioned in the section on Dutch coffeeshops in the previous chapter), the 1988 Convention restricted the use of discretionary legal powers regarding cultivation and trafficking offences (article 3, paragraph 6). All that notwithstanding, <u><mark>if, the U.S. interpretation attracted</mark> </u>a certain level of <u>political ac<mark>ceptance</u> <u>and</u> <u>became part of an extended practice of flexible treaty interpretation</u>, <u><strong>significantly more room for manoeuvre would open up</u></strong></mark>. <u>Other countries would be able to apply similar arguments</u>, not only to legally justify cannabis regulation, but for other currently contested policies as well, such as drug consumption rooms or legally regulated markets for coca leaf. <u>Accepting such an argumentation would come close to a <strong>de facto amendment</strong> by means of broad interpretation</u> that would restore the escape clause for the entire 1988 Convention (including for article 3, paragraph 1 (a) and (b) offences), and simultaneously annul the restrictions placed on the exercise of discretionary powers under domestic law. The Netherlands, for example, made a special reservation upon ratification of the 1988 Convention, exempting the country from the limitations on prosecutorial discretion the treaty intended to impose. Even with such a reservation in hand, however, the Dutch government has maintained thus far that the expediency principle under which the coffeeshops are operating, could not be used to justify non-enforcement guidelines with regard to cannabis cultivation. That position has often been challenged in the domestic policy debate as an excessively restrictive legal interpretation of existing treaty flexibility. <u>If the U.S. now asserts that the treaties are sufficiently flexible to allow state control and taxed regulation</u> of cultivation and trade for non-medical purposes on its territory, accordingly <u><mark>the Netherlands could comfortably extend the expediency principle to include</u></mark> the cultivation of cannabis destined to supply the <u><mark>coffeeshops</u></mark> by issuing additional nonprosecution guidelines.</p>
null
null
DA
430,422
43
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,068
Disregarding drug control treaties spills over- destroys international law
Bewley-Taylor 2003
Bewley-Taylor 2003 (David, Department of American Studies, Vnireraty of Wales Swansea Challenging the UN drug control conventions: problems and Possibilities International Journal of Drug Policy 14 (2003) 171/179, http://www.unawestminster.org.uk/pdf/drugs/UNdrugsBewley_Taylor_IJDP14.pdf)
Another strategy would be for Parties to simply ignore the treaties they could institute any policies deemed to be necessary including legalisation of cannabis Disregarding the treaties raises serious issues beyond the realm of drug control The possibility of nations unilaterally ignoring drug control treaty commitments could threaten the stability of the entire treaty system selective application would call into question the validity of many and varied conventions.
Disregarding the treaties raises serious issues nations unilaterally ignoring drug control treaty commitments could threaten the stability of the entire treaty system selective application would call into question the validity of many and varied conventions.
Another strategy would be for Parties to simply ignore the treaties or certain parts of them. In this way they could institute any policies deemed to be necessary at the national level, including for example the legalisation of cannabis and the introduction of a licensing system for domestic producers. This option has been gaining support amongst many opponents of the prohibition based international system for some time. Disregarding all or selected components of the treaties, however, raises serious issues beyond the realm of drug control. The possibility of nations unilaterally ignoring drug control treaty commitments could threaten the stability of the entire treaty system. As a consequence states may be wary of opting out. Some international lawyers argue that all treaties can naturally cease to be binding when a fundamental change of circumstances has occurred since the time of signing (Starke, 1989, pp. 473/474). Bearing in mind the dramatic changes in the nature and extent of the drug problem since the 1960s, this doctrine of rebus sic stantibus could probably be applied to the drug treaties. Yet the selective application of such a principle would call into question the validity of many and varied conventions.
1,236
<h4>Disregarding drug control treaties spills over- destroys international law</h4><p><strong>Bewley-Taylor 2003</strong> (David, Department of American Studies, Vnireraty<u> of Wales Swansea Challenging the UN drug control conventions: problems and Possibilities International Journal of Drug Policy 14 (2003) 171/179, http://www.unawestminster.org.uk/pdf/drugs/UNdrugsBewley_Taylor_IJDP14.pdf)</p><p>Another strategy would be for Parties to simply ignore the treaties</u> or certain parts of them. In this way <u>they could institute any policies deemed to be necessary</u> at the national level, <u>including</u> for example the <u>legalisation of cannabis</u> and the introduction of a licensing system for domestic producers. This option has been gaining support amongst many opponents of the prohibition based international system for some time. <u><mark>Disregarding</u></mark> all or selected components of <u><mark>the treaties</u></mark>, however, <u><mark>raises serious issues</mark> beyond the realm of drug control</u>. <u>The possibility of <mark>nations unilaterally ignoring drug control treaty commitments could <strong>threaten the stability of the entire treaty system</u></strong></mark>. As a consequence states may be wary of opting out. Some international lawyers argue that all treaties can naturally cease to be binding when a fundamental change of circumstances has occurred since the time of signing (Starke, 1989, pp. 473/474). Bearing in mind the dramatic changes in the nature and extent of the drug problem since the 1960s, this doctrine of rebus sic stantibus could probably be applied to the drug treaties. Yet the <u><mark>selective application</u></mark> of such a principle <u><mark>would <strong>call into question the validity of many and varied conventions</strong>.</p></u></mark>
null
null
DA
193,806
47
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,069
International treaty system solves great power war
Muller 2000
Muller 2000 (Dr. Harold Muller is the Director of the Peace Research Institute-Frankfurt and Professor of International Relations at Goethe University Compliance Politics: A Critical Analysis of Multilateral Arms Control Treaty Enforcement http://cns.miis.edu/npr/pdfs/72muell.pdf)
As long as the risk of great power rivalry and competition exists constructing barriers against a degeneration of this competition into major violence remains a pivotal task Things may be more complicated than during the bipolar age arms races are likely stabilization remains a key a web of interlocking agreements may even create enough of a sense of security and confidence to overcome past confrontations and enable transitions towards more cooperative relationships. arms limitation agreement are needed to ban existential dangers for global stability, ecological safety, and maybe the very survival of human life on earth Global agreements also reduce the chances that regional conflicts will escalate the normative frameworks that they enshrine may engender a feeling of community and shared security interests that help reduce the general level of conflict and assist in ushering in new relations of global cooperation it will serve these worthwhile purposes only if means are available to ensure compliance
as the risk of great power rivalry and competition exists constructing barriers against major violence remains a pivotal task arms races are likely interlocking agreements create enough of a sense of security and confidence to overcome confrontations and enable transitions towards cooperative relationships arms limitation agreements are needed to ban existential dangers ecological safety, and the survival of human life Global agreements reduce the chances that conflicts will escalate. , it will serve these worthwhile purposes only if means are available to ensure compliance
In this author's view,3 at least four distinct missions continue to make arms control, disarmament, and non-proliferation agreements useful, even indispensable parts of a stable and reliable world security structure: • As long as the risk of great power rivalry and competition exists—and it exists today—constructing barriers against a degeneration of this competition into major violence remains a pivotal task of global security policy. Things may be more complicated than during the bipolar age since asymmetries loom larger and more than one pair of competing major powers may exist. With overlapping rivalries among these powers, arms races are likely to be interconnected, and the stability of any one pair of rivals might be affected negatively by developments in other dyads. Because of this greater risk of instability, the increased political complexity of the post-bipolar world calls for more rather than less arms control. For these competitive relationships, stability or stabilization remains a key goal, and effectively verified agreements can contribute much to establish such stability. • Arms control also has a role to play in securing regional stability. At the regional level, arms control agreements can create balances of forces that reassure regional powers that their basic security is certain, and help build confidence in the basically non-aggressive policies of neighbors. Over time, a web of interlocking agreements may even create enough of a sense of security and confidence to overcome past confrontations and enable transitions towards more cooperative relationships. At the global level, arms limitation or prohibition agreements, notably in the field of weapons of mass destruction, are needed to ban existential dangers for global stability, ecological safety, and maybe the very survival of human life on earth. In an age of increasing interdependence and ensuing complex networks that support the satisfaction of basic needs, international cooperation is needed to secure the smooth working of these networks. Arms control can create underlying conditions of security and stability that reduce distrust and enable countries to commit them-selves to far-reaching cooperation in other sectors without perceiving undesirable risks to their national security. Global agreements also affect regional balances and help, if successful, to reduce the chances that regional conflicts will escalate. Under opportune circumstances, the normative frameworks that they enshrine may engender a feeling of community and shared security interests that help reduce the general level of conflict and assist in ushering in new relations of global cooperation. • Finally, one aspect that is rarely discussed in the arms control context is arms control among friends and partners. It takes the innocent form of military cooperation; joint staffs, commands, and units; common procurement planning; and broad and far-reaching transparency. While these relations serve at the surface to enhance a country's military capability by linking it with others, they are conducive as well to creating a sense of irreversibility in current friendly relations, by making unthinkable a return to previous, possibly more conflictual times. European defense cooperation is a case in point.1 Whatever the particular mission of a specific agreement, it will serve these worthwhile purposes only if it is implemented appropriately and, if not, means are available to ensure compliance. In other words, the enduring value of arms control rests very much on the ability to assure compliance.5 Despite the reasons given above for the continuing utility of arms control, the skeptics may still have the last word if agreements are made empty shells by repeated breaches and a lack of effective enforcement.
3,802
<h4>International treaty system solves great power war</h4><p><strong>Muller 2000 </strong>(Dr. Harold Muller is the Director of the Peace Research Institute-Frankfurt and Professor of International Relations at Goethe University Compliance Politics: A Critical Analysis of Multilateral Arms Control Treaty Enforcement http://cns.miis.edu/npr/pdfs/72muell.pdf)</p><p>In this author's view,3 at least four distinct missions continue to make arms control, disarmament, and non-proliferation agreements useful, even indispensable parts of a stable and reliable world security structure: • <u>As long <mark>as the risk of <strong>great power rivalry</strong> and <strong>competition</strong> exists</u></mark>—and it exists today—<u><mark>constructing barriers</mark> <mark>against</mark> a degeneration of this competition into <strong><mark>major violence</strong> remains a pivotal task</u></mark> of global security policy. <u>Things may be more complicated than during the bipolar age</u> since asymmetries loom larger and more than one pair of competing major powers may exist. With overlapping rivalries among these powers, <u><mark>arms races are <strong>likely</u></strong></mark> to be interconnected, and the stability of any one pair of rivals might be affected negatively by developments in other dyads. Because of this greater risk of instability, the increased political complexity of the post-bipolar world calls for more rather than less arms control. For these competitive relationships, stability or <u>stabilization remains a key</u> goal, and effectively verified agreements can contribute much to establish such stability. • Arms control also has a role to play in securing regional stability. At the regional level, arms control agreements can create balances of forces that reassure regional powers that their basic security is certain, and help build confidence in the basically non-aggressive policies of neighbors. Over time, <u>a web of <strong><mark>interlocking agreements</strong></mark> may even <mark>create enough of a sense of <strong>security</strong> and <strong>confidence</strong> to overcome</mark> past <mark>confrontations and enable transitions towards</mark> more <mark>cooperative relationships</mark>.</u> At the global level, <u><mark>arms limitation</u></mark> or prohibition <u><mark>agreement</u>s</mark>, notably in the field of weapons of mass destruction, <u><mark>are needed to ban <strong>existential dangers</strong></mark> for global stability, <strong><mark>ecological</strong> safety, and</mark> maybe <strong><mark>the</mark> very <mark>survival of human life</mark> on earth</u></strong>. In an age of increasing interdependence and ensuing complex networks that support the satisfaction of basic needs, international cooperation is needed to secure the smooth working of these networks. Arms control can create underlying conditions of security and stability that reduce distrust and enable countries to commit them-selves to far-reaching cooperation in other sectors without perceiving undesirable risks to their national security. <u><mark>Global agreements</mark> also</u> affect regional balances and help, if successful, to <u><strong><mark>reduce the chances</strong> that</mark> regional <mark>conflicts will escalate</u>.</mark> Under opportune circumstances, <u>the normative frameworks that they enshrine may engender a feeling of community and shared security interests that help reduce the general level of conflict and assist in ushering in new relations of global cooperation</u>. • Finally, one aspect that is rarely discussed in the arms control context is arms control among friends and partners. It takes the innocent form of military cooperation; joint staffs, commands, and units; common procurement planning; and broad and far-reaching transparency. While these relations serve at the surface to enhance a country's military capability by linking it with others, they are conducive as well to creating a sense of irreversibility in current friendly relations, by making unthinkable a return to previous, possibly more conflictual times. European defense cooperation is a case in point.1 Whatever the particular mission of a specific agreement<mark>, <u>it will serve these worthwhile purposes <strong>only if</u></strong></mark> it is implemented appropriately and, if not, <u><mark>means are available to ensure <strong>compliance</u></strong></mark>. In other words, the enduring value of arms control rests very much on the ability to assure compliance.5 Despite the reasons given above for the continuing utility of arms control, the skeptics may still have the last word if agreements are made empty shells by repeated breaches and a lack of effective enforcement.</p>
null
null
DA
65,123
59
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,070
Worst climate impacts take decades to arrive and don’t assume adaptation
Mendelsohn 9
Robert O. Mendelsohn 9, the Edwin Weyerhaeuser Davis Professor, Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, Yale University, June 2009, “Climate Change and Economic Growth,” online: http://www.growthcommission.org/storage/cgdev/documents/gcwp060web.pdf
Proponents argue that there is no time to waste ). These statements are largely alarmist and misleading society’s immediate behavior has an extremely low probability of leading to catastrophic conse- quences. emissions over the next few decades will lead to only mild consequences severe impacts predicted by alarmists require a century (or two of no mitigation acts assume that there will be no or little adaptation. Most of the more severe impacts will take more than a century or millennium and many of these will never occur because people will adapt. It is not at all apparent that immediate and dramatic policies need to be develope
that there is no time to wast are largely alarmist and misleading immediate behavior has an extremely low probability of leading to catastrophic conse- quences emissions over decades will lead to only mild consequences severe impacts require a century (or two no mitigation impacts assume no adaptation severe impacts will take more than a century or millennium and will never occur because people adapt
The heart of the debate about climate change comes from numerous warnings from scientists and others that give the impression that human- induced climate change is an immediate threat to society (IPCC 2007a, 2007c; Stern 2006). Millions of people might be vulnerable to health effects (IPCC 2007a), crop production might fall in the low latitudes (IPCC 2007a), water supplies might dwindle (IPCC 2007a), precipitation might fall in arid regions (IPCC 2007a), extreme events will grow exponentially (Stern 2006), and between 20 and 30 percent of species will risk extinction (IPCC 2007a). Even worse, there may be catastrophic events such as the melting of Greenland or Antarctic ice sheets, causing severe sea-level rise, which would inundate hundreds of millions of people (Dasgupta and others 2009). Proponents argue that there is no time to waste. Unless greenhouse gases are cut dramatically today, economic growth and well-being may be at risk (Stern 2006). These statements are largely alarmist and misleading. Although climate change is a serious problem that deserves attention, society’s immediate behavior has an extremely low probability of leading to catastrophic conse- quences. The science and economics of climate change are quite clear that emissions over the next few decades will lead to only mild consequences. The severe impacts predicted by alarmists require a century (or two, accord- ing to Stern 2006) of no mitigation. Many of the predicted impacts assume that there will be no or little adaptation. The net economic impacts from climate change over the next 50 years will be small regardless. Most of the more severe impacts will take more than a century or even a millennium to unfold, and many of these “potential” impacts will never occur because people will adapt. It is not at all apparent that immediate and dramatic policies need to be developed to thwart long-range climate risks. What is needed are long-run balanced responses.
1,962
<h4>Worst climate impacts take decades to arrive and don’t assume adaptation</h4><p>Robert O. <strong>Mendelsohn 9</strong>, the Edwin Weyerhaeuser Davis Professor, Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, Yale University, June 2009, “Climate Change and Economic Growth,” online: http://www.growthcommission.org/storage/cgdev/documents/gcwp060web.pdf</p><p>The heart of the debate about climate change comes from numerous warnings from scientists and others that give the impression that human- induced climate change is an immediate threat to society (IPCC 2007a, 2007c; Stern 2006). Millions of people might be vulnerable to health effects (IPCC 2007a), crop production might fall in the low latitudes (IPCC 2007a), water supplies might dwindle (IPCC 2007a), precipitation might fall in arid regions (IPCC 2007a), extreme events will grow exponentially (Stern 2006), and between 20 and 30 percent of species will risk extinction (IPCC 2007a). Even worse, there may be catastrophic events such as the melting of Greenland or Antarctic ice sheets, causing severe sea-level rise, which would inundate hundreds of millions of people (Dasgupta and others 2009). <u>Proponents argue <mark>that there is no time to wast</mark>e</u>. Unless greenhouse gases are cut dramatically today, economic growth and well-being may be at risk (Stern 2006<u>). These statements <mark>are largely alarmist and misleading</u></mark>. Although climate change is a serious problem that deserves attention, <u>society’s <mark>immediate behavior has an</u> <u><strong>extremely low probability</u></strong> <u>of leading to</mark> <mark>catastrophic conse- quences</mark>.</u> The science and economics of climate change are quite clear that <u><mark>emissions over</mark> the next few <mark>decades will lead to only mild consequences</u></mark>. The <u><mark>severe impacts</mark> predicted by alarmists <mark>require</u> <u><strong>a century (or two</u></strong></mark>, accord- ing to Stern 2006) <u>of <mark>no mitigation</u></mark>. Many of the predicted <mark>imp<u>acts assume</mark> that there will be <mark>no</mark> or little <mark>adaptation</mark>. </u>The net economic impacts from climate change over the next 50 years will be small regardless. <u>Most of the more <mark>severe impacts will take more than a century or</u></mark> even a <u><mark>millennium</u></mark> to unfold, <u><mark>and</mark> many of these</u> “potential” impacts <u><mark>will never occur because people</mark> will <mark>adapt</mark>. It is not at all apparent that immediate and dramatic policies need to be develope</u>d to thwart long-range climate risks. What is needed are long-run balanced responses.</p>
null
null
Environment
45,412
381
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,071
Either indoors is more cost-efficient and they can’t solve because they can’t make it illegal or it’s more cost-effective to cultivate outside and the squo solves
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Either indoors is more cost-efficient and they can’t solve because they can’t make it illegal or it’s more cost-effective to cultivate outside and the squo solves</h4>
null
null
Environment
430,558
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,072
Torts will wreck legal marijuana
Walters 2014
Walters 2014 (John, Chief Operating Officer of the Hudson Institute, “First Legalization, Then Lawsuits: Can Marijuana Retailers Survive the Tort Bar?” 5/26, http://www.hudson.org/research/10293-first-legalization-then-lawsuits-can-marijuana-retailers-survive-the-tort-bar-)
Legal or illegal, marijuana injures users and those who distribute it for profit are liable for its known effects America’s tort attorneys could respond by suing drug retailers for the harm done by their product to particular addicts, This approach would not depend on federal, state, or local government policy. It would require only a victim and a sympathetic jury If you think trial lawyers made a windfall on tobacco, just wait until they get a handle on marijuana. No warning label in the world could shield marijuana growers and sellers from the tsunami of tort liability
Legal or illegal, marijuana injures users and those who distribute it are liable tort attorneys could respond by suing drug retailers This would not depend on federal, state, or local government policy If you think trial lawyers made a windfall on tobacco, just wait until they get a handle on marijuana No warning label in the world could shield marijuana growers and sellers from the tsunami of tort liability
With the open sale of formerly illegal drugs, the number of users will grow. Some advocates expect legalization to destroy criminal markets by providing cheaper drugs, which should also boost total sales. If the legal market does not produce discounts, however, the black market will continue to operate in parallel with the new higher-end market—a kind of “fast-food” network persisting alongside the new “gourmet” outlets. Either way, the result is increased use and increased profits. But communities are not helpless before this onslaught. Even when the criminal law has been compromised at the state level, a resort to civil procedure may offer protection. Legal or illegal, marijuana injures users—researchers call it a “neurotoxin”—and those who distribute it for profit are liable for its known effects. Its production and distribution, after all are still Federal crimes. America’s tort attorneys could respond by suing drug retailers for the harm done by their product to particular addicts, then collecting damages for the clients and legal fees for themselves. This approach would not depend on the president or federal, state, or local government policy. It would require only a victim, a drug trafficker, a capable lawyer, and a sympathetic jury. Some law firms could afford to take such cases as a pro bono service to families. They already see for themselves that growing drug addiction makes their communities unattractive to legitimate businesses. Philanthropies concerned about the disadvantaged could also push this initiative forward. Some clever attorneys might partner directly with treatment providers for referrals. Others might advertise on billboards, busses, television and radio. They will find that YouTube and sites on the Internet are a vast repository of self-incrimination. In addition, the retailers of marijuana as medicine—whether for smoking or eating baked goods, candy, and ice cream—should be easy targets of legal action. There is scant evidence of legitimate medical efficacy and much evidence that “medical marijuana” is a calculated fraud producing large profits. Far from approving it, the FDA has in fact written a letter denying smoked marijuana is medicine. If you think trial lawyers made a windfall on tobacco, just wait until they get a handle on marijuana. The scientific and medical evidence against marijuana now dwarfs what we knew about tobacco at the time of the surgeon general’s report of 1964. No warning label in the world could shield marijuana growers and sellers from the tsunami of tort liability they should face from distributing a product with so many known harmful effects.
2,643
<h4>Torts will wreck legal marijuana</h4><p><strong>Walters 2014 </strong>(John, Chief Operating Officer of the Hudson Institute, “First Legalization, Then Lawsuits: Can Marijuana Retailers Survive the Tort Bar?” 5/26, http://www.hudson.org/research/10293-first-legalization-then-lawsuits-can-marijuana-retailers-survive-the-tort-bar-)</p><p>With the open sale of formerly illegal drugs, the number of users will grow. Some advocates expect legalization to destroy criminal markets by providing cheaper drugs, which should also boost total sales. If the legal market does not produce discounts, however, the black market will continue to operate in parallel with the new higher-end market—a kind of “fast-food” network persisting alongside the new “gourmet” outlets. Either way, the result is increased use and increased profits. But communities are not helpless before this onslaught. Even when the criminal law has been compromised at the state level, a resort to civil procedure may offer protection. <u><strong><mark>Legal or illegal,</strong> marijuana injures users</u></mark>—researchers call it a “neurotoxin”—<u><mark>and those who distribute it</mark> for profit <mark>are liable</mark> for its known effects</u>. Its production and distribution, after all are still Federal crimes. <u>America’s <mark>tort attorneys could respond by suing drug retailers</mark> for the harm done by their product to particular addicts,</u> then collecting damages for the clients and legal fees for themselves. <u><mark>This</mark> approach <mark>would not depend on</u></mark> the president or <u><mark>federal, state, or local government policy</mark>. It would require only a victim</u>, a drug trafficker, a capable lawyer, <u>and a sympathetic jury</u>. Some law firms could afford to take such cases as a pro bono service to families. They already see for themselves that growing drug addiction makes their communities unattractive to legitimate businesses. Philanthropies concerned about the disadvantaged could also push this initiative forward. Some clever attorneys might partner directly with treatment providers for referrals. Others might advertise on billboards, busses, television and radio. They will find that YouTube and sites on the Internet are a vast repository of self-incrimination. In addition, the retailers of marijuana as medicine—whether for smoking or eating baked goods, candy, and ice cream—should be easy targets of legal action. There is scant evidence of legitimate medical efficacy and much evidence that “medical marijuana” is a calculated fraud producing large profits. Far from approving it, the FDA has in fact written a letter denying smoked marijuana is medicine. <u><mark>If you think trial lawyers made a windfall on tobacco, just wait until they get a handle on marijuana</mark>. </u>The scientific and medical evidence against marijuana now dwarfs what we knew about tobacco at the time of the surgeon general’s report of 1964. <u><mark>No warning label in the world could shield marijuana growers and sellers from the <strong>tsunami of tort liability</u></strong></mark> they should face from distributing a product with so many known harmful effects.</p>
null
null
Environment
430,559
9
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,073
Indoor model won’t spill over
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Indoor model won’t spill over</h4>
null
null
Environment
430,560
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,074
No modeling – states lack infrastructural capacity
Levi 11
Levi 11 [Michael A. Levi David M. Rubenstein Senior Fellow for Energy and the Environment Why Don’t States Cooperate More on Energy and Climate? Posted on Tuesday, January 18, 2011 http://blogs.cfr.org/levi/2011/01/18/why-dont-states-cooperate-more-on-energy-and-climate/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed%3A+mlevi+%28Michael+Levi%27s+Blog%29&utm_content=Google+Reader]
states’ capacity to cooperate when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity cooperation will fail. India won’t be able to force power plants to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation under control without stronger capacity to enforce laws China won’t improve its IPR protection until its innovation system becomes much more capable of developing tech Our view of international politics tends to focus much more on pure ambition than on these sorts of
India won’t be able to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation under control without stronger capacity to enforce laws China won’t improve IPR protection until its more capable of developing tech Our view of international politics tends to focus more on ambition than these
I spent Friday and Saturday at an excellent (largely academic) workshop on international institutions and global governance. In our discussions about why states do and don’t cooperate, I was struck by how absent states’ capacity to cooperate was from the discussion. In particular, when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how both practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. Here’s a simple example of what I’m referring to: People argue that international oil markets would function more smoothly if states would publish basic data on their domestic markets (supply, demand, stocks, etc). They observe that China (among others) doesn’t do that. The immediate conclusion is that Beijing doesn’t want to. The only policy recourse, then, is to pressure or persuade China to change tack. But in more than one recent conversation, people have emphasized to me that Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics itself (though it’s working on developing its capacity). Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity to collect the right statistics, cooperation will fail. The same thing is true much more broadly. India, for example, won’t be able to force power plants to internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation properly under control without stronger capacity to enforce the laws that it puts on the books. One might even argue that China won’t improve its IPR protection until its innovation system becomes much more capable of developing technologies itself. Our view of international politics, though, tends to focus much more on pure ambition than on these sorts of features that directly influence results.
1,750
<h4>No modeling – states lack infrastructural capacity</h4><p><u><strong>Levi 11</strong><mark> [Michael A. Levi David M. Rubenstein Senior Fellow for Energy and the Environment Why Don’t States Cooperate More on Energy and Climate? Posted on Tuesday, January 18, 2011 http://blogs.cfr.org/levi/2011/01/18/why-dont-states-cooperate-more-on-energy-and-climate/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed%3A+mlevi+%28Michael+Levi%27s+Blog%29&utm_content=Google+Reader]</p><p></u></mark>I spent Friday and Saturday at an excellent (largely academic) workshop on international institutions and global governance. In our discussions about why states do and don’t cooperate, I was struck by how absent <u>states’ capacity to cooperate</u> was from the discussion. In particular, <u>when it comes to energy and climate, it’s one of the bigger blind spots in how</u> both <u>practitioners and scholars think about cooperation. </u> Here’s a simple example of what I’m referring to: People argue that international oil markets would function more smoothly if states would publish basic data on their domestic markets (supply, demand, stocks, etc). They observe that China (among others) doesn’t do that. The immediate conclusion is that Beijing doesn’t want to. The only policy recourse, then, is to pressure or persuade China to change tack. But in more than one recent conversation, people have emphasized to me that <u>Beijing doesn’t have many of the needed statistics</u> itself (though it’s working on developing its capacity). <u>Badgering them won’t change that; until they develop the capacity</u> to collect the right statistics, <u>cooperation will fail.</u> The same thing is true much more broadly. <u><mark>India</u></mark>, for example, <u><mark>won’t be able to </mark>force power plants to<mark> internalize pollution costs until it develops a serious environmental regulator. Brazil won’t get deforestation</u></mark> properly <u><mark>under control without stronger capacity to enforce</u></mark> the <u><mark>laws</u></mark> that it puts on the books. One might even argue that <u><mark>China won’t improve</mark> its <mark>IPR protection until its</mark> innovation system becomes much <mark>more capable of developing tech</u></mark>nologies itself. <u><mark>Our view of international politics</u></mark>, though, <u><mark>tends to focus </mark>much<mark> more on </mark>pure<mark> ambition than </mark>on<mark> these </mark>sorts of</u><strong> features that directly influence results.</p></strong>
null
null
Environment
430,283
4
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,075
Other countries
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4><strong>Other countries</h4></strong>
null
null
Environment
430,561
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,076
Impact to acidification Overstated
Carter 11
Carter 11, Robert, PhD, Adjuct Research Fellow, James Cook University, Craig Idso, PhD, Chairman at the Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Fred Singer, PhD, President of the Science and Environmental Policy Project, Susan Crockford, evolutionary biologist with a specialty in skeletal taxonomy , paleozoology and vertebrate evolution, Joseph D’Aleo, 30 years of experience in professional meteorology, former college professor of Meteorology at Lyndon State College, Indur Goklany, independent scholar, author, and co-editor of the Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development, Sherwood Idso, President of the Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Research Physicist with the US Department of Agriculture, Adjunct Professor in the Departments of Geology, Botany, and Microbiology at Arizona State University, Bachelor of Physics, Master of Science, and Doctor of Philosophy, all from the University of Minnesota, Madhav Khandekar, former research scientist from Environment Canada and is an expert reviewer for the IPCC 2007 Climate Change Panel, Anthony Lupo, Department Chair and Professor of Atmospheric Science at the University of Missouri, Willie Soon, astrophysicist at the Solar and Stellar Physics Division of the Harvard-Smithsonian Center for Astrophysics, Mitch Taylor (Canada) [“Climate Change Reconsidered 2011 Interim Report,” September, Science and Environmental Policy Project, Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Published by The Heartland Institute]
Rodolfo-Metalpa worked with bryozoans or ―moss animals the first coastal transplant experiment designed to investigate the effects of naturally acidified seawater on the rates of net calcification and dissolution of the branched calcitic Aquatic Life They did this by transplanting colonies of the species to normal (pH 8.1), high (pH 7.66), and extremely high (pH 7.43) CO2 conditions at gas vents where they calculated the net calcification rates of live colonies and the dissolution rates of dead colonies by weighing them before and after 45 days Throughout the first and cooler observation period, ―dead M. truncata colonies dissolved at high CO2 levels live specimens maintained the same net calcification rate as those growing at normal pH At the extremely high CO2 level life continued calcification ceased in both the normal and high CO2 treatments,and in the extremely high CO2 treatment, the transplants died M. truncata are able to up-regulate their calcification rates and survive in areas with higher levels of pCO2 than are predicted to occur due to anthropogenic ocean acidification
the first coastal transplant experiment designed to investigate the effects of naturally acidified seawater on the rates of net calcification and dissolution of the branched calcitic Aquatic Life live specimens maintained the same net calcification rate as those growing at normal pH At high CO2 level life continued M. truncata are able to up-regulate their calcification rates and survive in areas with higher levels of pCO2 than are predicted to occur due to anthropogenic ocean acidification
Lastly, Rodolfo-Metalpa et al. (2010) worked with bryozoans or ―moss animals‖—a geologically important group of small animals that resemble corals and are major calcifiers, found on rocky shores in cool-water areas of the planet, where they comprise a significant component of the carbonate sediments in shallow sublittoral habitats, and where they form long-lived, three-dimensional structures that provide attachment sites for numerous epifauna and trap sediment and food for a variety of infauna—in what they describe as ―the first coastal transplant experiment designed to investigate the effects of naturally acidified seawater on the rates of net calcification and dissolution of the branched calcitic Aquatic Life 347 bryozoan Myriapora truncata.‖ They did this by transplanting colonies of the species to normal (pH 8.1), high (pH 7.66), and extremely high (pH 7.43) CO2 conditions at gas vents located just off Italy‘s Ischia Island in the Tyrrhenian Sea, where they calculated the net calcification rates of live colonies and the dissolution rates of dead colonies by weighing them before and after 45 days of in situ residence in May–June (when seawater temperatures ranged from 19 to 24°C) and after 128 days of in situ residence in July–October (when seawater temperatures ranged from 25–28°C). Throughout the first and cooler observation period, ―dead M. truncata colonies dissolved at high CO2 levels (pH 7.66), whereas live specimens maintained the same net calcification rate as those growing at normal pH,‖ the researchers write. At the extremely high CO2 level, however, the net calcification rate of the live specimens was reduced to only about 20 percent of what it was at normal pH, but life continued. Throughout the second and warmer observation period, on the other hand, calcification ceased in both the normal and high CO2 treatments,and in the extremely high CO2 treatment, the transplants died. Based on these findings the five scientists concluded, ―at moderate temperatures,‖ such as those to which they are currently adapted, ―adult M. truncata are able to up-regulate their calcification rates and survive in areas with higher levels of pCO2 than are predicted to occur due to anthropogenic ocean acidification, although this ability broke down below mean pH 7.4.‖ This latter level, however, is below what even the IPCC predicts will occur in response to continued burning of fossil fuels, and far below what the more realistic analysis of Tans (2009) suggests.
2,495
<h4><strong>Impact to acidification Overstated </h4><p>Carter 11</strong>, Robert, PhD, Adjuct Research Fellow, James Cook University, Craig Idso, PhD, Chairman at the Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Fred Singer, PhD, President of the Science and Environmental Policy Project, Susan Crockford, evolutionary biologist with a specialty in skeletal taxonomy , paleozoology and vertebrate evolution, Joseph D’Aleo, 30 years of experience in professional meteorology, former college professor of Meteorology at Lyndon State College, Indur Goklany, independent scholar, author, and co-editor of the Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development, Sherwood Idso, President of the Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Research Physicist with the US Department of Agriculture, Adjunct Professor in the Departments of Geology, Botany, and Microbiology at Arizona State University, Bachelor of Physics, Master of Science, and Doctor of Philosophy, all from the University of Minnesota, Madhav Khandekar, former research scientist from Environment Canada and is an expert reviewer for the IPCC 2007 Climate Change Panel, Anthony Lupo, Department Chair and Professor of Atmospheric Science at the University of Missouri, Willie Soon, astrophysicist at the Solar and Stellar Physics Division of the Harvard-Smithsonian Center for Astrophysics, Mitch Taylor (Canada) [“Climate Change Reconsidered 2011 Interim Report,” September, Science and Environmental Policy Project, Center for the Study of Carbon Dioxide and Global Change, Published by The Heartland Institute]</p><p>Lastly, <u>Rodolfo-Metalpa</u> et al. (2010) <u>worked with bryozoans or ―moss animals</u>‖—a geologically important group of small animals that resemble corals and are major calcifiers, found on rocky shores in cool-water areas of the planet, where they comprise a significant component of the carbonate sediments in shallow sublittoral habitats, and where they form long-lived, three-dimensional structures that provide attachment sites for numerous epifauna and trap sediment and food for a variety of infauna—in what they describe as ―<u><mark>the first coastal transplant experiment designed to investigate the effects of naturally acidified seawater on the rates of net calcification and dissolution of the branched calcitic Aquatic Life</u></mark> 347 bryozoan Myriapora truncata.‖ <u>They did this by transplanting colonies of the species to normal (pH 8.1), high (pH 7.66), and extremely high (pH 7.43) CO2 conditions at gas vents </u>located just off Italy‘s Ischia Island in the Tyrrhenian Sea, <u>where they calculated the net calcification rates of live colonies and the dissolution rates of dead colonies by weighing them before and after 45 days</u> of in situ residence in May–June (when seawater temperatures ranged from 19 to 24°C) and after 128 days of in situ residence in July–October (when seawater temperatures ranged from 25–28°C). <u>Throughout the first and cooler observation period, ―dead M. truncata colonies dissolved at high CO2 levels </u>(pH 7.66), whereas <u><mark>live specimens maintained the same net calcification rate as those growing at normal pH</u></mark>,‖ the researchers write. <u><mark>At</mark> the extremely <mark>high CO2 level</u></mark>, however, the net calcification rate of the live specimens was reduced to only about 20 percent of what it was at normal pH, but <u><mark>life continued</u></mark>. Throughout the second and warmer observation period, on the other hand, <u>calcification ceased in both the normal and high CO2 treatments,and in the extremely high CO2 treatment, the transplants died</u>. Based on these findings the five scientists concluded, ―at moderate temperatures,‖ such as those to which they are currently adapted, ―adult <u><mark>M. truncata are able to up-regulate their calcification rates and survive in areas with higher levels of pCO2 than are predicted to occur due to anthropogenic ocean acidification</u></mark>, although this ability broke down below mean pH 7.4.‖ This latter level, however, is below what even the IPCC predicts will occur in response to continued burning of fossil fuels, and far below what the more realistic analysis of Tans (2009) suggests.</p>
null
null
Environment
430,564
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,077
Can’t solve Nepal—evidence is about massive exports
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Can’t solve Nepal—evidence is about massive exports</h4>
null
null
Countries
430,562
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,078
No Asian war.
Acharya 12
Acharya 12 [Amitav Acharya is Professor of International Relations at American University, Washington, DC. This article is from East Asia Forum (www.eastasiaforum.org) at the Crawford School, ANU. China’s rise and security in the Asian century May 6th, 2012 Author: Amitav Acharya, AU http://www.eastasiaforum.org/2012/05/06/china-s-rise-and-security-in-the-asian-century/]
scenarios ignore significant changes Asia has seen a major growth in economic internationalism production networks straddle national boundaries, making them especially costly to break institutions have proliferated; and now outnumber formal military alliances groups like ASEAN facilitate the peaceful engagement of great powers China supports and sustains Asian economic interdependence and institutions, as do the US, Japan and India. there are multiple mechanisms of stability: economic interdependence raises the stakes of mutual survival and well-being; US-centred alliances preserve the balance of power; and cooperative institutions develop a habit of dialogue and moderate extreme, unilateral behaviour.
scenarios ignore significant changes Asia has seen a major growth in economic internationalism production networks straddle national boundaries, making them especially costly to break institutions have proliferated; and now outnumber formal military alliances groups like ASEAN facilitate the peaceful engagement of great powers China supports and sustains Asian economic interdependence and institutions, as do the US, Japan and India. there are multiple mechanisms of stability: economic interdependence raises the stakes of mutual survival and well-being; US-centred alliances preserve the balance of power; and cooperative institutions develop a habit of dialogue and moderate extreme, unilateral behaviour.
The problem with these scenarios is that they ignore significant changes that have taken place in Asia in recent decades. Asian security in the aftermath of World War II was shaped by three forces: economic nationalism, security bilateralism (anchored on the US’s ‘hub-and-spoke’ alliances), and political authoritarianism. Over the decades, Asia has seen a major growth in economic internationalism, multilateral institutions and democratisation. Since the mid-1950s, intra-Asian trade has nearly doubled to over 50 per cent of the region’s total trade. The effect of economic interdependence and multilateral institutions in promoting peace has been well documented by international relations scholars. In Asia today, production networks straddle national boundaries, making them especially costly to break; multipurpose regional institutions have proliferated; and cooperative institutions now outnumber formal military alliances, thus reversing the Cold War pattern. Democracies in Asia today outnumber autocracies and, despite fears that democratic transitions might produce aggressively nationalistic regimes, no newly democratic regime in Asia has behaved this way. The Asian regional order today resembles neither the 19th century Concert of Europe, nor the EU of today. The EU model is implausible in a highly sovereignty-conscious Asia. An Asian concert of powers is unrealistic and dangerous. The two most important pitfalls of this idea are long-known. First, for a concert to function successfully it requires a degree of ideological convergence among the major powers. Such a convergence does not exist pending China’s democratisation. On the other hand, a concert based on current ideological conditions would be a welcome gift to China’s authoritarian rulers, as it would preserve a conservative status quo that would arrest China’s democratisation. A concert of this type would also necessarily marginalise weaker states. The Concert of Europe, as historian Richard Elrod points out, ensured a degree of self-restraint among the great powers toward each other, but also brought about ‘great power tutelage over the rest of Europe’ before collapsing over ideological divergence. An Asian concert would imply de facto Sino–US joint rule, but will the rest of Asia really want to live under Chinese or US tutelage? In contrast, Asia’s regional groups like the ASEAN Regional Forum or the East Asian Summit facilitate the peaceful engagement of great powers with each other and with the region, without reducing weaker states to the status of vassals and pawns. The rise of China requires adjustments and strengthening of the current order — not reinventing an outdated model. Asia’s future need not resemble Europe’s past or present. Nor will it resemble past US foreign policy. The revival of a tributary order would be similarly countered by the economic, strategic and cultural influence of the US, Japan, India and Russia. Moreover, a concert model may not serve Australia’s security interests because it will almost certainly be excluded from it. Asia and Australia are better served by a model based on the kind of ‘entrepreneurial’ and ‘intellectual’ leadership to which Japan, Australia and ASEAN (now South Korea, Indonesia and India) have made a contribution, and which has brought about the simultaneous engagement of China and the US. For all its recent diplomatic assertiveness, China supports and sustains Asian economic interdependence and institutions, as do the US, Japan and India. At the same time, US alliances and security ties with India offer a hedge against any future uncertainty in Chinese behaviour. In Asia today there are multiple mechanisms of stability: economic interdependence raises the stakes of mutual survival and well-being; US-centred alliances preserve the balance of power; and cooperative institutions develop a habit of dialogue and thereby moderate extreme, unilateral behaviour. None of these is sufficient by itself to guarantee order, but together they create the conditions for stability.
4,058
<h4>No Asian war.</h4><p><u><strong>Acharya 12</u></strong> [Amitav Acharya is Professor of International Relations at American University, Washington, DC. This article is from East Asia Forum (www.eastasiaforum.org) at the Crawford School, ANU. China’s rise and security in the Asian century May 6th, 2012 Author: Amitav Acharya, AU http://www.eastasiaforum.org/2012/05/06/china-s-rise-and-security-in-the-asian-century/]</p><p>The problem with these <u><mark>scenarios</u></mark> is that they <u><strong><mark>ignore significant changes</u></strong></mark> that have taken place in Asia in recent decades. Asian security in the aftermath of World War II was shaped by three forces: economic nationalism, security bilateralism (anchored on the US’s ‘hub-and-spoke’ alliances), and political authoritarianism. Over the decades, <u><mark>Asia has seen a major growth in economic internationalism</u></mark>, multilateral institutions and democratisation. Since the mid-1950s, intra-Asian trade has nearly doubled to over 50 per cent of the region’s total trade. The effect of economic interdependence and multilateral institutions in promoting peace has been well documented by international relations scholars. In Asia today, <u><mark>production networks straddle national boundaries, making them especially costly to break</u></mark>; multipurpose regional <u><mark>institutions have proliferated; and</u></mark> cooperative institutions <u><mark>now outnumber formal military alliances</u></mark>, thus reversing the Cold War pattern. Democracies in Asia today outnumber autocracies and, despite fears that democratic transitions might produce aggressively nationalistic regimes, no newly democratic regime in Asia has behaved this way. The Asian regional order today resembles neither the 19th century Concert of Europe, nor the EU of today. The EU model is implausible in a highly sovereignty-conscious Asia. An Asian concert of powers is unrealistic and dangerous. The two most important pitfalls of this idea are long-known. First, for a concert to function successfully it requires a degree of ideological convergence among the major powers. Such a convergence does not exist pending China’s democratisation. On the other hand, a concert based on current ideological conditions would be a welcome gift to China’s authoritarian rulers, as it would preserve a conservative status quo that would arrest China’s democratisation. A concert of this type would also necessarily marginalise weaker states. The Concert of Europe, as historian Richard Elrod points out, ensured a degree of self-restraint among the great powers toward each other, but also brought about ‘great power tutelage over the rest of Europe’ before collapsing over ideological divergence. An Asian concert would imply de facto Sino–US joint rule, but will the rest of Asia really want to live under Chinese or US tutelage? In contrast, Asia’s regional <u><mark>groups like</u></mark> the <u><mark>ASEAN</u></mark> Regional Forum or the East Asian Summit <u><mark>facilitate the peaceful engagement of great powers</u></mark> with each other and with the region, without reducing weaker states to the status of vassals and pawns. The rise of China requires adjustments and strengthening of the current order — not reinventing an outdated model. Asia’s future need not resemble Europe’s past or present. Nor will it resemble past US foreign policy. The revival of a tributary order would be similarly countered by the economic, strategic and cultural influence of the US, Japan, India and Russia. Moreover, a concert model may not serve Australia’s security interests because it will almost certainly be excluded from it. Asia and Australia are better served by a model based on the kind of ‘entrepreneurial’ and ‘intellectual’ leadership to which Japan, Australia and ASEAN (now South Korea, Indonesia and India) have made a contribution, and which has brought about the simultaneous engagement of China and the US. For all its recent diplomatic assertiveness, <u><mark>China supports and sustains Asian economic interdependence and institutions, as do the US, Japan and India.</u></mark> At the same time, US alliances and security ties with India offer a hedge against any future uncertainty in Chinese behaviour. In Asia today <u><mark>there are <strong>multiple mechanisms of stability</strong>: economic interdependence raises the stakes of mutual survival and well-being; US-centred alliances preserve the balance of power; and cooperative institutions develop a habit of dialogue and</u></mark> thereby <u><mark>moderate extreme, unilateral behaviour.</u></mark> None of these is sufficient by itself to guarantee order, but together they create the conditions for stability.</p>
null
null
Countries
97,821
6
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,079
If cartel can’t sell, Nepal can’t either
Carlson 2015
Carlson January 21, 2015 (Nicholas; DAVOS SOURCE: The US Is Growing So Much Weed Now, They're Burning Down Their Crops In Mexico; http://www.businessinsider.com/davos-source-the-us-is-growing-so-much-weed-now-theyre-burning-down-their-crops-in-mexico-2015-1#ixzz3PjrrOYGZ; kdf)
at the World Economic Forum in Davos, , a source with knowledge of security issues along the United States-Mexico border shared : The supply of marijuana grown in the U S has become so abundant and cheap that in the regions of northern Mexico, farmers have taken to burning their crops. Because of the increased domestic supply, it is no longer profitable for these Mexican farmers to and transport weed across the border They've decided there is more money in burning their crops and planting something else Medical marijuana is legal in 23 states, and recreational marijuana is legal in three and decriminalized in many more.
at Davos a source with knowledge of the border shared supply grown in the U S has become so abundant and cheap that in Mexico, farmers have taken to burning their crops. Because it is no longer profitable burning their crops and planting something else makes sense
Tuesday night at the World Economic Forum in Davos, Switzerland, a source with knowledge of security issues along the United States-Mexico border shared this interesting tidbit: The supply of marijuana grown in the United States has become so abundant and cheap that in the regions of northern Mexico, where it used to be grown, farmers have taken to burning their crops. Because of the increased domestic supply, it is no longer profitable for these Mexican farmers to grow, reap, and transport weed across the border. They've decided there is more money in burning down their crops down and planting something else instead. This makes sense. Medical marijuana is legal in 23 states, and recreational marijuana is legal in three and decriminalized in many more.
762
<h4>If cartel can’t sell, Nepal can’t either</h4><p><strong>Carlson</strong> January 21, <strong>2015 </strong>(Nicholas; DAVOS SOURCE: The US Is Growing So Much Weed Now, They're Burning Down Their Crops In Mexico; http://www.businessinsider.com/davos-source-the-us-is-growing-so-much-weed-now-theyre-burning-down-their-crops-in-mexico-2015-1#ixzz3PjrrOYGZ; kdf<u>)</p><p></u>Tuesday night <u><mark>at </mark>the World Economic Forum in <mark>Davos</mark>,</u> Switzerland<u>, <mark>a source with knowledge of</mark> security issues along <mark>the</mark> United States-Mexico <mark>border shared</u></mark> this interesting tidbit<u>: The <mark>supply </mark>of marijuana <mark>grown in the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u><mark>has become <strong>so abundant and cheap</strong></mark> <mark>that in</mark> the regions of northern <mark>Mexico,</u></mark> where it used to be grown, <u><mark>farmers have taken to <strong>burning their crops</strong>. Because</mark> of the increased domestic supply,</u> <u><mark>it is no longer profitable</mark> for these Mexican farmers to</u> grow, reap, <u>and transport weed across the border</u>. <u>They've decided there is more money in <mark>burning</mark> </u>down <u><mark>their crops</u></mark> down <u><mark>and planting something else</u></mark> instead. This <mark>makes sense</mark>. <u>Medical marijuana is legal in 23 states, and recreational marijuana is legal in three and decriminalized in many more.</p></u>
null
null
Countries
430,565
5
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,080
Economic growth doesn’t resolve Nepalese instability—
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>Economic growth doesn’t resolve Nepalese instability—</h4>
null
null
Countries
430,563
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,081
No Indo-Pak war.
Loudon 8
Loudon 8 [Bruce, The Australian, Doomsday dread, December 04, 2008, http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,24746635-25837,00.html]
their fourth war is an unlikely prospect. No one in either capital -- even the hotheads -- is thinking in those terms. Experienced strategic analysts rule it out the political will in both sides, despite muscle-flexing, is overwhelmingly against resort to nuclear arsenals. India has a firm no-first-strike policy and Zardari turned Pakistani policy on its head by articulating a similar stance. On both sides there is a mood of extreme caution
their fourth war is an unlikely prospect. No one in either capital -- even the hotheads -- is thinking in those terms. Experienced strategic analysts rule it out the political will in both sides, despite muscle-flexing, is overwhelmingly against resort to nuclear arsenals. India has a firm no-first-strike policy and Zardari turned Pakistani policy on its head by articulating a similar stance. On both sides there is a mood of extreme caution
THE doomsayers' published assessments tell the grim story: upwards of 12 million people killed on the first day of a nuclear exchange, more than 150 million dead in a longer nuclear conflict. Devastation and destruction on a scale that is almost unimaginable. A catastrophe that would vastly transcend that seen at Hiroshima and Nagasaki at the end of World War II. That is why, as India and Pakistan muscle up to each other after the Mumbai massacre and leaders from across the world hurry to counsel cool heads and caution in New Delhi and Islamabad, the unspoken fear everywhere is that the two South Asian neighbours could be pushed into the unthinkable: their fourth war, and one in which they would mobilise their nuclear arsenals. It is, it must be said, an unlikely prospect. No one in either capital -- even among the hotheads -- is thinking in those terms. Experienced strategic analysts rule it out. "Don't even think about it. It ain't going to happen," one says. But as the crisis over terrorism across South Asia deepens and jihadist groups linked to al-Qa'ida launch devastating attacks such as the one in Mumbai last week -- attacks designed to exacerbate tensions between India and Pakistan -- there is, in the view of most analysts, always the potential for events to tumble out of control and lead to a doomsday nuclear conflagration, with enormous loss of life. "South Asia's a nuclear tinderbox," a leading military analyst in New Delhi tells The Australian. "Yes, of course, I'd just about rule it out in the context of the face-off following the Mumbai attack. "But it's always there, always nagging at the edges of the constant tensions in the subcontinent. And there's no doubt that Osama (bin Laden) is doing his bit to stir the pot and do what he can to increase those tensions, since conflict between India and Pakistan serves the jihadist cause." Yesterday, US military officials in Washington, DC, closely monitoring the situation described the military temperature between the two neighbours as "pretty low right now", adding that although Pakistan has moved some aircraft and air defence units closer to the Indian border since the Mumbai attack, "on the nuclear side there is nothing". Which is hardly surprising, for the political will in both sides, despite the muscle-flexing, is overwhelmingly against resort to their nuclear arsenals. India, since it demonstrated its nuclear capability in 1998, has maintained a firm no-first-strike policy and a few days ago Pakistan's President Asif Ali Zardari turned longstanding Pakistani policy on its head (some believe to the annoyance of the country's powerful generals) by articulating a similar stance. On both sides there is a mood of extreme caution on the subject of any possible use of nuclear weapons, matched only by the intense secrecy that surrounds their arsenals. Jamaica not key to regional stability—US dominance in the region checks Don’t solve asymmetric threats
2,969
<h4>No Indo-Pak war.</h4><p><u><strong>Loudon 8</u></strong> [Bruce, The Australian, Doomsday dread, December 04, 2008, http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,24746635-25837,00.html]</p><p>THE doomsayers' published assessments tell the grim story: upwards of 12 million people killed on the first day of a nuclear exchange, more than 150 million dead in a longer nuclear conflict. Devastation and destruction on a scale that is almost unimaginable. A catastrophe that would vastly transcend that seen at Hiroshima and Nagasaki at the end of World War II. That is why, as India and Pakistan muscle up to each other after the Mumbai massacre and leaders from across the world hurry to counsel cool heads and caution in New Delhi and Islamabad, the unspoken fear everywhere is that the two South Asian neighbours could be pushed into the unthinkable: <u><mark>their fourth war</u></mark>, and one in which they would mobilise their nuclear arsenals. It <u><mark>is</u></mark>, it must be said, <u><strong><mark>an unlikely prospect.</strong> No one in either capital -- even</u></mark> among <u><mark>the hotheads -- is thinking in those terms. <strong>Experienced strategic analysts rule it out</u></strong></mark>. "Don't even think about it. It ain't going to happen," one says. But as the crisis over terrorism across South Asia deepens and jihadist groups linked to al-Qa'ida launch devastating attacks such as the one in Mumbai last week -- attacks designed to exacerbate tensions between India and Pakistan -- there is, in the view of most analysts, always the potential for events to tumble out of control and lead to a doomsday nuclear conflagration, with enormous loss of life. "South Asia's a nuclear tinderbox," a leading military analyst in New Delhi tells The Australian. "Yes, of course, I'd just about rule it out in the context of the face-off following the Mumbai attack. "But it's always there, always nagging at the edges of the constant tensions in the subcontinent. And there's no doubt that Osama (bin Laden) is doing his bit to stir the pot and do what he can to increase those tensions, since conflict between India and Pakistan serves the jihadist cause." Yesterday, US military officials in Washington, DC, closely monitoring the situation described the military temperature between the two neighbours as "pretty low right now", adding that although Pakistan has moved some aircraft and air defence units closer to the Indian border since the Mumbai attack, "on the nuclear side there is nothing". Which is hardly surprising, for <u><mark>the political will in both sides, despite</u></mark> the <u><mark>muscle-flexing, is <strong>overwhelmingly against</strong> resort to</u></mark> their <u><mark>nuclear arsenals. India</u></mark>, since it demonstrated its nuclear capability in 1998, <u><mark>has</u></mark> maintained <u><mark>a firm no-first-strike policy and</u></mark> a few days ago Pakistan's President Asif Ali <u><mark>Zardari turned</u></mark> longstanding <u><mark>Pakistani policy on its head</u></mark> (some believe to the annoyance of the country's powerful generals) <u><mark>by articulating a similar stance. On both sides there is a <strong>mood of extreme caution</u></strong></mark> on the subject of any possible use of nuclear weapons, matched only by the intense secrecy that surrounds their arsenals.</p><p>Jamaica not key to regional stability—US dominance in the region checks </p><p>Don’t solve asymmetric threats</p>
null
null
Countries
196,700
7
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,082
No Russian war.
MacGregor 11
MacGregor 11 [Lean, Mean Fighting Machine How to slash the Pentagon budget? Declare victory and go home. BY DOUGLAS MACGREGOR | APRIL 26, 2011 http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2011/04/26/lean_mean_fighting_machine]
there is no existential military threat to the U S The nuclear arsenals in Russia could be used but Russian leaders have no incentive to contemplate suicide in a nuclear confrontation with the U S For all its rhetoric, Russia's military focus is on restive Muslim populations in the Caucasus and Central Asia, not on NATO.
null
For one thing, there is no existential military threat to the United States or to its vital strategic interests. The nuclear arsenals in Russia and China could be used against the United States and its forces, but Russian and Chinese leaders have no incentive to contemplate suicide in a nuclear confrontation with the United States. Russia's diminished million-man armed forces are hard-pressed to modernize, let alone secure their own country, which borders 14 other states. For all its rhetoric, Russia's military focus is on restive Muslim populations in the Caucasus and Central Asia, not on NATO.
602
<h4>No Russian war.</h4><p><u><strong>MacGregor 11</strong> [Lean, Mean Fighting Machine How to slash the Pentagon budget? Declare victory and go home. BY DOUGLAS MACGREGOR | APRIL 26, 2011 http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2011/04/26/lean_mean_fighting_machine]</p><p></u>For one thing, <u>there is no existential military threat to the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates or to its vital strategic interests. <u>The nuclear arsenals in Russia</u> and China <u>could be used</u> against the United States and its forces, <u>but Russian</u> and Chinese <u>leaders have no incentive to contemplate suicide in a nuclear confrontation with the U</u>nited <u>S</u>tates. Russia's diminished million-man armed forces are hard-pressed to modernize, let alone secure their own country, which borders 14 other states. <u>For all its rhetoric, Russia's military focus is on restive Muslim populations in the Caucasus and Central Asia, not on NATO.</p></u>
null
null
Countries
276,501
6
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,083
No threatening programs and current defenses solve.
Orent 9
Orent 9 [Wendy, Ph.D. in anthropology from the University of Michigan, leading freelance science writer, and author of Plague: The Mysterious Past and Terrifying Future of the World's Most Dangerous Disease, "America's Bioterror Bugaboo." Los Angeles Times (Los Angeles, CA) 17 Jul 2009: A.29. SIRS Researcher. Web. 29 January 2010]
After the anthrax attacks Bush pledged $57 billion to keep the nation safe from bioterror. the government has created a vast network of laboratories and institutions to block every remotely conceivable threat. Obama seems committed to continuing the push Russian bioweapons program was officially shut down Iraq had no program. And Al Qaeda's explorations were interrupted by the invasion of Afghanistan.
After the anthrax attacks Bush pledged $57 billion to keep the nation safe from bioterror. the government has created a vast network of laboratories and institutions to block every remotely conceivable threat. Obama seems committed to continuing the push Russian bioweapons program was officially shut down Iraq had no program. And Al Qaeda's explorations were interrupted by the invasion of Afghanistan.
After the anthrax letter attacks of October 2001, the Bush administration pledged $57 billion to keep the nation safe from bioterror. Since then, the government has created a vast network of laboratories and institutions to track down and block every remotely conceivable form of bioterror threat. The Obama administration seems committed to continuing the biodefense push, having just appointed a zealous bioterror researcher as undersecretary of science and technology in the Department of Homeland Security. But is the threat really as great as we've been led to believe? Last summer, the FBI concluded that the anthrax letters that killed five Americans came not from abroad but from an American laboratory, the United States Army Medical Research Institute of Infectious Diseases. Meanwhile, the Russian bioweapons program was officially shut down in 1992, and it's unlikely that anything remaining of it could pose much of a threat. Iraq, it has turned out, had no active program. And Al Qaeda's rudimentary explorations were interrupted, according to an Army War College report, by the U.S. invasion of Afghanistan.
1,125
<h4>No threatening programs and current defenses solve.</h4><p><u><strong>Orent 9</strong><mark> [Wendy, Ph.D. in anthropology from the University of Michigan, leading freelance science writer, and author of Plague: The Mysterious Past and Terrifying Future of the World's Most Dangerous Disease, "America's Bioterror Bugaboo." Los Angeles Times (Los Angeles, CA) 17 Jul 2009: A.29. SIRS Researcher. Web. 29 January 2010]</p><p>After the anthrax</u></mark> letter <u><mark>attacks</u></mark> of October 2001, the <u><mark>Bush</u></mark> administration <u><mark>pledged $57 billion to keep the nation safe from bioterror.</u></mark> Since then, <u><mark>the government has created a vast network of laboratories and institutions to</u></mark> track down and <u><mark>block <strong>every remotely conceivable</u></strong></mark> form of bioterror <u><mark>threat.</u></mark> The <u><mark>Obama</u></mark> administration <u><mark>seems committed to continuing the</u></mark> biodefense <u><mark>push</u></mark>, having just appointed a zealous bioterror researcher as undersecretary of science and technology in the Department of Homeland Security. But is the threat really as great as we've been led to believe? Last summer, the FBI concluded that the anthrax letters that killed five Americans came not from abroad but from an American laboratory, the United States Army Medical Research Institute of Infectious Diseases. Meanwhile, the <u><mark>Russian bioweapons program was officially shut down</u></mark> in 1992, and it's unlikely that anything remaining of it could pose much of a threat. <u><mark>Iraq</u></mark>, it has turned out, <u><mark>had no</u></mark> active <u><mark>program. And Al Qaeda's</u></mark> rudimentary <u><mark>explorations were interrupted</u></mark>, according to an Army War College report, <u><mark>by the</u></mark> U.S. <u><mark>invasion of Afghanistan.</p></u></mark>
null
null
Countries
169,529
19
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,084
Not an existential risk.
Fettweis 10 om the University of Notre Dame, Threat and Anxiety in US Foreign Policy, April 2010 Survival, 52:2, 59 - 82]
Fettweis 10 [Christopher J., fifth year doctoral student in the University of Maryland's Department of Government and Politics. His primary interests include US foreign and national security policies. His dissertation, currently titled The Geopolitics of Energy and the Obsolescence of Major War, focuses on the relationship between oil and conflict. Mr. Fettweis has a BA in History from the University of Notre Dame, Threat and Anxiety in US Foreign Policy, April 2010 Survival, 52:2, 59 - 82]
terrorists would be incapable of causing damage so cataclysmic that it would prove fatal to modern states. the prospect is highly unlikely the well-funded, well-staffed Aum Shinrikyo found out workable w m d are hard to purchase, harder to synthesise and challenging to use The group managed to kill a dozen people hardly the stuff of apocalyptic nightmares. Super-weapons are simply not easy for even the most sophisticated non-state actors Modern industrialised countries can cope with disasters, both natural and man-made. such events do not represent existential threats.
terrorists would be incapable of causing damage so cataclysmic that it would prove fatal to modern states. the prospect is highly unlikely the well-funded, well-staffed Aum Shinrikyo found out workable w m d are hard to purchase, harder to synthesise and challenging to use The group managed to kill a dozen people hardly the stuff of apocalyptic nightmares. Super-weapons are simply not easy for even the most sophisticated non-state actors Modern industrialised countries can cope with disasters, both natural and man-made. such events do not represent existential threats.
Even terrorists equipped with nuclear, biological or chemical weapons would be incapable of causing damage so cataclysmic that it would prove fatal to modern states. Though the prospect of terrorists obtaining and using such weapons is one of the most consistently terrifying scenarios of the new era, it is also highly unlikely and not nearly as dangerous as sometimes portrayed. As the well-funded, well-staffed Aum Shinrikyo cult found out in the 1990s, workable forms of weapons of mass destruction are hard to purchase, harder still to synthesise without state help, and challenging to use effectively. The Japanese group managed to kill a dozen people on the Tokyo subway system at rush hour. While tragic, the attack was hardly the stuff of apocalyptic nightmares. Super-weapons are simply not easy for even the most sophisticated non-state actors to use.31 If terrorists were able to overcome the substantial obstacles and use the most destructive weapons in a densely populated area, the outcome would of course be terrible for those unfortunate enough to be nearby. But we should not operate under the illusion that doomsday would arrive. Modern industrialised countries can cope with disasters, both natural and man-made. As unpleasant as such events would be, they do not represent existential threats.
1,314
<h4>Not an existential risk.</h4><p><u><strong>Fettweis 10 </u></strong>[Christopher J., fifth year doctoral student in the University of Maryland's Department of Government and Politics. His primary interests include US foreign and national security policies. His dissertation, currently titled The Geopolitics of Energy and the Obsolescence of Major War, focuses on the relationship between oil and conflict. Mr. Fettweis has a BA in History fr<u><strong><mark>om the University of Notre Dame, Threat and Anxiety in US Foreign Policy, April 2010 Survival, 52:2, 59 - 82]</p><p></u></strong></mark>Even <u><mark>terrorists</u></mark> equipped with nuclear, biological or chemical weapons <u><mark>would be incapable of causing damage so cataclysmic that it would prove fatal to modern states.</u></mark> Though <u><mark>the prospect</u></mark> of terrorists obtaining and using such weapons is one of the most consistently terrifying scenarios of the new era, it <u><mark>is</u></mark> also <u><strong><mark>highly unlikely</u></strong></mark> and not nearly as dangerous as sometimes portrayed. As <u><mark>the well-funded, well-staffed Aum Shinrikyo</u></mark> cult <u><mark>found out</u></mark> in the 1990s, <u><mark>workable</u></mark> forms of <u><mark>w</u></mark>eapons of <u><mark>m</u></mark>ass <u><mark>d</u></mark>estruction <u><mark>are hard to purchase, harder</u></mark> still <u><mark>to synthesise</u></mark> without state help, <u><mark>and challenging to use</u></mark> effectively. <u><mark>The</u></mark> Japanese <u><mark>group managed to kill a dozen people</u></mark> on the Tokyo subway system at rush hour. While tragic, the attack was <u><mark>hardly the stuff of apocalyptic nightmares. Super-weapons are simply not easy for even the most sophisticated non-state actors</u></mark> to use.31 If terrorists were able to overcome the substantial obstacles and use the most destructive weapons in a densely populated area, the outcome would of course be terrible for those unfortunate enough to be nearby. But we should not operate under the illusion that doomsday would arrive. <u><mark>Modern industrialised countries can cope with disasters, both natural and man-made.</u></mark> As unpleasant as <u><strong><mark>such events</u></strong></mark> would be, they <u><strong><mark>do not represent existential threats.</p></u></strong></mark>
null
null
Countries
50,562
33
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,085
Their ONLY fed key warrant on War on Drugs is the Wild ev- it advocates federal legalization but there’s NO REASON that’s KEY- just says the US needs to adopt a less repressive policy on marijuana and the plan is an example of that- things like the CP and harm reduction policy would ALSO be sufficient- we’ve highlighted the ACTUAL warrants
Wild, 13
Wild, 13 [Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis]
The U.S. wields considerable influence over the rest of the world so it is no surprise that its call for the development and maintenance of prohibitive, punitive drug policies resulted in a majority of the international community following. Conversely, if the U.S. leads the call for the development and maintenance of more tolerant drug policies grounded in health a majority of the international community will also follow. until there is reform and supporting other countries to develop drug policies that suit their context there is still an abdication of policy responsibility. If marijuana was legal it would function similarly to the market of legal substances the U.S., law enforcement could refocus their efforts away from reducing the marijuana marke and instead towards reducing harm to individuals communities and national Marijuana is an actionable, evidence based mechanism for constructive legal and policy reform that through a domino effect can transform the global drug prohibition regime
The U.S. wields considerable influence so it is no surprise that punitive drug policies resulted in the community following Conversely, if the U.S. leads the call for tolerant drug policies a majority will also follow until there is reform supporting other countries to develop drug policies that suit their context there is still an abdication of responsibility enforcement could refocus away from marijuana and instead towards reducing harm Marijuana is an actionable, mechanism for constructive reform that through a domino effect can transform the global drug regime
C. Step 2: Real Reform - the U.S. Needs to Stand at the Forefront of Drug Policy Reformation The U.S. wields considerable influence over the rest of the world, so it is no surprise that its call for the development and maintenance of prohibitive, punitive drug policies resulted in a majority of the international community following. n105 Conversely, if the U.S. leads the call for the development and maintenance of more tolerant drug policies grounded in health, humanity and science, a majority of the international community will also follow. n106 Cultural shifts do not take place overnight, and the idea of complete U.S. drug policy reformation is too aggressive and stark in contrast to succeed against modern bureaucracy and political alliances. n107 On the other hand, a more moderate, piecemeal approach could effectively act as a catalyst for this transformation while simultaneously serving as a case study for opponents of legal regulation. n108 [*442] If the U.S. is serious about addressing the ineffectiveness of the War on Drugs, then the federal government must remove marijuana from its list of criminally banned substances. n109 The tone of the Obama administration is a significant step in this direction. n110 President Obama has explicitly acknowledged the need to treat drugs as more of a public health problem, as well as the validity of debate on alternatives, but he does not favor drug legalization. n111 This progressive rhetoric is a significant step in the right direction, but until there is some real reform confronting the issue, reducing punitive measures and supporting other countries to develop drug policies that suit their context, there is still an abdication of policy responsibility. n112 1. Starting Small - Potential Positive Effects of Regulation and Taxation of Marijuana in the U.S. If marijuana was legal in the U.S., it would function similarly to the market of legal substances such as liquor, coffee and tobacco. n113 Individual and corporate participants in the market would pay taxes, increasing revenues and saving the government from the exorbitant cost of trying to enforce prohibition laws. n114 Consumers' human rights would be promoted through self-determination, autonomy and access to more accurate information about the product they are consuming. n115 Additionally, case studies and research suggest that the decriminalization or legalization [*443] of marijuana reduces the drugs' consumption and does not necessarily result in a more favorable attitude towards it. n116 The legal regulation of marijuana would relieve the current displaced burden the drug places on law enforcement, domestically and internationally. n117 In the U.S., law enforcement could refocus their efforts away from reducing the marijuana market per se and instead towards reducing harm to individuals, communities and national security. n118 Abroad, U.S. international relations would improve because of the reduced levels of corruption and violence at home and afar. n119 The precarious position repressive policies place on foreign governments when they have to destroy the livelihoods of agricultural workers would be reduced. n120 Additionally, legalization and regulation would provide assistance to governments in regaining some degree of control over the regions dominated by drug dealers and terrorist groups because those groups would lose a major source of funding for their organizations. n121 2. Health Concerns? - Marijuana in Comparison to Other Similar Legal Substances The federal government, acknowledging the risks inherent in alcohol and tobacco, argues that adding a third substance to that mix cannot be beneficial. n122 Adding anything to a class of [*444] dangerous substances is likely never going to be beneficial; however marijuana would be incorrectly classified if it was equated with those two substances. n123 Marijuana is far less toxic and addictive than alcohol and tobacco. n124 Long term use of marijuana is far less damaging than long term alcohol or tobacco use. n125 Alcohol use contributes to aggressive and reckless behavior, acts of violence and serious injuries while marijuana actually reduces likelihood of aggressive behavior or violence during intoxication and is seldom associated with emergency room visits. n126 As with most things in life, there can be no guarantee that the legalization or decriminalization of marijuana would lead the U.S. to a better socio-economical position in the future. n127 Two things however, are certain: that the legalization of marijuana in the U.S. would dramatically reduce most of the costs associated with the current drug policies, domestically and internationally, and [*445] if the U.S. is serious about its objective of considering the costs of drug control measures, then it is vital and rational for the legalization option is considered. n128 D. Why the Time is Ripe for U.S. Drug Policy Reformation The political atmosphere at the end of World War I and II was leverage for the U.S., emerging as the dominant political, economic and military power. n129 This leverage allowed it to shape a prohibitive drug control regime that until now has remained in perpetuity. n130 Today, we stand in a unique moment inside of U.S. history. n131 The generational, political and cultural shifts that accompanied the U.S. emergence from the "Great Recession" resulted in a sociopolitical climate that may be what is necessary for real reform. n132 Politically, marijuana has become a hot issue; economically, the marijuana industry is bolstering a faltering economy and socially, marijuana is poised to transform the way we live and view medicine. n133 The public disdain for the widespread problems prohibition caused in the early 20th century resulted in the end of alcohol prohibition during the Great Depression. n134 If history does actually repeat itself than the Great recession may have been much more telling than expected. n135 V. Conclusion The U.S. and its prohibitionist ideals exacerbated the failure of both the international and its own domestic drug policies. n136 As a result, the U.S. should accept accountability for its mistakes by reforming its drug policies in a way that will help [*446] place the global drug market back into a manageable position. n137 Marijuana is an actionable, evidence based mechanism for constructive legal and policy reform that through a domino effect can transform the global drug prohibition regime. n138 The generational, political and cultural shifts that accompanied the U.S. emergence from the "Great Recession" have resulted in a sociopolitical climate ready for real reform. n139 The U.S. will capitalize on this unique moment by removing marijuana from the list of federally banned substances, setting the stage for future international and domestic drug policies that are actually effective. n140
6,875
<h4>Their ONLY fed key warrant on War on Drugs is the Wild ev- it advocates federal legalization but there’s NO REASON that’s KEY- just says the US needs to adopt a less repressive policy on marijuana and the plan is an example of that- things like the CP and harm reduction policy would ALSO be sufficient- we’ve highlighted the ACTUAL warrants</h4><p><strong>Wild, 13</strong> [Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis] </p><p>C. Step 2: Real Reform - the U.S. Needs to Stand at the Forefront of Drug Policy Reformation <u><mark>The U.S. wields considerable influence</mark> over the rest of the world</u>, <u><mark>so it is no surprise that </mark>its call for the development and maintenance of</u> <u>prohibitive, <mark>punitive drug policies resulted in</mark> a majority of <mark>the</mark> international <mark>community following</mark>.</u> n105 <u><mark>Conversely, <strong>if the U.S. leads the call for</mark> the development and maintenance of more <mark>tolerant drug policies</u></strong></mark> <u>grounded in health</u>, humanity and science, <u><mark>a majority</mark> of the international community <strong><mark>will also follow</mark>.</strong> </u>n106 Cultural shifts do not take place overnight, and the idea of complete U.S. drug policy reformation is too aggressive and stark in contrast to succeed against modern bureaucracy and political alliances. n107 On the other hand, a more moderate, piecemeal approach could effectively act as a catalyst for this transformation while simultaneously serving as a case study for opponents of legal regulation. n108 [*442] If the U.S. is serious about addressing the ineffectiveness of the War on Drugs, then the federal government must remove marijuana from its list of criminally banned substances. n109 The tone of the Obama administration is a significant step in this direction. n110 President Obama has explicitly acknowledged the need to treat drugs as more of a public health problem, as well as the validity of debate on alternatives, but he does not favor drug legalization. n111 This progressive rhetoric is a significant step in the right direction, but <u><mark>until there is</u></mark> some real <u><mark>reform</u></mark> confronting the issue, reducing punitive measures <u>and</u> <u><strong><mark>supporting other countries to develop drug policies that suit their context</u></strong></mark>, <u><strong><mark>there is still an abdication of</strong></mark> policy <strong><mark>responsibility</strong></mark>. </u>n112<u> </u>1. Starting Small - Potential Positive Effects of Regulation and Taxation of Marijuana in the U.S. <u><strong>If marijuana</strong> <strong>was legal</u></strong> in the U.S., <u><strong>it would function similarly to the market of legal substances</u></strong> such as liquor, coffee and tobacco. n113 Individual and corporate participants in the market would pay taxes, increasing revenues and saving the government from the exorbitant cost of trying to enforce prohibition laws. n114 Consumers' human rights would be promoted through self-determination, autonomy and access to more accurate information about the product they are consuming. n115 Additionally, case studies and research suggest that the decriminalization or legalization [*443] of marijuana reduces the drugs' consumption and does not necessarily result in a more favorable attitude towards it. n116 The legal regulation of marijuana would relieve the current displaced burden the drug places on law enforcement, domestically and internationally. n117 In <u>the U.S., law <mark>enforcement could refocus</mark> their efforts <mark>away from</mark> reducing the <mark>marijuana</mark> marke</u>t per se <u><mark>and instead</u> <u>towards <strong>reducing harm</u></strong></mark> <u>to individuals</u>, <u>communities and national </u>security. n118 Abroad, U.S. international relations would improve because of the reduced levels of corruption and violence at home and afar. n119 The precarious position repressive policies place on foreign governments when they have to destroy the livelihoods of agricultural workers would be reduced. n120 Additionally, legalization and regulation would provide assistance to governments in regaining some degree of control over the regions dominated by drug dealers and terrorist groups because those groups would lose a major source of funding for their organizations. n121 2. Health Concerns? - Marijuana in Comparison to Other Similar Legal Substances The federal government, acknowledging the risks inherent in alcohol and tobacco, argues that adding a third substance to that mix cannot be beneficial. n122 Adding anything to a class of [*444] dangerous substances is likely never going to be beneficial; however marijuana would be incorrectly classified if it was equated with those two substances. n123 Marijuana is far less toxic and addictive than alcohol and tobacco. n124 Long term use of marijuana is far less damaging than long term alcohol or tobacco use. n125 Alcohol use contributes to aggressive and reckless behavior, acts of violence and serious injuries while marijuana actually reduces likelihood of aggressive behavior or violence during intoxication and is seldom associated with emergency room visits. n126 As with most things in life, there can be no guarantee that the legalization or decriminalization of marijuana would lead the U.S. to a better socio-economical position in the future. n127 Two things however, are certain: that the legalization of marijuana in the U.S. would dramatically reduce most of the costs associated with the current drug policies, domestically and internationally, and [*445] if the U.S. is serious about its objective of considering the costs of drug control measures, then it is vital and rational for the legalization option is considered. n128 D. Why the Time is Ripe for U.S. Drug Policy Reformation The political atmosphere at the end of World War I and II was leverage for the U.S., emerging as the dominant political, economic and military power. n129 This leverage allowed it to shape a prohibitive drug control regime that until now has remained in perpetuity. n130 Today, we stand in a unique moment inside of U.S. history. n131 The generational, political and cultural shifts that accompanied the U.S. emergence from the "Great Recession" resulted in a sociopolitical climate that may be what is necessary for real reform. n132 Politically, marijuana has become a hot issue; economically, the marijuana industry is bolstering a faltering economy and socially, marijuana is poised to transform the way we live and view medicine. n133 The public disdain for the widespread problems prohibition caused in the early 20th century resulted in the end of alcohol prohibition during the Great Depression. n134 If history does actually repeat itself than the Great recession may have been much more telling than expected. n135 V. Conclusion The U.S. and its prohibitionist ideals exacerbated the failure of both the international and its own domestic drug policies. n136 As a result, the U.S. should accept accountability for its mistakes by reforming its drug policies in a way that will help [*446] place the global drug market back into a manageable position. n137 <u><mark>Marijuana is an actionable,</mark> evidence based <mark>mechanism for constructive</mark> legal and</u> <u>policy <mark>reform that <strong>through a domino effect can transform the global drug </mark>prohibition <mark>regime</u></strong></mark>. n138 The generational, political and cultural shifts that accompanied the U.S. emergence from the "Great Recession" have resulted in a sociopolitical climate ready for real reform. n139 The U.S. will capitalize on this unique moment by removing marijuana from the list of federally banned substances, setting the stage for future international and domestic drug policies that are actually effective. n140</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
46,065
168
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,086
Footnotes of their ev specifically say the CP solves
Wild 2013
Wild 2013 [Footnotes 108 and 109 which are after one of their most rhetorically powerful lines, Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis]
Promotion of more tolerant drug policies through experimenting with one already socially acceptable drug is more likely to occur than a radical culture shift This relatively small step would have a domino effect on the rest of the world because of the United States' international political influence Holder announced that raiding medical marijuana facilities was a low priority of federal law enforcement. This is a pivotal point in progressive reform because it allows states to act without interference from the federal government
null
n108. See generally GCDP, supra note 1 (suggesting value of governmental experimentation with legal regulation extends to case study potential). If the United States was to legalize marijuana, it could study the effects on United States society directly and not have to speculate or hypothesize about past studies. See id. Promotion of more tolerant drug policies through experimenting with one already socially acceptable drug is more likely to occur than a radical culture shift. See id. This relatively small step would have a domino effect on the rest of the world because of the United States' international political influence. See id. n109. See Welch & Leinwand, supra note 6 (noting current administration's perspective on marijuana in federal drug policy). The Attorney General of the United States, Eric Holder, announced that raiding medical marijuana facilities was a low priority of federal law enforcement. Id. This is a pivotal point in progressive reform because it allows states to act without interference from the federal government. Id.
1,056
<h4>Footnotes of their ev specifically say the CP solves</h4><p><strong>Wild 2013</strong> [Footnotes 108 and 109 which are after one of their most rhetorically powerful lines, Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis] </p><p>n108. See generally GCDP, supra note 1 (suggesting value of governmental experimentation with legal regulation extends to case study potential). If the United States was to legalize marijuana, it could study the effects on United States society directly and not have to speculate or hypothesize about past studies. See id. <u>Promotion of more tolerant drug policies through experimenting with one already socially acceptable drug is more likely to occur than a radical culture shift</u>. See id. <u>This relatively small step would have a domino effect on the rest of the world because of the United States' international political influence</u>. See id. n109. See Welch & Leinwand, supra note 6 (noting current administration's perspective on marijuana in federal drug policy). The Attorney General of the United States, Eric <u>Holder</u>, <u>announced that raiding medical marijuana facilities was a low priority of federal law enforcement. </u>Id. <u><strong>This is a pivotal point in progressive reform because it allows states to act without interference from the federal government</u></strong>. Id.</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,566
47
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,087
Wild says SUBSTANCE matters not SIGNAL- the CP is BETTER for “experimenting with models of legal regulation”
Wild 2013
Wild 2013 [Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis]
The U.S. has worked strenuously to ensure that all countries adopt its rigid, prohibitionist approach to drug policy The U.S. can remedy its mistake by using its considerable diplomatic influence and international presence to foster reform in other countries One way to do this is by capitalizing on this unique moment in its existence and experimenting with models of legal regulation specifically with marijuana This will help redeem our image because the international marijuana market is largely created by the exorbitant U.S. demand for the drug
null
IV. Analysis A. A Starting Point for Review: Taking Accountability The War on Drugs' demise started when the bellicose analogy was created. n77 The correct classification of the global drug problem was and still is as a set of interlinked health and social challenges to be managed, not a war to be won. n78 The U.S. has worked strenuously for the past fifty years to ensure that all countries adopt its rigid, prohibitionist approach to drug policy, essentially repressing the potential for alternative policy development and experimentation. n79 This was an expensive mistake that the U.S. unfortunately cannot take back. n80 The current emergence from the economic recession of 2008-2009 has set the stage for a generational, political and cultural shift, placing the U.S. in a unique moment in its history; the necessary sociopolitical context to revoke its prohibitionist ideals and replace them with more modern policies grounded in health, science and humanity. n81 The U.S. can remedy its mistake by using its considerable diplomatic influence and international presence to foster reform in other countries. n82 One way to do this is by capitalizing [*438] on this unique moment in its existence and experimenting with models of legal regulation, specifically with marijuana because nearly half of U.S. citizens favor legalization of it. n83 This will help redeem our image internationally and help repair foreign relations because the monumental scope of the international marijuana market is largely created by the exorbitant U.S. demand for the drug which partially stems from the illegality of the market. n84
1,621
<h4>Wild says SUBSTANCE matters not SIGNAL- the CP is BETTER for “experimenting with models of legal regulation”</h4><p><strong>Wild 2013</strong> [Joshua, JD, Suffolk University, EPIC FAILURE: THE UNCOMFORTABLE TRUTH ABOUT THE UNITED STATES' ROLE IN THE FAILURE OF THE GLOBAL WAR ON DRUGS AND HOW IT IS GOING TO FIX IT, Suffolk University Suffolk Transnational Law Review Summer, 2013, 36 Suffolk Transnat'l L. Rev. 423, p. lexis] </p><p>IV. Analysis A. A Starting Point for Review: Taking Accountability The War on Drugs' demise started when the bellicose analogy was created. n77 The correct classification of the global drug problem was and still is as a set of interlinked health and social challenges to be managed, not a war to be won. n78 <u>The U.S. has worked strenuously</u> for the past fifty years <u>to ensure that all countries adopt its rigid, prohibitionist approach to drug policy</u>, essentially repressing the potential for alternative policy development and experimentation. n79 This was an expensive mistake that the U.S. unfortunately cannot take back. n80 The current emergence from the economic recession of 2008-2009 has set the stage for a generational, political and cultural shift, placing the U.S. in a unique moment in its history; the necessary sociopolitical context to revoke its prohibitionist ideals and replace them with more modern policies grounded in health, science and humanity. n81 <u>The U.S. can remedy its mistake by using its considerable diplomatic influence and international presence to foster reform in other countries</u>. n82 <u>One way to do this is by capitalizing </u>[*438] <u>on this unique moment in its existence and <strong>experimenting with models of legal regulation</u></strong>, <u>specifically with marijuana</u> because nearly half of U.S. citizens favor legalization of it. n83 <u>This will help redeem our image</u> internationally and help repair foreign relations <u>because</u> the monumental scope of <u>the</u> <u>international marijuana market is largely created by the exorbitant U.S. demand for the drug</u> which partially stems from the illegality of the market. n84</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,567
2
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,088
LEGAL IN THE US as a mandate of the plan- if they don’t change the CSA, they can’t be topical
Jackson et al 2011
Jackson et al 2011 (Ashlee Jackson, Chad Murray, Amanda C. Miralrío, Nicolas Eiden, Second-year Master’s students at the George Washington University Elliott School of International Affairs, Inter-American Drug Abuse Control Commission: Capstone Report, Mexican Drug Trafficking Organizations and Marijuana: The Potential Effects of U.S. Legalization, https://elliott.gwu.edu/sites/elliott.gwu.edu/files/downloads/acad/lahs/mexico-marijuana-071111.pdf)
legalization and decriminalization are terms for very different proposals even though they are sometimes conflated Decriminalization proposes the removal of the criminal penalty for possession of marijuana, but not for its trafficking and production „Legalization‟ authorizes the possession, production and trafficking of marijuana, and therefore enables the state to tax and regulate its sale and consumption A common definition of decriminalization is “the removal of the criminal sanction for possession,” in effect making the penalty for the possession of marijuana a civil rather than criminal offense What is important here is that criminal penalties for possession are removed, but there is still some type of civil sanction in place that punishes both users and producers. This is what separates decriminalization from legalization.
Legalization‟ authorizes the possession, production and trafficking of marijuana definition of decriminalization is making the penalty for the possession of marijuana civil rather than criminal ere is still some type of civil sanction in place This is what separates decriminalization from legalization
Any white paper that includes a policy review of drug legislation must include key term definitions that are clear, accurate, and coherent. Thus, there are various definitions of „legalization‟ of marijuana use and commerce strewn across countless reports, papers and analyses of drug policy. It is critical to note that legalization and decriminalization are terms for very different proposals even though they are sometimes conflated. Decriminalization proposes the removal of the criminal penalty for possession of marijuana, but not for its trafficking and production. „Legalization‟ authorizes the possession, production and trafficking of marijuana, and therefore enables the state to tax and regulate its sale and consumption.4 This study takes a holistic approach to examining how legalization of marijuana in the United States would affect Mexican DTOs. However, in the United States there has been no example of true marijuana legalization since the inception of the modern drug control regime. This is why our case studies will look at changes that occurred after various countries relaxed their system of marijuana prohibition. We will look at decriminalization in Mexico and Portugal, as well as a special case of toleration/de facto legalization in the Netherlands. However, we will first lay out in detail what each type of change entails. Decriminalization is one of the most common methods employed by countries that seek to ease or lighten anti-marijuana policies. A common definition of decriminalization is “the removal of the criminal sanction for possession,” in effect making the penalty for the possession of marijuana a civil (fines, counseling etc), rather than criminal offense. 5 One common example of this type of reform is the 2001 Law 30/2000 in Portugal. What is important here is that criminal penalties for possession are removed, but there is still some type of civil sanction in place that punishes both users and producers. This is what separates decriminalization from legalization.
2,020
<h4>LEGAL IN THE US as a mandate of the plan- if they don’t change the CSA, they can’t be topical</h4><p><strong>Jackson et al 2011</strong> (Ashlee Jackson, Chad Murray, Amanda C. Miralrío, Nicolas Eiden, Second-year Master’s students at the George Washington University Elliott School of International Affairs, Inter-American Drug Abuse Control Commission: Capstone Report, Mexican Drug Trafficking Organizations and Marijuana: The Potential Effects of U.S. Legalization, https://elliott.gwu.edu/sites/elliott.gwu.edu/files/downloads/acad/lahs/mexico-marijuana-071111.pdf)</p><p>Any white paper that includes a policy review of drug legislation must include key term definitions that are clear, accurate, and coherent. Thus, there are various definitions of „legalization‟ of marijuana use and commerce strewn across countless reports, papers and analyses of drug policy. It is critical to note that <u>legalization and decriminalization are terms for <strong>very different proposals</strong> even though they are sometimes conflated</u>. <u>Decriminalization proposes the removal of the criminal penalty for possession of marijuana, but not for its trafficking and production</u>. <u>„<mark>Legalization‟ <strong>authorizes the possession, production and trafficking of marijuana</strong></mark>, and therefore enables the state to tax and regulate its sale and consumption</u>.4 This study takes a holistic approach to examining how legalization of marijuana in the United States would affect Mexican DTOs. However, in the United States there has been no example of true marijuana legalization since the inception of the modern drug control regime. This is why our case studies will look at changes that occurred after various countries relaxed their system of marijuana prohibition. We will look at decriminalization in Mexico and Portugal, as well as a special case of toleration/de facto legalization in the Netherlands. However, we will first lay out in detail what each type of change entails. Decriminalization is one of the most common methods employed by countries that seek to ease or lighten anti-marijuana policies. <u>A common <mark>definition of</mark> <mark>decriminalization</mark> <mark>is</mark> “the removal of the criminal sanction for possession,” in effect <mark>making the penalty for the possession of marijuana</mark> a <mark>civil</u></mark> (fines, counseling etc), <u><mark>rather than criminal</mark> offense</u>. 5 One common example of this type of reform is the 2001 Law 30/2000 in Portugal. <u>What is important here is that criminal penalties for possession are removed, but th<mark>ere is still some type of civil sanction in place</mark> that punishes both users and producers.</u> <u><strong><mark>This is what separates decriminalization from legalization</strong></mark>.</p></u>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,568
11
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,089
Legalize means removing from the books
Heaps & Swartz 1994
Melody M. Heaps & James A. Swartz 1994 (Heapsis the founder and president of Treatment Alternative for Special Clients, Ph.D, Swartz is presently Director of Research at the Illinois Treatment Alternative for Special Clients (TASC) program and an associate faculty member of the Illinois School of Professional Psychology. University of Chicago Legal Forum 1994 1994 U Chi Legal F 175 ARTICLE: TOWARD A RATIONAL DRUG POLICY: SETTING NEW PRIORITIES)
Legalization is removing or repealing statutory proscriptions entirely possessing marijuana becomes legal under the rubric of legalization
Legalization is removing statutory proscriptions entirely possessing marijuana becomes legal under the rubric
n7 The term "decriminalization" should not be mistaken as being equivalent to "legalization." As Professor Kraska has written (albeit in an article that ultimately argues against decriminalization): The terms "decriminalization" and "legalization" are often confused. Decriminalization is the reduction in severity of a criminal offense and the penalty associated with that offense. Marijuana possession, for instance, might be decriminalized from a felony offense to a misdemeanor. Legalization, on the other hand, is exactly what the word implies: removing or repealing statutory proscriptions entirely. To wit, possessing marijuana, once a criminal offense, becomes legal under the rubric of legalization.
712
<h4>Legalize means <u>removing from the books</h4><p></u>Melody M. <strong>Heaps &</strong> James A. <strong>Swartz 1994</strong> (Heapsis the founder and president of Treatment Alternative for Special Clients, Ph.D, Swartz is presently Director of Research at the Illinois Treatment Alternative for Special Clients (TASC) program and an associate faculty member of the Illinois School of Professional Psychology. University of Chicago Legal Forum 1994 1994 U Chi Legal F 175 ARTICLE: TOWARD A RATIONAL DRUG POLICY: SETTING NEW PRIORITIES)</p><p>n7 The term "decriminalization" should not be mistaken as being equivalent to "legalization." As Professor Kraska has written (albeit in an article that ultimately argues against decriminalization): The terms "decriminalization" and "legalization" are often confused. Decriminalization is the reduction in severity of a criminal offense and the penalty associated with that offense. Marijuana possession, for instance, might be decriminalized from a felony offense to a misdemeanor. <u><mark>Legalization</u></mark>, on the other hand, <u><mark>is</u></mark> exactly what the word implies: <u><strong><mark>removing</mark> or repealing <mark>statutory proscriptions entirely</u></strong></mark>. To wit, <u><mark>possessing marijuana</u></mark>, once a criminal offense, <u><mark>becomes legal under the rubric</mark> of legalization</u>.</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,569
12
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,090
States can’t legalize
Kleiman 2010
Kleiman 2010 (Mark Kleiman is professor of public policy at UCLA and the editor of the Journal of Drug Policy Analysis, “California can't legalize marijuana” Los Angeles Times, 7/16, http://articles.latimes.com/2010/jul/16/opinion/la-oe-kleiman-marijuna-legalization-20100714)
There's one problem with legalizing at the state level: It can't be done The C S A makes it a felony to grow or sell cannabis. California can repeal its own marijuana laws But it can't legalize a federal felony.
There's one problem with legalizing at the state level: It can't be done. The C S A makes it a felony California can repeal its own marijuana laws But it can't legalize a felony
There's one problem with legalizing, taxing and regulating cannabis at the state level: It can't be done. The federal Controlled Substances Act makes it a felony to grow or sell cannabis. California can repeal its own marijuana laws, leaving enforcement to the feds. But it can't legalize a federal felony. Therefore, any grower or seller paying California taxes on marijuana sales or filing pot-related California regulatory paperwork would be confessing, in writing, to multiple federal crimes. And that won't happen.
519
<h4>States can’t legalize</h4><p><strong>Kleiman 2010 </strong>(Mark Kleiman is professor of public policy at UCLA and the editor of the Journal of Drug Policy Analysis, “California can't legalize marijuana” Los Angeles Times, 7/16, http://articles.latimes.com/2010/jul/16/opinion/la-oe-kleiman-marijuna-legalization-20100714)</p><p><u><mark>There's one problem with legalizing</u></mark>, taxing and regulating cannabis <u><mark>at the state level: It <strong>can't be done</u></strong>. <u>The</u></mark> federal <u><mark>C</u></mark>ontrolled <u><mark>S</u></mark>ubstances <u><mark>A</u></mark>ct <u><mark>makes it a felony</mark> to grow or sell cannabis. <mark>California can repeal its own marijuana laws</u></mark>, leaving enforcement to the feds. <u><mark>But it can't legalize a</mark> federal <mark>felony</mark>.</u> Therefore, any grower or seller paying California taxes on marijuana sales or filing pot-related California regulatory paperwork would be confessing, in writing, to multiple federal crimes. And that won't happen.</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,570
12
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,091
“Clear statement” ruling solves- avoids commandeering and prevents Congressional reauthorization
Schwartz 2013
Schwartz 2013 (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)
political safeguards proponents should insist on a clear statement rule against commandeering By throwing the federalism issue back to Congress, they require Congress to engage in dialogue about the proper federal/state policymaking balance By requiring clarity and explicitness when state autonomy will be curtailed by a federal law, the clear statement requirement forces Congress to give notice to potential opponents of a bill who might not otherwise have coalesced. they promote the working of the political safeguards and deter political process failure they may be of greater practical significance in protecting state autonomy than splashier, but less frequently applied categorical constitutional rules The difficulties in enacting legislation and the increased drafting costs in following the clear statement rule may mean that Congress will not ultimately amend the law to make the clear statement Given a statute's silence on any intent to commandeer state officials, there is no way for the Court to "defer" to a congressional choice when Congress has not made a choice. the commandeering of state officials would represent a significant judicial choice of legislative means Commandeering hundreds of thousands of police officers and thousands of state prosecutors to enforce federal law is a major step that Congress may or may not have considered. Its absence from the CSA means that the question did not undergo the rigors of the political process Given the political checks and vetoes that would face an effort today to amend the CSA to commandeer state officials a decision by politically-insulated courts to read commandeering into the statute would actively promote a major failure of the political safeguards of federalism. Here legislation creates a federalism problem, and is thus a continuing focal point, but my argument focuses on a doctrinal, rather than legislative solution Congress simply did not take a position in the CSA on whether state officials had to enforce the federal law irrespective of contrary state policies. Imposing a clear statement rule against commandeering thus does not check the power of Congress - because that power wasn't exercised - so much as it checks the power of the courts
a clear statement rule against commandeering require Congress to engage in dialogue about the proper federal/state policymaking balance forces Congress to give notice to potential opponents of a bill who might not otherwise have coalesced they promote the working of the political safeguards and deter political process failure. be of greater practical significance in protecting state autonomy than categorical constitutional rules difficulties in enacting legislation and the increased drafting costs in following the clear statement rule mean that Congress will not ultimately amend the law to make the clear statement. Given a statute's silence on any intent to commandeer state officials, there is no way for the Court to "defer" the commandeering of state officials would represent a significant judicial choice Commandeering absence from the CSA means that the question did not undergo the rigors of the political process. Given the political checks and vetoes that would face an effort today to amend the CSA to commandeer state officials a decision by politically-insulated courts to read commandeering into the statute would actively promote a major failure of the political safeguards of federalism . Imposing a clear statement rule it checks the power of the court
Of course, Young's argument still doesn't provide a convincing reason why an adherent of the political safeguards of federalism should prefer that the anti-commandeering doctrine be a "hard" and categorical constitutional rule rather than a "softer" clear statement rule. Externalizing regulatory costs may be a bad thing, but if Congress has put such cost externalization clearly on the political agenda, and passed the various legislative "veto gates," the political safeguard proponent might still be satisfied. Nevertheless, political safeguards proponents should insist on a clear statement rule against commandeering. As Young argues, clear statement rules have numerous advantages that should appeal to political safeguard proponents. n241 By throwing the federalism issue back to Congress, they require Congress to engage in dialogue about the proper federal/state policymaking balance. By requiring clarity and explicitness when state autonomy will be curtailed by a federal law, the clear statement requirement forces Congress to give notice to potential opponents of a bill who might not otherwise have coalesced. Thus, they promote the working of the political safeguards and deter political [*634] process failure. Although clear statement rules avoid direct confrontations between the courts and the political branches over the limits of their power, they may be of greater practical significance in protecting state autonomy than splashier, but less frequently applied categorical constitutional rules. The difficulties in enacting legislation and the increased drafting costs in following the clear statement rule may mean that Congress will not ultimately amend the law to make the clear statement. n242 As the Court stated in Gregory: Inasmuch as this Court in Garcia has left primarily to the political process the protection of the States against intrusive exercises of Congress' Commerce Clause powers, we must be absolutely certain that Congress intended such an exercise. "To give the state-displacing weight of federal law to mere congressional ambiguity would evade the very procedure for lawmaking on which Garcia relied to protect states' interests." n243 The problem addressed by the clear statement rule is not a pedantic or formalistic insistence on clarity, but rather a concern to ensure that the political safeguards have in fact functioned. As the Court has repeatedly observed, applying the clear statement rule to legislation affecting the federalism balance "assures that the legislature has in fact faced, and intended to bring into issue, the critical matters involved in the judicial decision." n244 All of these advantages of clear statement rules are present in the anti-commandeering clear statement rule. Both sides of the federalism debate should agree on a rigorous clear statement rule. For proponents of judicially enforced federalism, the reason is obvious: Commandeering restructures state governments contrary to the constitution and statutes of the state. But proponents of the political safeguards theory should also prefer the clear statement rule because judicially inferred commandeering-by-preemption represents a serious political process failure. There is yet a further reason. Given a statute's silence on any intent to commandeer state officials, there is no way for the Court to "defer" to a congressional choice when Congress has not made a choice. Here, the commandeering of state officials would represent a significant judicial choice of legislative means. For a court to infer commandeering from a silent statute - based on its purpose or even legislative history - would represent a dramatic judicial intervention in the choice of legislative means. Put another way, the political process failure of commandeering [*635] through silence or ambiguity does not materialize unless and until a court infers commandeering. The CSA illustrates these issues plainly. Commandeering hundreds of thousands of police officers and thousands of state prosecutors to enforce federal law is a major step that Congress may or may not have considered. Its absence from the CSA means that the question did not undergo the rigors of the political process. Given the political checks and vetoes that would face an effort today to amend the CSA to commandeer state officials, a decision by politically-insulated courts to read commandeering into the statute would actively promote a major failure of the political safeguards of federalism. Too often in discussions of federalism, courts flit in and out of view, sprite-like. But when discussing federalism "doctrine," - in this Article, the difficulties in reconciling preemption and anti-commandeering doctrine in particular - we are talking about judge-made law, not legal authority external to courts. Here legislation creates a federalism problem, and is thus a continuing focal point, but my argument focuses on a doctrinal, rather than legislative solution. And what we call "doctrine" is at bottom an exercise of judicial power. The anti-commandeering doctrine is a judicial check on federal legislative power; preemption has elements of both an assertion of federal legislative and judicial power. The clarity with which Congress states an intention to preempt state law varies along a spectrum, both in terms of the linguistic clarity of the statute itself and the degree to which specific applications have or have not been contemplated in the statute. The less clear the preemptive intent, the more a court gains latitude to impose its own idea of policy. Congress simply did not take a position in the CSA on whether state officials had to enforce the federal law irrespective of contrary state policies. Imposing a clear statement rule against commandeering thus does not check the power of Congress - because that power wasn't exercised - so much as it checks the power of the courts. There can be, but need not be, a hard constitutional anti-commandeering rule standing behind the clear statement rule; were Congress to expressly commandeer state officials, the presumption would be overcome and only then would the exercise of judicial review power be truly at issue. In the meantime, the anti-commandeering clear statement rule limits the power of courts, by preventing them under the cloak of statutory interpretation, from undertaking a potentially major initiative in federal drug policy.
6,405
<h4>“Clear statement” ruling solves- avoids commandeering and prevents Congressional reauthorization</h4><p><strong>Schwartz 2013</strong> (David, Foley & Lardner-Bascom Professor of Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, High Federalism: Marijuana Legalization and the Limits of Federal Power to Regulate States, 35 Cardozo L. Rev. 567, December, lexis)</p><p>Of course, Young's argument still doesn't provide a convincing reason why an adherent of the political safeguards of federalism should prefer that the anti-commandeering doctrine be a "hard" and categorical constitutional rule rather than a "softer" clear statement rule. Externalizing regulatory costs may be a bad thing, but if Congress has put such cost externalization clearly on the political agenda, and passed the various legislative "veto gates," the political safeguard proponent might still be satisfied. Nevertheless, <u>political safeguards proponents should insist on <mark>a clear statement rule against commandeering</u></mark>. As Young argues, clear statement rules have numerous advantages that should appeal to political safeguard proponents. n241 <u>By throwing the federalism issue back to Congress, they <mark>require Congress to engage in dialogue about the proper federal/state policymaking balance</u></mark>. <u>By requiring clarity and explicitness when state autonomy will be curtailed by a federal law, the clear statement requirement <mark>forces Congress to give notice to potential opponents of a bill who might not otherwise have coalesced</mark>.</u> Thus, <u><mark>they promote the working of the political safeguards and deter political</u></mark> [*634] <u><mark>process failure</u>.</mark> Although clear statement rules avoid direct confrontations between the courts and the political branches over the limits of their power, <u>they may <mark>be of greater practical significance in protecting state autonomy than</mark> splashier, but less frequently applied <mark>categorical constitutional</mark> <mark>rules</u></mark>. <u>The <mark>difficulties in enacting legislation and the increased drafting costs in following the clear statement rule</mark> may <mark>mean that <strong>Congress will not ultimately amend the law to make the clear statement</u></strong>.</mark> n242 As the Court stated in Gregory: Inasmuch as this Court in Garcia has left primarily to the political process the protection of the States against intrusive exercises of Congress' Commerce Clause powers, we must be absolutely certain that Congress intended such an exercise. "To give the state-displacing weight of federal law to mere congressional ambiguity would evade the very procedure for lawmaking on which Garcia relied to protect states' interests." n243 The problem addressed by the clear statement rule is not a pedantic or formalistic insistence on clarity, but rather a concern to ensure that the political safeguards have in fact functioned. As the Court has repeatedly observed, applying the clear statement rule to legislation affecting the federalism balance "assures that the legislature has in fact faced, and intended to bring into issue, the critical matters involved in the judicial decision." n244 All of these advantages of clear statement rules are present in the anti-commandeering clear statement rule. Both sides of the federalism debate should agree on a rigorous clear statement rule. For proponents of judicially enforced federalism, the reason is obvious: Commandeering restructures state governments contrary to the constitution and statutes of the state. But proponents of the political safeguards theory should also prefer the clear statement rule because judicially inferred commandeering-by-preemption represents a serious political process failure. There is yet a further reason. <u><mark>Given a statute's silence on any intent to commandeer state officials, there is no way for the Court to "defer"</mark> to a congressional choice when Congress has not made a choice.</u> Here, <u><mark>the commandeering of state officials would represent a significant judicial choice</mark> of legislative means</u>. For a court to infer commandeering from a silent statute - based on its purpose or even legislative history - would represent a dramatic judicial intervention in the choice of legislative means. Put another way, the political process failure of commandeering [*635] through silence or ambiguity does not materialize unless and until a court infers commandeering. The CSA illustrates these issues plainly. <u><mark>Commandeering</mark> hundreds of thousands of police officers and thousands of state prosecutors to enforce federal law is a major step that Congress may or may not have considered. Its <mark>absence from the CSA means that the question did not undergo the rigors of the political process</u>. <u><strong>Given the political checks and vetoes that would face an effort today to amend the CSA to commandeer state officials</u></strong></mark>, <u><mark>a decision by politically-insulated courts to read commandeering into the statute would actively promote a major failure of the political safeguards of federalism</mark>. </u>Too often in discussions of federalism, courts flit in and out of view, sprite-like. But when discussing federalism "doctrine," - in this Article, the difficulties in reconciling preemption and anti-commandeering doctrine in particular - we are talking about judge-made law, not legal authority external to courts. <u>Here legislation creates a federalism problem, and is thus a continuing focal point, but my argument focuses on a doctrinal, rather than legislative solution</u>. And what we call "doctrine" is at bottom an exercise of judicial power. The anti-commandeering doctrine is a judicial check on federal legislative power; preemption has elements of both an assertion of federal legislative and judicial power. The clarity with which Congress states an intention to preempt state law varies along a spectrum, both in terms of the linguistic clarity of the statute itself and the degree to which specific applications have or have not been contemplated in the statute. The less clear the preemptive intent, the more a court gains latitude to impose its own idea of policy. <u>Congress simply did not take a position in the CSA on whether state officials had to enforce the federal law irrespective of contrary state policies<mark>. Imposing a clear statement rule</mark> against commandeering thus does not check the power of Congress - because that power wasn't exercised - so much as <mark>it checks the power of the court</mark>s</u>. There can be, but need not be, a hard constitutional anti-commandeering rule standing behind the clear statement rule; were Congress to expressly commandeer state officials, the presumption would be overcome and only then would the exercise of judicial review power be truly at issue. In the meantime, the anti-commandeering clear statement rule limits the power of courts, by preventing them under the cloak of statutory interpretation, from undertaking a potentially major initiative in federal drug policy.</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,571
9
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,092
Their ev’s from March—squo solved
Walker, 14
Walker, 14 (Hunter, “The FBI Can’t Hire Cyber Security Recruits Because They All Smoke Weed” Slate, 5/21, http://www.slate.com/blogs/business_insider/2014/05/21/fbi_director_james_comey_has_trouble_recruiting_it_savvy_workers_because.html)
FBI Director Comey discussed how the bureau's pot prohibition was making it harder to find tech savvy recruits the bureau is already relaxing its restrictions on marijuana Comey said they "should go ahead and apply" in spite of their marijuana smoking
Comey discussed how the bureau's pot prohibition was making it harder to find tech savvy recruits the bureau is already relaxing its restrictions on marijuana Comey said they "should go ahead and apply" in spite of marijuana smoking.
FBI Director James Comey is starting to think the law enforcement agency's zero tolerance policy on marijuana might be, like, a total bummer. According to the Wall Street Journal, Comey discussed how the bureau's pot prohibition was making it harder to find tech savvy recruits when he spoke to the annual White Collar Crime Institute conference Monday. "I have to hire a great work force to compete with those cyber criminals and some of those kids want to smoke weed on the way to the interview," Comey said. As a result of this, Comey said the FBI is "grappling with the question right now" of whether or not to change its marijuana policy. Currently, the agency will not accept job applicants who have smoked pot at any point within the past three years. In fact, Comey indicated the bureau is already relaxing its restrictions on marijuana. When one attendee at the conference said one of their friends was discouraged from trying to work at the FBI due to the pot policy, Comey said they "should go ahead and apply" in spite of their marijuana smoking.
1,058
<h4>Their ev’s from March—squo solved</h4><p><strong>Walker, 14 </strong>(Hunter, “The FBI Can’t Hire Cyber Security Recruits Because They All Smoke Weed” Slate, 5/21, http://www.slate.com/blogs/business_insider/2014/05/21/fbi_director_james_comey_has_trouble_recruiting_it_savvy_workers_because.html)</p><p><u>FBI Director</u> James <u><mark>Comey</u></mark> is starting to think the law enforcement agency's zero tolerance policy on marijuana might be, like, a total bummer.</p><p>According to the Wall Street Journal, Comey <u><mark>discussed how the bureau's pot prohibition was making it harder to find tech savvy recruits</u></mark> when he spoke to the annual White Collar Crime Institute conference Monday.</p><p>"I have to hire a great work force to compete with those cyber criminals and some of those kids want to smoke weed on the way to the interview," Comey said.</p><p>As a result of this, Comey said the FBI is "grappling with the question right now" of whether or not to change its marijuana policy. Currently, the agency will not accept job applicants who have smoked pot at any point within the past three years.</p><p>In fact, Comey indicated <u><strong><mark>the bureau is already relaxing its restrictions on marijuana</u></strong></mark>. When one attendee at the conference said one of their friends was discouraged from trying to work at the FBI due to the pot policy, <u><mark>Comey said they "should go ahead and apply" in spite of</mark> their <mark>marijuana smoking</u>.</mark> </p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,572
15
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,093
Salaries and retention are key alt causes- outweighs the aff
Washington Post 10/1
Washington Post 10/1/2014 (Key Homeland Security official urges passage of cybersecurity bill, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/federal-eye/wp/2014/10/01/key-homeland-security-official-urges-passage-of-cybersecurity-bill/)
A top Homeland Security official called on Congress to pass cybersecurity legislation, saying there is a “dire need the department’s “labrynthine” hiring processes often prevents it from grabbing top recruits the government can’t match higher private sector salaries. We have a difficult time competing with the private sector because of financial realities DHS has had major difficulties in not only hiring cyber officials but retaining them once they arrive. A parade of high-level cyber departures in recent years has helped slow the rollout of key cybersecurity initiatives
null
A top Department of Homeland Security official on Wednesday called on Congress to pass cybersecurity legislation, saying there is a “dire need” to strengthen the department’s ability to defend against cyberattacks. Deputy Secretary Alejandro Mayorkas said the legislation would “better equip us” to fight computer hackers and state-sponsored cyberattacks and is especially important in helping DHS compete with private industry to recruit top cyber personnel. He said the department’s “labrynthine” hiring processes often prevents it from grabbing top recruits and that the government can’t match higher private sector salaries. “We have a difficult time competing with the private sector because of financial realities,’’ Mayorkas said at The Washington Post’s Cybersecurity Summitt 2014, held at the Post building in the District. “On the other hand, we are advantaged because … our mission is an extraordinary one.’’ Homeland Security logo reflected in the eyeglasses of a cybersecurity analyst at the agency’s secretive cyber defense facility in Idaho. (Mark J. Terrill/AP). Congress has been struggling for years to pass cybersecurity legislation, even as law enforcement officials have said cyberattacks increasingly pose the biggest threat to the nation’s security. A comprehensive bill to establish cybersecurity standards died in 2012, but several pieces of legislation are now pending in Congress. One bill that recently passed the House would require a DHS strategy to recruit and keep cyber personnel. Congressional aides from both parties have said in recent days that they are hoping to reach agreement on a comprehensive cyber bill to be voted on during Congress’s lame-duck session after November’s midterm elections. DHS has had major difficulties in not only hiring cyber officials but retaining them once they arrive. A parade of high-level cyber departures in recent years has helped slow the rollout of key cybersecurity initiatives, including a program aimed at blocking malicious software before it can infiltrate civilian government computers, former officials have said. Mayorkas said he and Homeland Security Secretary Jeh Johnson are focused on the problem, pointing out that Johnson personally went on a trip in February to Georgia Institute of Technology and Morehouse College aimed at recruiting young cyber leaders. While Mayorkas said “attackers are in fact becoming more and more sophisticated,’’ he added that DHS and the rest of the government are up to the challenge of stopping them. “Our prevention capabilities are growing in sophistication,’’ he said.
2,591
<h4>Salaries and retention are key alt causes- outweighs the aff</h4><p><strong>Washington Post 10/1</strong>/2014 (Key Homeland Security official urges passage of cybersecurity bill, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/federal-eye/wp/2014/10/01/key-homeland-security-official-urges-passage-of-cybersecurity-bill/)</p><p><u>A top</u> Department of <u>Homeland Security official</u> on Wednesday <u>called on Congress to pass cybersecurity legislation, saying there is a “dire need</u>” to strengthen the department’s ability to defend against cyberattacks. Deputy Secretary Alejandro Mayorkas said the legislation would “better equip us” to fight computer hackers and state-sponsored cyberattacks and is especially important in helping DHS compete with private industry to recruit top cyber personnel. He said <u>the department’s “labrynthine” hiring processes often prevents it from grabbing top recruits</u> and that <u><strong>the government can’t match higher private sector salaries. </u></strong>“<u>We have a difficult time competing with the private sector</u> <u>because of financial realities</u>,’’ Mayorkas said at The Washington Post’s Cybersecurity Summitt 2014, held at the Post building in the District. “On the other hand, we are advantaged because … our mission is an extraordinary one.’’ Homeland Security logo reflected in the eyeglasses of a cybersecurity analyst at the agency’s secretive cyber defense facility in Idaho. (Mark J. Terrill/AP). Congress has been struggling for years to pass cybersecurity legislation, even as law enforcement officials have said cyberattacks increasingly pose the biggest threat to the nation’s security. A comprehensive bill to establish cybersecurity standards died in 2012, but several pieces of legislation are now pending in Congress. One bill that recently passed the House would require a DHS strategy to recruit and keep cyber personnel. Congressional aides from both parties have said in recent days that they are hoping to reach agreement on a comprehensive cyber bill to be voted on during Congress’s lame-duck session after November’s midterm elections. <u>DHS has had major difficulties in not only hiring cyber officials but <strong>retaining them</strong> once they arrive.</u> <u>A parade of high-level cyber departures in recent years has helped <strong>slow the rollout of key cybersecurity initiatives</u></strong>, including a program aimed at blocking malicious software before it can infiltrate civilian government computers, former officials have said. Mayorkas said he and Homeland Security Secretary Jeh Johnson are focused on the problem, pointing out that Johnson personally went on a trip in February to Georgia Institute of Technology and Morehouse College aimed at recruiting young cyber leaders. While Mayorkas said “attackers are in fact becoming more and more sophisticated,’’ he added that DHS and the rest of the government are up to the challenge of stopping them. “Our prevention capabilities are growing in sophistication,’’ he said.</p>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,574
7
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,094
No cyber impact—Korea attack proves and no ev anyone has will and capability to shut down the US military…
null
null
null
null
null
null
<h4>No cyber impact—Korea attack proves and no ev anyone has will and capability to shut down the US military…</h4>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,573
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,095
No cyber war – deterrence.
Lewis 11
Lewis 11 [Project Director James A. Lewis January 2011 a report of the csis commission on cybersecurity for the 44th presidency Cybersecurity Two Years Later Commission Cochairs Representative James R. Langevin Representative Michael T. McCaul Scott Charney Lt. General Harry Raduege, USAF (ret.) http://csis.org/files/publication/110128_Lewis_CybersecurityTwoYearsLater_Web.pdf]
we are not engaged in a cyber war nation-states are unlikely to launch cyber attacks against the U S The political risk is too high. Just as with missiles and aircraft, countries can strike the U S using cyber attack, but they know this would trigger a violent if not devastating response. The risks are too high for frivolous engagement.
we are not engaged in a cyber war nation-states are unlikely to launch cyber attacks against the U S The political risk is too high. Just as with missiles and aircraft, countries can strike the U S using cyber attack, but they know this would trigger a devastating response risks are too high for frivolous engagement.
However, we are not engaged in a cyber war. Short of armed conflict, nation-states are unlikely to launch cyber attacks against the United States. The political risk is too high. Just as with missiles and aircraft, countries can strike the United States using cyber attack, but they know this would trigger a violent if not devastating response. The risks are too high for frivolous engagement.
397
<h4>No cyber war – deterrence.</h4><p><u><strong>Lewis 11</u></strong> [Project Director James A. Lewis January 2011 a report of the csis commission on cybersecurity for the 44th presidency Cybersecurity Two Years Later Commission Cochairs Representative James R. Langevin Representative Michael T. McCaul Scott Charney Lt. General Harry Raduege, USAF (ret.) http://csis.org/files/publication/110128_Lewis_CybersecurityTwoYearsLater_Web.pdf<u>]</p><p></u>However, <u><mark>we are not engaged in a cyber war</u></mark>. Short of armed conflict, <u><mark>nation-states are unlikely to launch cyber attacks against the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates. <u><strong><mark>The political risk is too high.</strong></mark> <mark>Just as with missiles and aircraft, countries can strike the U</u></mark>nited <u><mark>S</u></mark>tates <u><mark>using cyber attack, but they know this would trigger a</mark> violent if not <mark>devastating response</mark>. The <mark>risks are too high for frivolous engagement.</p></u></mark>
null
null
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
423,520
2
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,096
Israeli strike draws in great powers – causes miscalc and escalation
Trabanco, 09 – Independent researcher of geopoltical and military affairs (1/13/09, José Miguel Alonso Trabanco, “The Middle Eastern Powder Keg Can Explode at anytime,” **http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=11762**)
Trabanco, 09 – Independent researcher of geopoltical and military affairs (1/13/09, José Miguel Alonso Trabanco, “The Middle Eastern Powder Keg Can Explode at anytime,” **http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=11762**)
In case of an Israeli attack Iran will certainly respond A countermeasure would be to fire Persian ballistic missiles against Israel and against American military bases Teheran will resort to its proxies like Hamas or Hezbollah to carry out attacks against Israel, America and their allies setting in flames a large portion of the Middle East. The disposal is to block the Strait of Hormuz that would dramatically increase the price of oil, this a very threatening retaliation because it will bring intense financial and economic havoc upon the West, the necessary conditions for a major war in the Middle East are given. Such conflict could rapidly spiral out of control and thus a relatively minor clash could quickly and dangerously escalate by engulfing the whole region and perhaps even beyond great powers could become involved America, Russia, Europe, China ny miscalculation by any of the main protagonists can trigger something no one can stop. Taking into consideration that the stakes are too high, perhaps it is not wise to be playing with fire right in the middle of a powder keg.
In case of an Israeli attack Iran will respond. A countermeasure would be to fire ballistic missiles against Israel and against American military bases Teheran will resort to its proxies like Hamas or Hezbollah setting in flames the Middle East. The disposal is to block the Strait of Hormuz that would increase the price of oil the necessary conditions for a major war in the Middle East are given. Such conflict could rapidly spiral out of control and thus a relatively minor clash could quickly and dangerously escalate great powers could become involved America, Russia, Europe, China any miscalculation can trigger something no one can stop
In case of an Israeli and/or American attack against Iran, Ahmadinejad's government will certainly respond. A possible countermeasure would be to fire Persian ballistic missiles against Israel and maybe even against American military bases in the regions. Teheran will unquestionably resort to its proxies like Hamas or Hezbollah (or even some of its Shiite allies it has in Lebanon or Saudi Arabia) to carry out attacks against Israel, America and their allies, effectively setting in flames a large portion of the Middle East. The ultimate weapon at Iranian disposal is to block the Strait of Hormuz. If such chokepoint is indeed asphyxiated, that would dramatically increase the price of oil, this a very threatening retaliation because it will bring intense financial and economic havoc upon the West, which is already facing significant trouble in those respects. In short, the necessary conditions for a major war in the Middle East are given. Such conflict could rapidly spiral out of control and thus a relatively minor clash could quickly and dangerously escalate by engulfing the whole region and perhaps even beyond. There are many key players: the Israelis, the Palestinians, the Arabs, the Persians and their respective allies and some great powers could become involved in one way or another (America, Russia, Europe, China). Therefore, any miscalculation by any of the main protagonists can trigger something no one can stop. Taking into consideration that the stakes are too high, perhaps it is not wise to be playing with fire right in the middle of a powder keg.
1,580
<h4>Israeli strike draws in great powers – causes miscalc<strong> and escalation</h4><p><u>Trabanco, 09</u> – Independent researcher of geopoltical and military affairs (1/13/09, José Miguel Alonso Trabanco, “The Middle Eastern Powder Keg Can Explode at anytime,”</strong> <u><strong>**http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=11762**)</p><p></strong><mark>In case of an Israeli</u></mark> and/or American <u><mark>attack</u></mark> against <u><mark>Iran</u></mark>, Ahmadinejad's government <u><mark>will</mark> certainly <mark>respond</u>. <u>A</mark> </u>possible <u><mark>countermeasure would be to fire</mark> Persian <mark>ballistic missiles against Israel and</u></mark> maybe even <u><mark>against American military bases</u></mark> in the regions. <u><mark>Teheran will</u></mark> unquestionably <u><mark>resort to its proxies like Hamas or Hezbollah</u></mark> (or even some of its Shiite allies it has in Lebanon or Saudi Arabia) <u>to carry out attacks against Israel, America and their allies</u>, effectively <u><mark>setting in flames</mark> a large portion of <mark>the</mark> <mark>Middle East. The</u></mark> ultimate weapon at Iranian <u><mark>disposal is to block the Strait of Hormuz</u></mark>. If such chokepoint is indeed asphyxiated, <u><mark>that</mark> <mark>would</mark> dramatically <mark>increase the price of oil</mark>, this a</u> <u>very threatening retaliation because it will bring intense financial and economic havoc</u> <u>upon the West,</u> which is already facing significant trouble in those respects. In short, <u><mark>the necessary conditions for <strong>a</mark> <mark>major war</strong> in the Middle East are given.</u> <u>Such conflict could rapidly spiral out of control and thus a</u> <u>relatively minor</mark> <mark>clash could quickly and dangerously escalate</mark> by engulfing the whole region and perhaps even beyond</u>. There are many key players: the Israelis, the Palestinians, the Arabs, the Persians and their respective allies and some <u><mark>great powers</mark> <mark>could become involved</u></mark> in one way or another (<u><mark>America, Russia, Europe, China</u></mark>). Therefore, <mark>a<u>ny miscalculation</mark> by any of the main protagonists <mark>can trigger something no one can stop</mark>. Taking into consideration that the stakes are too high, perhaps it is not wise to be playing with fire right in the middle of a powder keg.</p></u>
1nr
Ov
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
70,300
29
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,097
Turns conflict with Russia and China
PressTV 13
PressTV 13
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in months should the world powers fail to reach a nuclear deal with Iran If the talks fail then there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran before Obama leaves office The United States could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other and those are the kinds of conditions that can lead to miscalculation we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons failure in talks with Iran could lead to war
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in months should the world powers fail to reach a deal with Iran If the talks fail there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran The U S could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other those conditions can lead to miscalculation
Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail, 11/13/13, http://www.presstv.ir/detail/2013/11/13/334544/global-nuclear-war-likely-if-iran-talks-fail/ A global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in the coming months should the world powers fail to reach a nuclear deal with Iran, an American analyst says.¶ “If the talks fail, if the agreements being pursued are not successfully carried forward and implemented, then there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran before [US President Barack] Obama leaves office and that’s a very great danger that no one can underestimate the importance of,” senior editor at the Executive Intelligence Review Jeff Steinberg told Press TV on Wednesday. ¶ “The United States could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other and those are the kinds of conditions that can lead to miscalculation and general roar,” Steinberg said. ¶ “So the danger in this situation is that if these talks don’t go forward, we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months and years and that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons,” he warned. ¶ The warning came one day after the White House told Congress not to impose new sanctions against Tehran because failure in talks with Iran could lead to war.
1,431
<h4><strong>Turns conflict with Russia and China</h4><p>PressTV 13</p><p><u></strong><mark>Global nuclear conflict between US, Russia, China likely if Iran talks fail</u></mark>, 11/13/13, http://www.presstv.ir/detail/2013/11/13/334544/global-nuclear-war-likely-if-iran-talks-fail/ <u><mark>A <strong>global conflict between the US, Russia, and China is likely in </u></strong></mark>the coming<u><strong><mark> months should the world powers fail to reach a</mark> nuclear <mark>deal with Iran</u></strong></mark>, an American analyst says.¶ “<u><mark>If the talks fail</u></mark>, if the agreements being pursued are not successfully carried forward and implemented, <u>then <mark>there would be enormous international pressure to drive towards a conflict with Iran</mark> before</u> [US President Barack] <u>Obama leaves office</u> and that’s a very great danger that no one can underestimate the importance of,” senior editor at the Executive Intelligence Review Jeff Steinberg told Press TV on Wednesday. ¶ “<u><mark>The U</mark>nited <mark>S</mark>tates <mark>could find itself on one side and Russia and China on the other</mark> and <mark>those</mark> are the kinds of <mark>conditions</mark> that <mark>can <strong>lead to miscalculation</u></strong></mark> and general roar,” Steinberg said. ¶ “So the danger in this situation is that if these talks don’t go forward, <u>we could be facing a global conflict in the coming months</u> and years and <u>that’s got to be avoided at all costs when you’ve got countries like the United States, Russia, and China with” their arsenals of “nuclear weapons</u>,” he warned. ¶ The warning came one day after the White House told Congress not to impose new sanctions against Tehran because <u>failure in talks with Iran could lead to war</u>.</p>
1nr
Ov
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
188,942
22
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,098
Iran prolif jacks US cred—no modeling
Bolton ’11
Bolton, senior fellow – AEI, 4/15/’11
we have confirmation that the regime has the capability to mass-produce critical components for centrifuges used to enrich uranium to weapons-grade levels. That news proves again the inefficacy of U.N. Security Council resolutions and sanctions against a determined adversary. Iran's weapons program proceeds full steam ahead, which emphasizes to would-be proliferators that persistence pays Gadhafi is cursing his timidity. Had he made seven years of progress there would surely be no NATO bombing of his military today. An Iranian nuclear capability would cause Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Turkey and others to seek their own weapons. We would see a region far more unstable and dangerous America's failure to stop Iran which is how it would be perceived would be a substantial blow to U.S. influence in general. Terrorists and state sponsors would see Iran's role and would wonder what they have to lose. even if Iranian economic retaliation
Iran's weapons program proceeds full steam ahead An Iranian nuclear capability would cause Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Turkey and others to seek their own weapons. We would see a region far more unstable and dangerous America's failure to stop Iran's which is how it would be perceived worldwide—would be a substantial blow to U.S. influence in general.
(John, http://www.aei.org/article/103463) Inside Iran, we now have confirmation—thanks to disclosures this month by an Iranian opposition group, which have been confirmed by Iranian officials—that the regime has the capability to mass-produce critical components for centrifuges used to enrich uranium to weapons-grade levels. That news proves again the inefficacy of U.N. Security Council resolutions and sanctions against a determined adversary. Thus Iran's weapons program proceeds full steam ahead, which only emphasizes to would-be proliferators that persistence pays. Moammar Gadhafi surrendered his nuclear weapons program in 2003-04 because he feared becoming the next Saddam Hussein, but he is now undoubtedly cursing his timidity. Had he made seven years of progress toward deliverable nuclear weapons, there would surely be no NATO bombing of his military today. An Iranian nuclear capability would undoubtedly cause Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Turkey and perhaps others to seek their own deliverable nuclear weapons. We would therefore see a region substantially more in Iran's thrall and far more unstable and dangerous for Washington and its allies. Moreover, America's failure to stop Iran's nuclear ambitions—which is certainly how it would be perceived worldwide—would be a substantial blow to U.S. influence in general. Terrorists and their state sponsors would see Iran's unchallenged role as terrorism's leading state sponsor and central banker, and would wonder what they have to lose. Turns Jamaica and Nepal—even if strikes don’t escalate it causes Iranian economic retaliation which cuts the flow of oil – comparatively more important to Jamaican and Nepalese economies than Marijuana because it influences the prices of everything and determines broader exports Independently turns bioterror because Iran would fund terror groups in retaliation
1,862
<h4>Iran prolif jacks US cred—no modeling</h4><p><strong>Bolton</strong>, senior fellow – AEI, 4/15/<strong>’11</p><p></strong>(John, http://www.aei.org/article/103463)</p><p>Inside Iran, <u>we</u> now <u>have confirmation</u>—thanks to disclosures this month by an Iranian opposition group, which have been confirmed by Iranian officials—<u>that the regime has the capability to mass-produce critical components for centrifuges used to enrich uranium to weapons-grade levels. That news proves again the inefficacy of U.N. Security Council resolutions and sanctions against a determined adversary.</p><p></u>Thus <u><mark>Iran's weapons program proceeds full steam ahead</mark>, which</u> only <u>emphasizes to would-be proliferators that persistence pays</u>. Moammar <u>Gadhafi</u> surrendered his nuclear weapons program in 2003-04 because he feared becoming the next Saddam Hussein, but he <u>is</u> now undoubtedly <u>cursing his timidity. Had he made seven years of progress</u> toward deliverable nuclear weapons, <u>there would surely be no NATO bombing of his military today.</p><p><mark>An Iranian nuclear capability would</u></mark> undoubtedly <u><mark>cause Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Turkey and</u></mark> perhaps <u><mark>others to seek their own</u></mark> deliverable nuclear <u><mark>weapons.</u> <u>We would</u></mark> therefore <u><mark>see a</mark> <mark>region</u></mark> substantially more in Iran's thrall and <u><mark>far more unstable and dangerous</u></mark> for Washington and its allies.</p><p>Moreover, <u><mark>America's failure to stop Iran</u>'s</mark> nuclear ambitions—<u><mark>which is</u></mark> certainly <u><mark>how it would be perceived</u> worldwide—<u>would be a <strong>substantial blow</strong> to U.S. influence in general.</mark> Terrorists and</u> their <u>state sponsors would see Iran's</u> unchallenged <u>role</u> as terrorism's leading state sponsor and central banker, <u>and would wonder what they have to lose.</u> </p><p>Turns Jamaica and Nepal—<u>even if</u> strikes don’t escalate it causes <u>Iranian economic retaliation</u> which cuts the flow of oil – comparatively more important to Jamaican and Nepalese economies than Marijuana because it influences the prices of everything and determines broader exports</p><p>Independently turns bioterror because Iran would fund terror groups in retaliation</p>
1nr
Ov
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,575
2
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,099
Yes strikes- and they escalate- prefer recent ev
Guardian 1/1
Guardian 1/1/2015 (Middle East, 2015: further standoffs, tripwires and catastrophes; The jihadist threat of Isis and ongoing Syria disaster will pile pressure on western leaders. Then there's Iran, Turkey, Israel-Palestine and north Africa, lexis)
The Middle East in 2015 features several dangerous tripwires that could tip the region into sudden chaos The most obvious is the standoff over Iran's suspect nuclear programme, which Israel regards as an existential threat. Opinions differ whether a deal can be reached. If it is, Iran could come in from the cold If not the possibility that Israel, led by Netanyahu, will take matters into its own hands and launch military strikes against Iranian nuclear facilities is very real
Middle East in 2015 features several dangerous tripwires that could tip the region into sudden chaos. The most obvious is Iran's nuclear programme, which Israel regards as an existential threat a deal can be reached. If not, the possibility that Israel, led by Binyamin Netanyahu, will take matters into its own hands and launch military strikes against Iranian nuclear facilities is very real
The Middle East in 2015 features several other dangerous tripwires that could tip the region into sudden chaos. The most obvious is the standoff over Iran's suspect nuclear programme, which Israel regards as an existential threat. Long-running talks again ended without agreement in November. A new deadline of July, 2015 has been set. Opinions differ whether a deal can be reached. If it is, Iran could come in from the cold for the first time since 1979. If not, the possibility that Israel, led by prime minister Binyamin Netanyahu, will take matters into its own hands and launch military strikes against Iranian nuclear facilities is very real indeed.
656
<h4><strong>Yes strikes- and they escalate- prefer recent ev</h4><p>Guardian 1/1</strong>/2015 (Middle East, 2015: further standoffs, tripwires and catastrophes; The jihadist threat of Isis and ongoing Syria disaster will pile pressure on western leaders. Then there's Iran, Turkey, Israel-Palestine and north Africa, lexis)</p><p><u>The <mark>Middle East in 2015 features several</u></mark> other <u><mark>dangerous tripwires that could tip the region</mark> <mark>into sudden chaos</u>. <u>The most obvious is</mark> the standoff over <mark>Iran's</mark> suspect <mark>nuclear programme, which Israel regards as an existential threat</mark>.</u> Long-running talks again ended without agreement in November. A new deadline of July, 2015 has been set. <u>Opinions differ whether <mark>a deal can be reached.</mark> If it is, Iran could come in from the cold </u>for the first time since 1979. <u><mark>If not</u>, <u>the possibility that Israel, led by</u></mark> prime minister <mark>Binyamin <u>Netanyahu, will take matters into its own hands and launch military strikes against Iranian nuclear facilities is <strong>very real</u></strong></mark> indeed.</p>
1nr
Strikes
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
430,495
6
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,100
Nuclear exchanges are likely---Iranian prolif uniquely guarantees involvement
Schlosser 14
Eric Schlosser 14, the author of Command and Control: the story of nuclear weapons and the illusion of safety, "Why we must rid the world of nuclear weapons," 11-27-2014, Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/nov/27/nuclear-weapons-near-misses-iran-bomb-peace
simple. An Iran armed with nuclear weapons would pose a grave threat to world peace The fact that a nuclear catastrophe hasn’t occurred since 1945 encourages the belief that it won’t happen That argument reveals nothing about the future Every country that possesses weapons must contend with risks Political instability has been a source of catastrophe. Split-second decision-making has brought the world close to nuclear war countries came up with nuclear weapon designs that were less safe Iran was racked by demonstrations; the “green movement” seeking democracy was violently suppressed. Political instability and nuclear weapons are not a good combination According to Tertrais four of the nine countries that now possess nuclear weapons are “known to have undergone severe political crises Even with the best of intentions and a sincere desire to avoid nuclear war, the complexity of weapons systems the unreliability of communications systems can precipitate disaster Given Iran’s technical, political and leadership challenges its pursuit of nuclear weapons seems an invitation to disaste A nuclear arms race would endanger every country in the region possessing nuclear weapons would make Iran the target of other nuclear states. A new nuclear arms race, new states possessing nuclear weapons, and a breakdown of the nonproliferation regime are the antithesis of those goals. that is why Iran must not get the bomb
An Iran armed with nuclear weapons would pose a grave threat The fact that a nuclear catastrophe hasn’t occurred reveals nothing about the future Political instability has been a source of catastrophe Split-second decision-making has brought the world close to nuclear war Iran was racked by demo Even with the best of intentions the unreliability of communications systems precipitate disaster A nuclear arms race would endanger the region
Much has been written about the nuclear negotiations with Iran. While diplomacy has received a great deal of attention, one important question too often gets lost in the details: why Iran must not get the bomb. In my view, the answer is quite simple. An Iran armed with nuclear weapons would pose a grave threat not only to world peace but to the Iranian people. Almost 70 years have passed since the destruction of Nagasaki, the last time a nuclear weapon was used against a civilian target. The cold war ended without a nuclear exchange, and the dangers of nuclear terrorism remain speculative, thus far. The fact that a nuclear catastrophe hasn’t occurred since 1945 encourages the belief that because it hasn’t happened, it won’t happen. Or even that it can’t happen. An influential American academic, Kenneth Waltz, considered the proliferation of nuclear weapons to be a good thing; the more countries that obtained them, the better. “Those who like peace should love nuclear weapons,” Waltz argued. “They are the only weapons ever invented that work decisively against their own use.” Many academics now agree with his contention that nuclear weapons discourage warfare between the states that possess them, stabilise international relations, and encourage world leaders to be more cautious. That argument does, in fact, accurately describe the recent diplomatic history of nuclear weapon states. But it reveals nothing about the future. It’s true – until one day, it isn’t. Every country that possesses nuclear weapons must contend with their inherent risks. They are the most dangerous machines ever invented, extremely difficult to manage, for reasons both technical and administrative. Like every manmade object, they are imperfect. And so are the people who control them. The US first devised this technology, perfected it, gained more experience with it than any other nation – and yet has come close on numerous occasions to having American cities destroyed accidentally by American nuclear weapons. Political instability in almost half the countries with nuclear weapons has been a potential source of catastrophe. Split-second decision-making has brought the world close to nuclear war more than once and then narrowly averted it. The Pentagon has long claimed that only 32 serious accidents have occurred with American nuclear weapons. But a document that I obtained through the Freedom of Information Act listed more than a thousand accidents involving US nuclear weapons just between the years of 1950 and 1968. Many of those accidents were trivial; others were more likely to produce a full-scale nuclear detonation than some of the accidents on the official list. Seemingly innocuous things could have led to disaster. A tiny metal nut that came off a screw inside a B-52 bomber created a new electrical pathway, circumventing a safety switch and fully arming four hydrogen bombs. A maintenance technician investigating a faulty intruder alarm at a missile silo pulled the wrong fuse with a screwdriver, caused a short circuit, and blew the warhead off a missile. Four rubber seat cushions inadvertently stowed near a heat vent in the cockpit of a B-52 set the plane on fire, forced the crew to bail out mid-flight, and could have detonated hydrogen bombs at one of America’s most important, top-secret military installations. Other countries came up with nuclear weapon designs that were vastly less safe. Had Saddam Hussein built nuclear weapons, they might have posed a greater threat to Baghdad than to any of his enemies. “It could go off if a rifle bullet hit it,” a UN inspector said about an Iraqi weapon design. “I wouldn’t want to be around if it fell off the edge of this desk.” Five years ago Iran was racked by massive demonstrations; the “green movement” seeking democracy was violently suppressed. Political instability and nuclear weapons are not a good combination. According to Bruno Tertrais, a former official in the French ministry of defence and a proliferation expert, four of the nine countries that now possess nuclear weapons are “known to have undergone severe political crises affecting nuclear security and/or control of use in one way or another”. A recent book edited by Tertrais and Henry Sokolski, a former Pentagon official, describes how a group of French generals plotting a coup against President De Gaulle in the spring of 1961 tried to obtain a nuclear device that France was about to test in the Algerian desert. “Refrain from detonating your little bomb,” one of the generals told the commander in charge of the test. “Keep it for us, it will always be useful.” De Gaulle ordered the device to be set off earlier than planned, and the coup was unsuccessful. During the Cultural Revolution in China, members of the red guards launched a missile with a nuclear warhead on a flight path over populated areas – an extremely risky and perhaps unauthorised launch. For a few days in the summer of 1991, all three “chegets”, the small handheld devices that controlled the Soviet Union’s nuclear arsenal, were in the hands of military officials trying to seize power and overthrow President Mikhail Gorbachev. And Pakistan, the nation with the world’s fastest-growing nuclear arsenal, has had three military coups since the late 1960s, four prime ministers removed from power since the late 1980s, and an Islamist insurgency determined to topple the government. Even with the best of intentions and a sincere desire to avoid nuclear war, the complexity of weapons systems, the unreliability of communications systems and human fallibility can precipitate disaster. During the Cuban missile crisis, John F Kennedy and the Soviet leader Nikita Khruschev did all they could to avoid a conflict. And yet events beyond their knowledge or control – an American U-2 spy plane that accidentally strayed into Soviet territory, the test of an American ballistic missile without Kennedy’s approval, the delegation of authority for the use of nuclear weapons to Soviet commanders in Cuba and the captains of Soviet submarines – almost started a war that neither leader wanted. On October 27 1962, off the coast of Cuba, when American forces dropped practice depth charges to force a Soviet submarine to the surface, two of the three officers in charge of the sub voted to respond by firing nuclear weapons. They mistakenly believed the submarine was under attack. Vasili Arkhipov, the second-in-command, refused to authorise the use of nuclear weapons, and the vote to do so had to be unanimous. Arkhipov’s refusal prevented the world’s first nuclear war. Given Iran’s technical, political and leadership challenges, its pursuit of nuclear weapons seems an invitation to disaster. Moreover, Iran signed the nuclear non-proliferation treaty in 1970. Getting the bomb would violate that treaty, encourage other countries to violate it and discourage Israel from ever submitting nuclear facilities to international inspection. A nuclear arms race in the Middle East would endanger every country in the region; the effects of a nuclear detonation would spread without regard to national borders. And possessing nuclear weapons would make Iran the target of other nuclear states. Early next month, officials from 150 countries meet in Vienna to discuss the humanitarian impact of nuclear weapons and a treaty to ban them. The world was lucky in the 20th century to avoid a nuclear Armageddon. In the 21st century a new international consensus is emerging: nuclear weapons are only useful for killing or terrorising civilians. The number of weapons worldwide must be reduced with the goal of some day reaching zero. A new nuclear arms race, new states possessing nuclear weapons, and a breakdown of the nonproliferation regime are the antithesis of those goals. And that, among many other reasons, is why Iran must not get the bomb.
7,868
<h4>Nuclear exchanges are likely---Iranian prolif uniquely guarantees involvement</h4><p>Eric <strong>Schlosser 14</strong>, the author of Command and Control: the story of nuclear weapons and the illusion of safety, "Why we must rid the world of nuclear weapons," 11-27-2014, Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/nov/27/nuclear-weapons-near-misses-iran-bomb-peace</p><p>Much has been written about the nuclear negotiations with Iran. While diplomacy has received a great deal of attention, one important question too often gets lost in the details: why Iran must not get the bomb. In my view, the answer is quite <u><strong>simple. <mark>An Iran armed with nuclear weapons would pose a</mark> <mark>grave threat</u></strong></mark> not only <u><strong>to world peace</u></strong> but to the Iranian people. Almost 70 years have passed since the destruction of Nagasaki, the last time a nuclear weapon was used against a civilian target. The cold war ended without a nuclear exchange, and the dangers of nuclear terrorism remain speculative, thus far. <u><mark>The fact that a nuclear catastrophe hasn’t occurred</mark> since 1945</u> <u>encourages the belief that</u> because it hasn’t happened, <u>it won’t happen</u>. Or even that it can’t happen. An influential American academic, Kenneth Waltz, considered the proliferation of nuclear weapons to be a good thing; the more countries that obtained them, the better. “Those who like peace should love nuclear weapons,” Waltz argued. “They are the only weapons ever invented that work decisively against their own use.” Many academics now agree with his contention that nuclear weapons discourage warfare between the states that possess them, stabilise international relations, and encourage world leaders to be more cautious. <u>That argument</u> does, in fact, accurately describe the recent diplomatic history of nuclear weapon states. But it <u><mark>reveals <strong>nothing about the future</u></strong></mark>. It’s true – until one day, it isn’t. <u>Every country that possesses</u> nuclear <u>weapons must contend with</u> their inherent <u><strong>risks</u></strong>. They are the most dangerous machines ever invented, extremely difficult to manage, for reasons both technical and administrative. Like every manmade object, they are imperfect. And so are the people who control them. The US first devised this technology, perfected it, gained more experience with it than any other nation – and yet has come close on numerous occasions to having American cities destroyed accidentally by American nuclear weapons. <u><strong><mark>Political instability</u></strong></mark> in almost half the countries with nuclear weapons <u><mark>has been <strong>a</strong></mark> </u>potential<u> <strong><mark>source of catastrophe</strong></mark>.</u> <u><strong><mark>Split-second decision-making</u></strong></mark> <u><mark>has brought the world</u> <u>close to <strong>nuclear war</u></strong></mark> more than once and then narrowly averted it. The Pentagon has long claimed that only 32 serious accidents have occurred with American nuclear weapons. But a document that I obtained through the Freedom of Information Act listed more than a thousand accidents involving US nuclear weapons just between the years of 1950 and 1968. Many of those accidents were trivial; others were more likely to produce a full-scale nuclear detonation than some of the accidents on the official list. Seemingly innocuous things could have led to disaster. A tiny metal nut that came off a screw inside a B-52 bomber created a new electrical pathway, circumventing a safety switch and fully arming four hydrogen bombs. A maintenance technician investigating a faulty intruder alarm at a missile silo pulled the wrong fuse with a screwdriver, caused a short circuit, and blew the warhead off a missile. Four rubber seat cushions inadvertently stowed near a heat vent in the cockpit of a B-52 set the plane on fire, forced the crew to bail out mid-flight, and could have detonated hydrogen bombs at one of America’s most important, top-secret military installations. Other <u>countries came up with nuclear weapon designs that were</u> vastly <u><strong>less safe</u></strong>. Had Saddam Hussein built nuclear weapons, they might have posed a greater threat to Baghdad than to any of his enemies. “It could go off if a rifle bullet hit it,” a UN inspector said about an Iraqi weapon design. “I wouldn’t want to be around if it fell off the edge of this desk.” Five years ago <u><mark>Iran was racked by</u></mark> massive <u><mark>demo</mark>nstrations; the “green movement” seeking democracy was violently suppressed.</u> <u><strong>Political instability</u></strong> <u>and</u> <u><strong>nuclear weapons</u></strong> <u>are not a good combination</u>. <u>According to</u> Bruno <u>Tertrais</u>, a former official in the French ministry of defence and a proliferation expert, <u>four of the nine countries that now possess nuclear weapons are “known to have undergone severe <strong>political crises</u></strong> affecting nuclear security and/or control of use in one way or another”. A recent book edited by Tertrais and Henry Sokolski, a former Pentagon official, describes how a group of French generals plotting a coup against President De Gaulle in the spring of 1961 tried to obtain a nuclear device that France was about to test in the Algerian desert. “Refrain from detonating your little bomb,” one of the generals told the commander in charge of the test. “Keep it for us, it will always be useful.” De Gaulle ordered the device to be set off earlier than planned, and the coup was unsuccessful. During the Cultural Revolution in China, members of the red guards launched a missile with a nuclear warhead on a flight path over populated areas – an extremely risky and perhaps unauthorised launch. For a few days in the summer of 1991, all three “chegets”, the small handheld devices that controlled the Soviet Union’s nuclear arsenal, were in the hands of military officials trying to seize power and overthrow President Mikhail Gorbachev. And Pakistan, the nation with the world’s fastest-growing nuclear arsenal, has had three military coups since the late 1960s, four prime ministers removed from power since the late 1980s, and an Islamist insurgency determined to topple the government. <u><mark>Even with the best of intentions</mark> and a sincere desire to avoid nuclear war, the complexity of weapons systems</u>, <u><strong><mark>the unreliability of communications systems</u></strong></mark> and human fallibility <u>can <mark>precipitate</u> <u><strong>disaster</u></strong></mark>. During the Cuban missile crisis, John F Kennedy and the Soviet leader Nikita Khruschev did all they could to avoid a conflict. And yet events beyond their knowledge or control – an American U-2 spy plane that accidentally strayed into Soviet territory, the test of an American ballistic missile without Kennedy’s approval, the delegation of authority for the use of nuclear weapons to Soviet commanders in Cuba and the captains of Soviet submarines – almost started a war that neither leader wanted. On October 27 1962, off the coast of Cuba, when American forces dropped practice depth charges to force a Soviet submarine to the surface, two of the three officers in charge of the sub voted to respond by firing nuclear weapons. They mistakenly believed the submarine was under attack. Vasili Arkhipov, the second-in-command, refused to authorise the use of nuclear weapons, and the vote to do so had to be unanimous. Arkhipov’s refusal prevented the world’s first nuclear war. <u>Given Iran’s <strong>technical</strong>, <strong>political</strong> and <strong>leadership</strong> challenges</u>, <u>its pursuit of nuclear weapons seems an invitation to disaste</u>r. Moreover, Iran signed the nuclear non-proliferation treaty in 1970. Getting the bomb would violate that treaty, encourage other countries to violate it and discourage Israel from ever submitting nuclear facilities to international inspection. <u><strong><mark>A nuclear arms race</u></strong></mark> in the Middle East <u><mark>would</u> <u>endanger</mark> every country in <mark>the region</u></mark>; the effects of a nuclear detonation would spread without regard to national borders. And <u><strong>possessing nuclear weapons would make Iran the target of other nuclear states. </u></strong>Early next month, officials from 150 countries meet in Vienna to discuss the humanitarian impact of nuclear weapons and a treaty to ban them. The world was lucky in the 20th century to avoid a nuclear Armageddon. In the 21st century a new international consensus is emerging: nuclear weapons are only useful for killing or terrorising civilians. The number of weapons worldwide must be reduced with the goal of some day reaching zero. <u>A new nuclear arms race, new states possessing nuclear weapons, and a breakdown of the nonproliferation regime are the antithesis of those goals. </u>And <u><strong>that</u></strong>, among many other reasons, <u><strong>is why Iran must not get the bomb</u>.</p></strong>
1nr
Strikes
CP: A/T “Wild Ev”
72,220
8
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,101
PC’s key and sufficient to stop passage- key to negotiation success
Washington Post 4/2
Washington Post 4/2/2015 (Congress reacts to Iran nuclear framework with cautious optimism, renewed skepticism, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/post-politics/wp/2015/04/02/congress-reacts-to-iran-nuclear-framework-with-cautious-optimism-renewed-skepticism/)
If Congress kills this deal then it's the United States that will be blamed for the failure of diplomacy International unity will collapse, and the path to conflict will widen Thursday's release of key details about the nuclear framework heralded a new phase of domestic politicking where Obama will be seeking to keep Democrats unified behind him as he sells the deal on Capitol Hill the Senate Foreign Relations Committee is scheduled to mark up the review bill the day after members return the deal's fate may rest squarely on whether he can convince congressional Democrats to leave him a free hand in the coming months it’ll be a tough sell, and it’s the final details that matter The administration is going to need all hands on deck.” Despite the White House’s poor reputation for managing congressional relations on this particular issue they have demonstrated success before and should be able to replicate that now In 2014, as pressure built to ramp up sanctions on Iran, administration officials worked the Democrats to avoid a vote on the issue
null
President Obama said Thursday that his administration would give Congress a thorough briefing on the details of the framework, but the outlines immediately revealed did not immediately move any key lawmakers off of their previous positions — even as Obama warned against knee-jerk reactions. "If Congress kills this deal not based on expert analysis, and without offering any reasonable alternative, then it's the United States that will be blamed for the failure of diplomacy," he said. "International unity will collapse, and the path to conflict will widen." Congressional sentiment was inflamed by Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu's early-March visit to Washington, where he told a joint session of Congress that any deal would "pave the way" to an Iranian nuke, and by the subsequent letter signed by 47 Republican senators sent to the Iranian regime, warning that Congress could reverse any deal made at the negotiating table. Thursday's release of key details about the nuclear framework heralded a new phase of domestic politicking, where Obama will be seeking to keep Democrats unified behind him as he sells the deal to the public and on Capitol Hill, while Republicans determine how hard a line to draw against the terms negotiated over many months by the U.S. and five other foreign partners. Key lawmakers struck a careful note Thursday, seeking above all to firm up Congress's role in reviewing the deal. Sen. Bob Corker (R-Tenn.), chairman of the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, said lawmakers "must remain clear-eyed regarding Iran’s continued resistance to concessions, long history of covert nuclear weapons-related activities, support of terrorism, and its current role in destabilizing the region." "If a final agreement is reached, the American people, through their elected representatives, must have the opportunity to weigh in to ensure the deal truly can eliminate the threat of Iran’s nuclear program and hold the regime accountable," said Corker, the lead sponsor of a bipartisan bill that would bring the nuclear deal to Congress for a 60-day review. Congress is out of session until April 13, but the Senate Foreign Relations Committee is scheduled to mark up the review bill the day after members return. Corker said he is "confident of a strong vote" in its favor. The Post's Dan Balz talks to Yahoo News about the nuclear framework agreement reached between Iran and world powers, and the political ramifications for President Obama. (Yahoo News) House Speaker John A. Boehner (R-Ohio), who invited Netanyahu to Washington and visited him in Israel earlier this week, also called for a legislative role in any deal: "Congress must be allowed to fully review the details of any agreement before any sanctions are lifted," he said in a statement. "After visiting with our partners on the ground in the Middle East this week, my concerns about Iran’s efforts to foment unrest, brutal violence and terror have only grown. It would be naïve to suggest the Iranian regime will not continue to use its nuclear program, and any economic relief, to further destabilize the region." Rep. Peter Roskam (R-Ill.), a co-chairman of the House Republican Israel caucus, was more sharply critical of the advance toward a deal, saying in a statement that it "makes no demonstrable progress on the legitimate security concerns of the American people and the international community." Rep. Steve Israel, a House Democratic leader and frequent critic of the Iran talks, said he remains "highly skeptical" of a deal: "The details deserve and must get a vote by the U.S. Congress." On the Senate side, the Republicans most critical of the deal showed no sign of softening their rebukes, and their Thursday statements indicated an emerging set of specific criticisms. Sen. Tom Cotton (R-Ark.), the freshman who rocked Capitol Hill by putting together the letter addressed to Iranian leaders, said in an interview that the framework discussed Thursday represented "a list of concessions to put Iran on the path to a nuclear bomb." “At this point, the only thing to do is walk away, impose new sanctions, and drive a tougher bargain,” he said. Sen. Marco Rubio (R-Fla.), a Foreign Relations member and a potential presidential candidate, said in a statement that the initial reports on the framework were "very troubling" and represented an "attempt to spin diplomatic failure as a success" while doing nothing about Iran's non-nuclear activities. Both Cotton and Rubio said they were concerned that thousands of uranium enrichment centrifuges would remain operational, even as negotiators said two-thirds or more would be decommissioned, and that the hardened Fordow enrichment facility would remain open, even if in a non-weapons capacity. Senate Democrats, even those who had been skeptical of the negotiations, struck more positive notes Thursday, starting with Minority Leader Harry M. Reid (Nev.), who called on his colleagues to "take a deep breath, examine the details and give this critically important process time to play out." "We must always remain vigilant about preventing Iran from getting a nuclear weapon but there is no question that a diplomatic solution is vastly preferable to the alternatives," he said. Sen. Robert Menendez (D-N.J.), who until his Wednesday indictment on federal corruption charges served as the top Democrat on the Foreign Relations Committee, had been outspoken in his criticism of the Iranian regime and the dismal prospects for a diplomatic solution to its nuclear ambitions. But, like Corker, he did not characterize the deal in a Thursday statement but instead staked out the congressional interest in reviewing it. "If diplomats can negotiate for two years on this issue, then certainly Congress is entitled to a review period of an agreement that will fundamentally alter our relationship with Iran and the sanctions imposed by Congress," he said. "The best outcome remains a good deal that ends Iran’s illicit nuclear weapons program. That requires a strong, united, and bipartisan approach from the administration and Congress." Sen. Ben Cardin (D-Md.), the new ranking member, said in his own statement that "Congress has a role to play in this process" but he stopped short of endorsing a formal review period. "The best outcome is a strong diplomatic one," said Cardin, who is not a cosponsor of the bipartisan review bill. Obama on Thursday sought to forestall criticism of the deal by focusing attention on alternatives. "When you hear the inevitable critics of the deal sound off, ask them a simple question: Do you really think that this verifiable deal, if fully implemented, backed by the world's major powers, is a worse option than the risk of another war in the Middle East?" Obama asked in the White House Rose Garden. "Is it worse than doing what we've done for almost two decades with Iran moving forward with its nuclear program and without robust inspections? I think the answer will be clear." But the deal's fate may rest squarely on whether he can convince congressional Democrats and a few centrist Republicans to leave him a free hand in the coming months to consummate the deal. “I hope today’s announcement imbues Democrats with a sense of the seriousness of the stakes,” said Sen. Chris Murphy (D-Conn.), a junior member of the Foreign Relations Committee who has emerged as a strong administration ally. Murphy said that it was critical that enough Democrats stand together to assure that the Corker bill mandating congressional review falls short of the two-thirds majority needed to override Obama’s veto. Sen. Jeff Flake (R-Ariz.), another junior member of Foreign Relations, said the bloc of Republicans open to possible compromise is "bigger than it would seem to some people" and noted that "the country as a whole seems more open to a negotiated agreement than our conference has been." A new Washington Post-ABC News poll found that Americans by a nearly 2-to-1 margin support the idea of striking a deal that would restrict the Iranian nuclear program in return for loosened sanctions. “That said, it’ll be a tough sell, and it’s the final details that matter," Flake said, adding that he expects Secretary of State John Kerry, a former chairman of the Foreign Relations Committee, to make personally make the case on Capitol Hill: "The administration is going to need all hands on deck.” Despite the White House’s poor reputation for managing congressional relations, Murphy said that on this particular issue they have demonstrated success before and should be able to replicate that now. In 2014, as pressure built to ramp up sanctions on Iran, administration officials worked the Democrats to avoid a vote on the issue.
8,728
<h4>PC’s key and sufficient to stop passage- key to negotiation success</h4><p><strong>Washington Post 4/2</strong>/2015 (Congress reacts to Iran nuclear framework with cautious optimism, renewed skepticism, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/post-politics/wp/2015/04/02/congress-reacts-to-iran-nuclear-framework-with-cautious-optimism-renewed-skepticism/)</p><p>President Obama said Thursday that his administration would give Congress a thorough briefing on the details of the framework, but the outlines immediately revealed did not immediately move any key lawmakers off of their previous positions — even as Obama warned against knee-jerk reactions. "<u>If Congress kills this deal</u> not based on expert analysis, and without offering any reasonable alternative, <u>then it's the United States that will be blamed for the failure of diplomacy</u>," he said. "<u>International unity will collapse, and the path to conflict will widen</u>." Congressional sentiment was inflamed by Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu's early-March visit to Washington, where he told a joint session of Congress that any deal would "pave the way" to an Iranian nuke, and by the subsequent letter signed by 47 Republican senators sent to the Iranian regime, warning that Congress could reverse any deal made at the negotiating table. <u>Thursday's release of key details about the nuclear framework heralded a new phase of domestic politicking</u>, <u>where Obama will be seeking to keep Democrats unified behind him as he sells the deal</u> to the public and <u>on Capitol Hill</u>, while Republicans determine how hard a line to draw against the terms negotiated over many months by the U.S. and five other foreign partners. Key lawmakers struck a careful note Thursday, seeking above all to firm up Congress's role in reviewing the deal. Sen. Bob Corker (R-Tenn.), chairman of the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, said lawmakers "must remain clear-eyed regarding Iran’s continued resistance to concessions, long history of covert nuclear weapons-related activities, support of terrorism, and its current role in destabilizing the region." "If a final agreement is reached, the American people, through their elected representatives, must have the opportunity to weigh in to ensure the deal truly can eliminate the threat of Iran’s nuclear program and hold the regime accountable," said Corker, the lead sponsor of a bipartisan bill that would bring the nuclear deal to Congress for a 60-day review. Congress is out of session until April 13, but <u>the Senate Foreign Relations Committee is scheduled to mark up the review bill the day after members return</u>. Corker said he is "confident of a strong vote" in its favor. The Post's Dan Balz talks to Yahoo News about the nuclear framework agreement reached between Iran and world powers, and the political ramifications for President Obama. (Yahoo News) House Speaker John A. Boehner (R-Ohio), who invited Netanyahu to Washington and visited him in Israel earlier this week, also called for a legislative role in any deal: "Congress must be allowed to fully review the details of any agreement before any sanctions are lifted," he said in a statement. "After visiting with our partners on the ground in the Middle East this week, my concerns about Iran’s efforts to foment unrest, brutal violence and terror have only grown. It would be naïve to suggest the Iranian regime will not continue to use its nuclear program, and any economic relief, to further destabilize the region." Rep. Peter Roskam (R-Ill.), a co-chairman of the House Republican Israel caucus, was more sharply critical of the advance toward a deal, saying in a statement that it "makes no demonstrable progress on the legitimate security concerns of the American people and the international community." Rep. Steve Israel, a House Democratic leader and frequent critic of the Iran talks, said he remains "highly skeptical" of a deal: "The details deserve and must get a vote by the U.S. Congress." On the Senate side, the Republicans most critical of the deal showed no sign of softening their rebukes, and their Thursday statements indicated an emerging set of specific criticisms. Sen. Tom Cotton (R-Ark.), the freshman who rocked Capitol Hill by putting together the letter addressed to Iranian leaders, said in an interview that the framework discussed Thursday represented "a list of concessions to put Iran on the path to a nuclear bomb." “At this point, the only thing to do is walk away, impose new sanctions, and drive a tougher bargain,” he said. Sen. Marco Rubio (R-Fla.), a Foreign Relations member and a potential presidential candidate, said in a statement that the initial reports on the framework were "very troubling" and represented an "attempt to spin diplomatic failure as a success" while doing nothing about Iran's non-nuclear activities. Both Cotton and Rubio said they were concerned that thousands of uranium enrichment centrifuges would remain operational, even as negotiators said two-thirds or more would be decommissioned, and that the hardened Fordow enrichment facility would remain open, even if in a non-weapons capacity. Senate Democrats, even those who had been skeptical of the negotiations, struck more positive notes Thursday, starting with Minority Leader Harry M. Reid (Nev.), who called on his colleagues to "take a deep breath, examine the details and give this critically important process time to play out." "We must always remain vigilant about preventing Iran from getting a nuclear weapon but there is no question that a diplomatic solution is vastly preferable to the alternatives," he said. Sen. Robert Menendez (D-N.J.), who until his Wednesday indictment on federal corruption charges served as the top Democrat on the Foreign Relations Committee, had been outspoken in his criticism of the Iranian regime and the dismal prospects for a diplomatic solution to its nuclear ambitions. But, like Corker, he did not characterize the deal in a Thursday statement but instead staked out the congressional interest in reviewing it. "If diplomats can negotiate for two years on this issue, then certainly Congress is entitled to a review period of an agreement that will fundamentally alter our relationship with Iran and the sanctions imposed by Congress," he said. "The best outcome remains a good deal that ends Iran’s illicit nuclear weapons program. That requires a strong, united, and bipartisan approach from the administration and Congress." Sen. Ben Cardin (D-Md.), the new ranking member, said in his own statement that "Congress has a role to play in this process" but he stopped short of endorsing a formal review period. "The best outcome is a strong diplomatic one," said Cardin, who is not a cosponsor of the bipartisan review bill. Obama on Thursday sought to forestall criticism of the deal by focusing attention on alternatives. "When you hear the inevitable critics of the deal sound off, ask them a simple question: Do you really think that this verifiable deal, if fully implemented, backed by the world's major powers, is a worse option than the risk of another war in the Middle East?" Obama asked in the White House Rose Garden. "Is it worse than doing what we've done for almost two decades with Iran moving forward with its nuclear program and without robust inspections? I think the answer will be clear." But <u><strong>the deal's fate may rest squarely on whether he can convince congressional Democrats</u></strong> and a few centrist Republicans <u><strong>to leave him a free hand in the coming months</u></strong> to consummate the deal. “I hope today’s announcement imbues Democrats with a sense of the seriousness of the stakes,” said Sen. Chris Murphy (D-Conn.), a junior member of the Foreign Relations Committee who has emerged as a strong administration ally. Murphy said that it was critical that enough Democrats stand together to assure that the Corker bill mandating congressional review falls short of the two-thirds majority needed to override Obama’s veto. Sen. Jeff Flake (R-Ariz.), another junior member of Foreign Relations, said the bloc of Republicans open to possible compromise is "bigger than it would seem to some people" and noted that "the country as a whole seems more open to a negotiated agreement than our conference has been." A new Washington Post-ABC News poll found that Americans by a nearly 2-to-1 margin support the idea of striking a deal that would restrict the Iranian nuclear program in return for loosened sanctions. “That said, <u>it’ll be a tough sell, and it’s the final details that matter</u>," Flake said, adding that he expects Secretary of State John Kerry, a former chairman of the Foreign Relations Committee, to make personally make the case on Capitol Hill: "<u><strong>The administration is going to need all hands on deck.” </strong>Despite the White House’s poor reputation for managing congressional relations</u>, Murphy said that <u><strong>on this particular issue they have demonstrated success before and should be able to replicate that now</u></strong>. <u>In 2014, as pressure built to ramp up sanctions on Iran, administration officials worked the Democrats to avoid a vote on the issue</u>.</p>
1nr
Strikes
PC Key
430,576
4
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,102
PC keeps critical Democrats who are on the fence from supporting the bill
Politico 4/2
Politico 4/2/2015 (Fate of Iran bill rests with Democrats, http://www.politico.com/story/2015/04/bob-corker-iran-bill-116629.html)
the president’s Democratic allies in the Senate that hold the keys to any Iran bill. Republicans need Democrats to proceed with the bill, and the White House is sure to start twisting arms in the party to try and keep the measure off the Senate floor now that Obama can argue he’s made progress, Democrats will have to decide whether they want to openly rebuke the administration Cardin sounded like he was still making up his mind If he determines that Corker’s bill won’t break the fragile agreement, Cardin could end up supporting it if the bill begins working its way through Congress it could undermine a deal. They’ll be working hard to peel them off Obama indicated a full-court press to lobby against the bill was already in the works With Congress in the middle of a recess, both Corker and the White House will be gauging support for the bill To win a veto-proof majority, Corker will have to fend off White House pressure on Democrats The main event will be courting Democrats some aren’t inclined to support Corker. Murphy said that as long as the president’s negotiators are telling him that Iran votes would scuttle negotiations, he will hold off on supporting congressional approval legislation Obama’s outreach will focus on Democrats who have signaled support for either Corker’s bill or one that would snap sanctions back on Iran if it reneges on any part of an agreement. The White House has repeatedly lobbied Democrats away from supporting either bill on the Senate floor, and as McConnell prepares his chamber to vote on Corker’s bill, Obama and his aides are moving quickly to stifle Democratic support The White House will concentrate on members like Cardin and Schumer who’s a co-sponsor of Corker’s bill and Kirk’s sanctions legislation. Schumer didn’t tip his hand
null
The Republican Congress is demanding to be heard on a nuclear deal with Iran despite President Barack Obama’s warnings. But it’s the president’s Democratic allies in the Senate that hold the keys to any Iran bill. Republicans have written legislation they think can move quickly through the Senate. It would give Congress a critical role in accepting or rejecting a deal with Tehran. But they need Democrats to proceed with the bill, and the White House is sure to start twisting arms in the party to try and keep the measure off the Senate floor. Several Democrats have previously said they would support the legislation, but now that Obama can argue he’s made progress, Democrats will have to decide whether they want to openly rebuke the administration’s diplomatic efforts. The new top Democrat on the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, Ben Cardin of Maryland, sounded like he was still making up his mind. He said he was open to moving forward, but cautioned he needs to study how legislation written by Sen. Bob Corker (R-Tenn.) interacts with the complex non-proliferation framework struck by Iran, the United States and five other global powers. Cardin noted that he hadn’t yet spoken to the president about his new role on the committee. If he determines that Corker’s bill won’t break the fragile agreement, Cardin could end up supporting it, particularly if Corker is open to tweaking it further to satisfy Democrats. “Congress does have a right to review the agreement, the sanctions are imposed by Congress. A review process established by Congress makes sense,” Cardin said late Thursday afternoon. But, he added a critical disclaimer: “I want it to strengthen the president, not weaken the president, I don’t want it to undermine negotiations.” If enough Democrats go along with Corker, it’s on to the Senate floor and then the House, where Speaker John Boehner (R-Ohio) is open to taking up the proposal, which would give lawmakers the power to approve or reject the agreement’s lifting of sanctions on Iran. But if the bill begins working its way through Congress, Obama has warned lawmakers it could undermine a deal. “They’ll be working hard to peel them off, but I think they’ve got a fairly hard case to make because [the deal is] so vague,” said John Thune of South Dakota, the No. 3 Republican in the Senate. “It’s going to depend a lot on how strong and resilient these Democrats are when the administration starts breaking arms.” Indeed, Obama indicated a full-court press to lobby against the bill was already in the works. With Congress in the middle of a recess, both Corker and the White House will be gauging support for the bill, which Corker intends to take up in committee on April 14. To win a veto-proof majority, Corker will have to reassure Cardin and fend off White House pressure on Democrats to hold off on voting for Iran legislation. Other Democrats, like Sen. Tim Kaine (D-Va.), reemphasized their support for legislation even in the wake of the historic announcement, calling the Corker measure one that “sets up a clear and constructive process for Congress to weigh in on any final deal that touches upon the statutory sanctions Congress has enacted.” Obama challenged lawmakers preemptively in his Thursday speech, asking whether a verifiable deal with Iran “is a worse option than another war in the Middle East.” “If Congress kills this deal, not based on expert analysis, and without offering any reasonable alternative, then it’s the United States that will be blamed for the failure of diplomacy, international unity will collapse, and the path to conflict will widen,” Obama added. And shortly after he spoke his top aides began working the phones. Sen. Ron Johnson (R-Wis.) got a phone call from U.S. Ambassador to the United Nations Samantha Power urging him to keep an open mind, Sen. Chris Murphy (D-Conn.) got a telephone briefing from Deputy Secretary of State Tony Blinken and Obama himself called Senate Democratic Leader Harry Reid (D-Nev.) and said he’d soon be in contact with other congressional leaders, including Boehner and Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell (R-Ky.). Many Republicans won’t be swayed. Johnson said he was trying to keep an open mind but also suggested that Corker’s bill doesn’t go far enough, suggesting instead that Congress should declare the nuclear deal a treaty that must be ratified by the Senate. “We could have a very simple bill that basically says, that no matter what President Obama says, we are going to call this a treaty and we are going to ratify this as a treaty,” Johnson said, adding that he’s “concerned” about the complexity of Corker’s bill. Many of Johnson’s colleagues went straight into the blistering criticisms, summoning their choicest rhetoric to pan Obama’s negotiating acumen after railing against the ongoing negotiations for months. Sen. Tom Cotton (R-Ark.) said no agreement was struck, describing Thursday’s announcement as simply a “list of dangerous concessions.” And in a telephone interview, Sen. Mark Kirk (R-Ill.) reiterated that his leaders should give his sanctions bill a vote and blasted the president’s announcement and a top State Department negotiator, Wendy Sherman. “I would say that Neville Chamberlain got a lot more out of Hitler than Wendy Sherman got out of Iran,” Kirk said. Meanwhile, Republican presidential contenders said the administration was pursuing a seriously flawed nuclear deal that gives away too much while getting little in return. “These negotiations began, by President Obama’s own admission, as an effort to deny Iran nuclear capabilities, but instead will only legitimize those activities,” former Florida Gov. Jeb Bush said in a statement. “I cannot stand behind such a flawed agreement.” Wisconsin Gov. Scott Walker, was more critical, saying the agreement “rewards an enemy, undermines our allies and threatens our safety.” And Sen. Marco Rubio called it “just the latest example of this administration’s farcical approach to Iran.” The main event, though, will be courting Democrats. And some aren’t inclined to support Corker. Murphy said that as long as the president’s negotiators are telling him that Iran votes would scuttle negotiations, he will hold off on supporting congressional approval legislation. “Corker’s desire to move his bill exists independent of the contents of the deal. Bob just believes he’s got to pass this bill. I disagree,” Murphy said. “My feelings about the Corker proposal are completely interdependent on the level of concern from our negotiators.” Indeed, with the framework in hand and some members like Murphy already satisfied with giving the administration room and time to negotiate, Obama’s outreach will focus on Democrats who have signaled support for either Corker’s bill or one that would snap sanctions back on Iran if it reneges on any part of an agreement. But on-the-fence Democrats are also waiting for a signal from leaders in Tehran. Will Iran step forward and publicly embrace Obama’s description of an agreement that would pull apart two-thirds of the country’s centrifuges? And will Iran accept the president’s claim that the deal prevents Tehran from making a nuclear weapon? That, said Rep. Brad Sherman (D-Calif.), is the sticking point. “If the Iranians do not publicly agree to what the president says they’ve agreed to, then I’m ready to vote for both bills,” Sherman said in an interview. “If Iran cares what Congress does, the first step is to publicly agree to what the president puts out.” The White House has repeatedly lobbied Democrats away from supporting either bill on the Senate floor, and as McConnell prepares his chamber to vote on Corker’s bill, Obama and his aides are moving quickly to stifle Democratic support. The White House is less worried about members like Murphy and Reid, and instead will concentrate on members like Cardin and Democratic-leader-in-waiting Sen. Chuck Schumer of New York, who’s a co-sponsor of Corker’s bill and Kirk’s sanctions legislation. Schumer didn’t tip his hand on Thursday. “Secretary Kerry and Secretary [Ernest] Moniz have worked long and hard and their announcement deserves careful, rigorous and deliberate analysis. I’ll be giving the framework a very careful look,” Schumer said.
8,266
<h4>PC keeps critical Democrats who are on the fence from supporting the bill</h4><p><strong>Politico 4/2</strong>/2015 (Fate of Iran bill rests with Democrats, http://www.politico.com/story/2015/04/bob-corker-iran-bill-116629.html)</p><p>The Republican Congress is demanding to be heard on a nuclear deal with Iran despite President Barack Obama’s warnings. But it’s <u>the president’s Democratic allies in the Senate that hold the keys to any Iran bill. Republicans</u> have written legislation they think can move quickly through the Senate. It would give Congress a critical role in accepting or rejecting a deal with Tehran. But they <u>need Democrats to proceed with the bill, and the White House is sure to start twisting arms in the party to try and keep the measure off the Senate floor</u>. Several Democrats have previously said they would support the legislation, but <u>now that Obama can argue he’s made progress, Democrats will have to decide whether they want to openly rebuke the administration</u>’s diplomatic efforts. The new top Democrat on the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, Ben <u>Cardin</u> of Maryland, <u>sounded like he was still making up his mind</u>. He said he was open to moving forward, but cautioned he needs to study how legislation written by Sen. Bob Corker (R-Tenn.) interacts with the complex non-proliferation framework struck by Iran, the United States and five other global powers. Cardin noted that he hadn’t yet spoken to the president about his new role on the committee. <u>If he determines that Corker’s bill won’t break the fragile agreement, Cardin could end up supporting it</u>, particularly if Corker is open to tweaking it further to satisfy Democrats. “Congress does have a right to review the agreement, the sanctions are imposed by Congress. A review process established by Congress makes sense,” Cardin said late Thursday afternoon. But, he added a critical disclaimer: “I want it to strengthen the president, not weaken the president, I don’t want it to undermine negotiations.” If enough Democrats go along with Corker, it’s on to the Senate floor and then the House, where Speaker John Boehner (R-Ohio) is open to taking up the proposal, which would give lawmakers the power to approve or reject the agreement’s lifting of sanctions on Iran. But <u>if the bill begins working its way through Congress</u>, Obama has warned lawmakers <u>it could undermine a deal. </u>“<u>They’ll be working hard to peel them off</u>, but I think they’ve got a fairly hard case to make because [the deal is] so vague,” said John Thune of South Dakota, the No. 3 Republican in the Senate. “It’s going to depend a lot on how strong and resilient these Democrats are when the administration starts breaking arms.” Indeed, <u>Obama indicated a full-court press to lobby against the bill was already in the works</u>. <u>With Congress in the middle of a recess, both Corker and the White House will be gauging support for the bill</u>, which Corker intends to take up in committee on April 14. <u>To win a veto-proof majority, Corker will have to</u> reassure Cardin and <u>fend off White House pressure on Democrats</u> to hold off on voting for Iran legislation. Other Democrats, like Sen. Tim Kaine (D-Va.), reemphasized their support for legislation even in the wake of the historic announcement, calling the Corker measure one that “sets up a clear and constructive process for Congress to weigh in on any final deal that touches upon the statutory sanctions Congress has enacted.” Obama challenged lawmakers preemptively in his Thursday speech, asking whether a verifiable deal with Iran “is a worse option than another war in the Middle East.” “If Congress kills this deal, not based on expert analysis, and without offering any reasonable alternative, then it’s the United States that will be blamed for the failure of diplomacy, international unity will collapse, and the path to conflict will widen,” Obama added. And shortly after he spoke his top aides began working the phones. Sen. Ron Johnson (R-Wis.) got a phone call from U.S. Ambassador to the United Nations Samantha Power urging him to keep an open mind, Sen. Chris Murphy (D-Conn.) got a telephone briefing from Deputy Secretary of State Tony Blinken and Obama himself called Senate Democratic Leader Harry Reid (D-Nev.) and said he’d soon be in contact with other congressional leaders, including Boehner and Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell (R-Ky.). Many Republicans won’t be swayed. Johnson said he was trying to keep an open mind but also suggested that Corker’s bill doesn’t go far enough, suggesting instead that Congress should declare the nuclear deal a treaty that must be ratified by the Senate. “We could have a very simple bill that basically says, that no matter what President Obama says, we are going to call this a treaty and we are going to ratify this as a treaty,” Johnson said, adding that he’s “concerned” about the complexity of Corker’s bill. Many of Johnson’s colleagues went straight into the blistering criticisms, summoning their choicest rhetoric to pan Obama’s negotiating acumen after railing against the ongoing negotiations for months. Sen. Tom Cotton (R-Ark.) said no agreement was struck, describing Thursday’s announcement as simply a “list of dangerous concessions.” And in a telephone interview, Sen. Mark Kirk (R-Ill.) reiterated that his leaders should give his sanctions bill a vote and blasted the president’s announcement and a top State Department negotiator, Wendy Sherman. “I would say that Neville Chamberlain got a lot more out of Hitler than Wendy Sherman got out of Iran,” Kirk said. Meanwhile, Republican presidential contenders said the administration was pursuing a seriously flawed nuclear deal that gives away too much while getting little in return. “These negotiations began, by President Obama’s own admission, as an effort to deny Iran nuclear capabilities, but instead will only legitimize those activities,” former Florida Gov. Jeb Bush said in a statement. “I cannot stand behind such a flawed agreement.” Wisconsin Gov. Scott Walker, was more critical, saying the agreement “rewards an enemy, undermines our allies and threatens our safety.” And Sen. Marco Rubio called it “just the latest example of this administration’s farcical approach to Iran.” <u>The main event</u>, though, <u>will be courting Democrats</u>. And <u>some aren’t inclined to support Corker. Murphy said that as long as the president’s negotiators are telling him that Iran votes would scuttle negotiations, he will hold off on supporting congressional approval legislation</u>. “Corker’s desire to move his bill exists independent of the contents of the deal. Bob just believes he’s got to pass this bill. I disagree,” Murphy said. “My feelings about the Corker proposal are completely interdependent on the level of concern from our negotiators.” Indeed, with the framework in hand and some members like Murphy already satisfied with giving the administration room and time to negotiate, <u>Obama’s outreach will focus on Democrats who have signaled support for either Corker’s bill or one that would snap sanctions back on Iran if it reneges on any part of an agreement. </u>But on-the-fence Democrats are also waiting for a signal from leaders in Tehran. Will Iran step forward and publicly embrace Obama’s description of an agreement that would pull apart two-thirds of the country’s centrifuges? And will Iran accept the president’s claim that the deal prevents Tehran from making a nuclear weapon? That, said Rep. Brad Sherman (D-Calif.), is the sticking point. “If the Iranians do not publicly agree to what the president says they’ve agreed to, then I’m ready to vote for both bills,” Sherman said in an interview. “If Iran cares what Congress does, the first step is to publicly agree to what the president puts out.” <u>The White House has repeatedly lobbied Democrats away from supporting either bill on the Senate floor, and as McConnell prepares his chamber to vote on Corker’s bill, Obama and his aides are moving quickly to stifle Democratic support</u>. <u>The White House</u> is less worried about members like Murphy and Reid, and instead <u>will concentrate on members like Cardin and</u> Democratic-leader-in-waiting Sen. Chuck <u>Schumer</u> of New York, <u>who’s a co-sponsor of Corker’s bill and Kirk’s sanctions legislation. Schumer didn’t tip his hand</u> on Thursday. “Secretary Kerry and Secretary [Ernest] Moniz have worked long and hard and their announcement deserves careful, rigorous and deliberate analysis. I’ll be giving the framework a very careful look,” Schumer said.</p>
1nr
Strikes
PC Key
430,578
5
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,103
PC’s key and it’s top of the agenda
WSJ 4/2
WSJ 4/2/2015 (Congress Presses for Power to Review Any Final Iran Nuclear Deal, http://www.wsj.com/articles/congress-presses-for-power-to-review-any-final-iran-nuclear-deal-1428017616)
The White House has threatened to veto the review legislation, and its ability to rally opposition will be a test of confidence lawmakers have the White House is expected to attempt to sell the deal to lawmakers
null
The White House has threatened to veto the review legislation, and its ability to get the bill altered or rally opposition against it in coming weeks will be a test of the confidence lawmakers have in the continuing negotiations with Iran. The Obama administration may have been helped by Wednesday’s indictment of Sen. Bob Menendez (D., N.J.) on allegations of corruption. Mr. Menendez, who has been outspoken in calling for a congressional review of any deal, has stepped down as the top Democrat on the foreign-relations panel while the legal process plays out. Senate Minority Leader Harry Reid (D., Nev.) cautioned against Congress taking immediate action on Iran-related legislation that could undermine the deal as negotiations continue until the June 30 deadline. “We have much to learn about what was negotiated and what will take place between now and the end of June,” Mr. Reid said, urging colleagues to “take a deep breath, examine the details and give this critically important process time to play out.” The White House and its Democratic allies in Congress have warned for more than a year against Congress taking steps such as imposing additional sanctions that could disrupt talks. But many Republicans, along with a number of Democrats, have increasingly called for lawmakers to have a greater role in the process, including the ability to review and either accept or reject any final deal. The parameters of the deal call for strict controls on Iran’s nuclear program for as long as 25 years. In return, sanctions imposed on Iran would be lifted once it was verified that Iranian officials had fulfilled their commitments. The deal sets the stage for negotiators to begin ironing out a final agreement by the end of June. Meanwhile, the White House is expected to attempt to sell the deal to lawmakers. A senior administration official said Thursday the White House’s main message to Congress is to give negotiators the space they need to cut a deal. President Barack Obama is open to discussions with lawmakers about how they will play an oversight role, the official said. Congress returns from a two-week break April 13.
2,143
<h4>PC’s key and it’s top of the agenda</h4><p><strong>WSJ 4/2</strong>/2015 (Congress Presses for Power to Review Any Final Iran Nuclear Deal, http://www.wsj.com/articles/congress-presses-for-power-to-review-any-final-iran-nuclear-deal-1428017616)</p><p><u>The White House has threatened to veto the review legislation, and <strong>its ability to</u></strong> get the bill altered or <u><strong>rally opposition</u></strong> against it in coming weeks <u><strong>will be a test of </u></strong>the <u><strong>confidence</u></strong> <u><strong>lawmakers have</u></strong> in the continuing negotiations with Iran. The Obama administration may have been helped by Wednesday’s indictment of Sen. Bob Menendez (D., N.J.) on allegations of corruption. Mr. Menendez, who has been outspoken in calling for a congressional review of any deal, has stepped down as the top Democrat on the foreign-relations panel while the legal process plays out. Senate Minority Leader Harry Reid (D., Nev.) cautioned against Congress taking immediate action on Iran-related legislation that could undermine the deal as negotiations continue until the June 30 deadline. “We have much to learn about what was negotiated and what will take place between now and the end of June,” Mr. Reid said, urging colleagues to “take a deep breath, examine the details and give this critically important process time to play out.” The White House and its Democratic allies in Congress have warned for more than a year against Congress taking steps such as imposing additional sanctions that could disrupt talks. But many Republicans, along with a number of Democrats, have increasingly called for lawmakers to have a greater role in the process, including the ability to review and either accept or reject any final deal. The parameters of the deal call for strict controls on Iran’s nuclear program for as long as 25 years. In return, sanctions imposed on Iran would be lifted once it was verified that Iranian officials had fulfilled their commitments. The deal sets the stage for negotiators to begin ironing out a final agreement by the end of June. Meanwhile, <u>the White House is expected to attempt to sell the deal to lawmakers</u>. A senior administration official said Thursday the White House’s <strong>main message to Congress is to give negotiators the space they need to cut a deal. President Barack Obama is open to discussions with lawmakers about how they will play an oversight role, the official said. Congress returns from a two-week break April 13.</p></strong>
1nr
Strikes
PC Key
430,577
1
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2
742,104
Plan costs an extraordinary amount of political capital, trades off with other legislative priorities
Downs 12
Downs 12 David, freelance journalist who has written for the new york times, rollingstone, and SF chronicle and specializes in cannabis policy; “What Obama and the Feds Will Do About Washington and Colorado Legalization – Expert Analysis” San Francisco Chronicle; November 13, 2012 http://blog.sfgate.com/smellthetruth/2012/11/13/what-obama-and-the-feds-will-do-about-washington-and-colorado-legalization-expert-analysis/
As much as he may want to reform drug laws on a personal level, Obama is nonetheless hampered by the heritage of an ugly racial history entwined with those same laws Given this history, the president would risk an extraordinary level of political capital on any proposed easing of federal law and other issues, rank higher on his list of legislative priorities.
As much as he may want to reform drug laws , Obama is hampered by the heritage of an ugly racial history entwined with those laws the president would risk an extraordinary level of political capital on any easing of federal law and other issues, rank higher on his list of legislative priorities
Perhaps. But there are plenty of other caveats to consider. As much as he may want to reform drug laws on a personal level, Obama is nonetheless hampered by the heritage of an ugly racial history entwined with those same laws since their inception (see discussion above). Given this history, the president would risk an extraordinary level of political capital on any proposed easing of federal law through legislative channels; and other issues, such as healthcare, the environment, and above all jobs appear to rank higher on his list of legislative priorities.
563
<h4>Plan costs an <u>extraordinary</u> amount of political capital, trades off with other legislative priorities</h4><p><strong>Downs 12 </strong>David, freelance journalist who has written for the new york times, rollingstone<u>, and SF chronicle and specializes in cannabis policy; “What Obama and the Feds Will Do About Washington and Colorado Legalization – Expert Analysis” San Francisco Chronicle; November 13, 2012 http://blog.sfgate.com/smellthetruth/2012/11/13/what-obama-and-the-feds-will-do-about-washington-and-colorado-legalization-expert-analysis/</p><p></u>Perhaps. But there are plenty of other caveats to consider. <u><mark>As much as he may want to reform drug laws </mark>on a personal level<mark>, Obama is</mark> nonetheless <mark>hampered by the heritage of an ugly racial history entwined with those</mark> same <mark>laws</u></mark> since their inception (see discussion above). <u>Given this history, <mark>the president would <strong>risk an extraordinary level of political capital</u></strong> <u>on any</mark> proposed <mark>easing of federal law</u></mark> through legislative channels; <u><mark>and</u></mark> <u><mark>other issues,</u></mark> such as healthcare, the environment, and above all jobs appear to <u><mark>rank higher on his list of</u></mark> <u><mark>legislative</mark> <mark>priorities<strong></mark>.</p></u></strong>
1nr
At: link
PC Key
305,170
62
17,068
./documents/ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
565,307
N
Ndt
1
Georgia Boyce-Feinberg
Bricker, Holland, McElhinny
null
ndtceda14/Dartmouth/KrMa/Dartmouth-Kreus-Martin-Neg-Ndt-Round1.docx
null
48,459
KrMa
Dartmouth KrMa
null
Da.....
Kr.....
Jo.....
Ma.....
18,764
Dartmouth
Dartmouth
null
null
1,004
ndtceda14
NDT/CEDA 2014-15
2,014
cx
college
2