Datasets:

Modalities:
Text
Formats:
text
Languages:
English
Libraries:
Datasets
License:
CoCoHD_transcripts / data /CHRG-115 /CHRG-115hhrg24670.txt
erikliu18's picture
Upload folder using huggingface_hub
93cf514 verified
<html>
<title> - AT WHAT COST? EXAMINING THE SOCIAL COST OF CARBON</title>
<body><pre>
[House Hearing, 115 Congress]
[From the U.S. Government Publishing Office]
AT WHAT COST? EXAMINING THE
SOCIAL COST OF CARBON
=======================================================================
JOINT HEARING
BEFORE THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ENVIRONMENT &
SUBCOMMITTEE ON OVERSIGHT
COMMITTEE ON SCIENCE, SPACE, AND TECHNOLOGY
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION
__________
FEBRUARY 28, 2017
__________
Serial No. 115-05
__________
Printed for the use of the Committee on Science, Space, and Technology
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Available via the World Wide Web: http://science.house.gov
______
U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE
24-670 PDF WASHINGTON : 2017
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Publishing
Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800;
DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC,
Washington, DC 20402-0001
COMMITTEE ON SCIENCE, SPACE, AND TECHNOLOGY
HON. LAMAR S. SMITH, Texas, Chair
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma EDDIE BERNICE JOHNSON, Texas
DANA ROHRABACHER, California ZOE LOFGREN, California
MO BROOKS, Alabama DANIEL LIPINSKI, Illinois
RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois SUZANNE BONAMICI, Oregon
BILL POSEY, Florida ALAN GRAYSON, Florida
THOMAS MASSIE, Kentucky AMI BERA, California
JIM BRIDENSTINE, Oklahoma ELIZABETH H. ESTY, Connecticut
RANDY K. WEBER, Texas MARC A. VEASEY, Texas
STEPHEN KNIGHT, California DONALD S. BEYER, JR., Virginia
BRIAN BABIN, Texas JACKY ROSEN, Nevada
BARBARA COMSTOCK, Virginia JERRY MCNERNEY, California
GARY PALMER, Alabama ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado
BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia PAUL TONKO, New York
RALPH LEE ABRAHAM, Louisiana BILL FOSTER, Illinois
DRAIN LaHOOD, Illinois MARK TAKANO, California
DANIEL WEBSTER, Florida COLLEEN HANABUSA, Hawaii
JIM BANKS, Indiana CHARLIE CRIST, Florida
ANDY BIGGS, Arizona
ROGER W. MARSHALL, Kansas
NEAL P. DUNN, Florida
CLAY HIGGINS, Louisiana
------
Subcommittee on Environment
HON. ANDY BIGGS, Arizona, Chair
DANA ROHRABACHER, California SUZANNE BONAMICI, Oregon, Ranking
BILL POSEY, Florida Member
MO BROOKS, Alabama COLLEEN HANABUSA, Hawaii
DANIEL WEBSTER, Florida CHARLIE CRIST, Florida
BRIAN BABIN, Texas EDDIE BERNICE JOHNSON, Texas
GARY PALMER, Alabama
BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia
JIM BANKS, Indiana
CLAY HIGGINS, Louisiana
LAMAR S. SMITH, Texas
------
Subcommittee on Oversight
HON. DRAIN LaHOOD, Illinois, Chair
BILL POSEY, Florida DONALD S. BEYER, Jr., Virginia,
THOMAS MASSIE, Kentucky Ranking Member
GARY PALMER, Alabama JERRY MCNERNEY, California
ROGER W. MARSHALL, Kansas ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado
CLAY HIGGINS, Louisiana EDDIE BERNICE JOHNSON, Texas
LAMAR S. SMITH, Texas
C O N T E N T S
February 28, 2017
Page
Witness List..................................................... 2
Hearing Charter.................................................. 3
Opening Statements
Statement by Representative Andy Biggs, Chairman, Subcommittee on
Environment, Committee on Science, Space, and Technology, U.S.
House of Representatives....................................... 4
Written Statement............................................ 6
Statement by Representative Suzanne Bonamic, Ranking Member,
Subcommittee on Environment, Committee on Science, Space, and
Technology, U.S. House of Representatives...................... 8
Written Statement............................................ 10
Statement by Representative Darin LaHood, Chairman, Subcommittee
on Oversight, Committee on Science, Space, and Technology, U.S.
House of Representatives....................................... 12
Written Statement............................................ 14
Statement by Representative Donald S. Beyer, Jr., Ranking Member,
Subcommittee on Oversight, Committee on Science, Space, and
Technology, U.S. House of Representatives...................... 16
Written Statement............................................ 18
Statement by Representative Lamar S. Smith, Chairman, Committee
on Science, Space, and Technology, U.S. House of
Representatives................................................ 20
Written Statement............................................ 22
Witnesses:
Dr. Ted Gayer, PhD, Vice President and Director of Economic
Studies and Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow at Brookings
Institution
Oral Statement............................................... 24
Written Statement............................................ 27
Dr. Kevin Dayaratna, PhD, Senior Statistician and Research
Programmer, Center for Data Analysis, Institute for Economic
Freedom and Opportunity at The Heritage Foundation
Oral Statement............................................... 34
Written Statement............................................ 36
Dr. Michael Greenstone, PhD, Milton Friedman Professor in
Economics, the College, and the Harris School; Director of the
interdisciplinary Energy Policy Institute at the University of
Chicago and the Energy & Environment Lab at the University of
Chicago Urban Labs
Oral Statement............................................... 50
Written Statement............................................ 52
Dr. Patrick Michaels, PhD, Director, Center for the Study of
Science, Cato Institute; contributing author to United Nations
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Nobel Peace Prize
2007)
Oral Statement............................................... 60
Written Statement............................................ 62
Discussion....................................................... 98
Appendix I: Answers to Post-Hearing Questions
Dr. Kevin Dayaratna, PhD, Senior Statistician and Research
Programmer, Center for Data Analysis, Institute for Economic
Freedom and Opportunity at The Heritage Foundation............. 124
Dr. Michael Greenstone, PhD, Milton Friedman Professor in
Economics, the College, and the Harris School; Director of the
interdisciplinary Energy Policy Institute at the University of
Chicago and the Energy & Environment Lab at the University of
Chicago Urban Labs............................................. 127
Appendix II: Additional Material for the Record
Statement submitted by Representative Eddie Bernice Johnson,
Ranking Member, Committee on Science, Space, and Technology,
U.S. House of Representatives.................................. 134
Document submitted by Representative Darin LaHood, Chairman,
Subcommittee on Oversight, Committee on Science, Space, and
Technology, U.S. House of Representatives...................... 136
AT WHAT COST? EXAMINING THE
SOCIAL COST OF CARBON
----------
TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 28, 2017
House of Representatives,
Subcommittee on Environment and
Subcommittee on Oversight,
Committee on Science, Space, and Technology,
Washington, D.C.
The Subcommittees met, pursuant to call, at 10:07 a.m., in
Room 2318, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Andy Biggs
[Chairman of the Subcommittee on Environment] presiding.
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Good morning. The Subcommittees on
Environment and Oversight will come to order.
Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare
recesses of the Subcommittee at any time.
Welcome to today's hearing entitled ``At What Cost?
Examining the Social Cost of Carbon.'' I recognize myself for
five minutes for an opening statement.
Welcome to today's joint subcommittee hearing entitled ``At
What Cost? Examining the Social Cost of Carbon.'' Today, we
will examine the previous Administration's determination of the
social cost of carbon, or SCC, and explore why the calculated
value is flawed.
Energy is the bedrock of our society, and yet the SCC
estimate of the previous Administration has killed jobs,
limited innovation, and resulted in higher energy costs for
American families, all in exchange for benefits that are
negligible at best and nonexistent at worst.
The Obama Administration's Interagency Working Group, which
ultimately established an enormously high SCC of $37 per ton of
CO<INF>2</INF> emitted into the atmosphere, relied on an
outdated economic model and failed to take into account the
White House's own Office of Management and Budget, or OMB,
guidelines for cost-benefit analysis. Quite simply, the working
group used numbers that got them the results they wanted in
order to advance some of the most expensive and expansive
regulations ever written. In pushing forward this political
agenda, the working group acted irresponsibly. It also allowed
the previous Administration to implement stringent and costly
regulations without a scientific basis.
As we will learn today, the SCC working group ignored two
major OMB recommendations for federal agency rulemaking. First,
it failed to use a seven percent discount rate, and instead
relied on rates of 2.5 percent, three percent, and five
percent. and, second, it ignored the guideline to report cost-
benefit analysis from a domestic perspective. If nothing else
is taken away from what will be a very technical hearing, I
hope it will be these two very basic flaws.
The low long-term discount rate established by the previous
Administration fundamentally disregards the notion that the
American economy is resilient and can respond to potential
future threats with technological development and innovation.
As to the flaw of the previous Administration's decision to
focus on CO<INF>2</INF> emissions from a global perspective,
this approach leaves the United States footing the bill for
costly regulations that are based on benefits conferred to
other countries. It is simply not right for Americans to be
bearing the brunt of costs when the majority of benefits will
be conferred away from home.
By ignoring OMB guidelines, the current SCC models leave
critical components out of the discussion. If the OMB
guidelines would have been followed, the social cost of carbon
would have been significantly lower.
The previous Administration disregarded scientific
integrity by overestimating climate change resulting from
greenhouse gas emissions. In order to push an expensive
regulatory agenda, the Administration inflated the SCC to
justify costly regulations in response to the allegedly
terrible damage CO<INF>2</INF> emissions will cause in the
future.
The SCC is nothing but a one-sided manipulation of
parameters to fit the policy-driven agendas of the previous
Administration. These alarmist tactics need to stop. Today's
hearing is intended to uncover the real truth and deception
behind the SCC.
America's strength emanates from our resilience and
flexibility. Attempts to justify government regulations over
industry innovations hinders growth and development. I look
forward to working with the Trump Administration to renew faith
in American ingenuity and technological development.
[The prepared statement of Chairman Biggs follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. I now recognize the Ranking member of the
Subcommittee on Environment, Ms. Bonamici, for an opening
statement.
Ms. Bonamici. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman, and thank
you to our witnesses for being here today.
The social cost of carbon is a metric used to value the
damage caused by emitting 1 ton of carbon dioxide into the
atmosphere in a year. It provides a consistent value for all
federal agencies to use for their cost-benefit analysis on
regulatory efforts that reduce carbon dioxide emissions.
There are some people who criticize this metric, but the
Government Accountability Office and independent peer review by
the National Academy of Sciences have validated it many times.
Additionally, federal courts have upheld that the methodology
used to develop the social cost of carbon is based on robust
science and sound economic analysis. It is critical that
updates to the social cost of carbon metric are based on the
best available science and updated economic analysis based on
peer-reviewed literature.
The Government Accountability Office has found that the
methodology used to develop the social cost of carbon was based
on peer-reviewed academic literature and took steps to
incorporate new information as it became available. This
process also provided ample opportunity for public comment on
both the social cost of carbon and the regulations that use the
metric in their cost-benefit analysis.
Some people suggest that regulations to reduce the
emissions of carbon dioxide and other pollutants are
unnecessary because climate change does not exist or human
activity does not contribute to it, but simply ignoring a fact
does not make it less true. The climate is warming, and we need
to work now to limit the consequences for future generations.
Our children and grandchildren should not inherit an
environment that degrades their health and harms their future
economy.
Economic growth and reducing carbon pollution are not in
conflict with one another. Clean energy development allows us
to continue powering our communities in ways that avoid long-
term negative consequences on future generations. It also gives
us the opportunity to bring new living-wage jobs into
communities. In fact, the American Wind Energy Association
found that the wind energy sector accounts for 3,000 jobs
throughout my home State of Oregon alone. In addition to
boosting Oregon's economy, wind energy generation avoided more
than 1 million tons of statewide carbon dioxide emissions in
2015, and many of the wind energy jobs are in rural areas where
jobs are needed.
The social cost of carbon is not a product of a single
President, a single scientific study, or a single legal action.
It is rooted in overwhelming scientific consensus on climate
change, an effort spanning 30 years from both the executive and
judicial branches of the Federal Government. These factors,
coupled with a transparent development process and strong
economic analysis, form the basis of this metric that has been
used in at least 79 federal regulations, including fuel economy
standards for vehicles, energy efficiency measures for home
appliances, and regulations such as the Clean Power Plan. This
metric was not invented to serve a political agenda but in fact
was developed to meet a legal mandate to justify, in simple
terms of dollars and cents, how the Federal Government's
actions will affect Americans today and our children and
grandchildren tomorrow.
I look forward to hearing how we may best continue to use
the social cost of carbon in support of policies that protect
our environment.
With that, I would like to again thank the witnesses for
being here today, and I yield back the balance of my time.
[The prepared statement of Ms. Bonamici follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Ms. Bonamici.
I now recognize the Chairman of the Subcommittee on
Oversight, Mr. LaHood, for his opening statement.
Mr. LaHood. Thank you, Chairman Biggs, and happy to be part
of this hearing today with you, today's hearing titled ``At
What Cost? Examining the Social Cost of Carbon,'' and happy to
have the witnesses here today as we examine the previous
Administration's social cost of carbon and the shortfalls in
application of this flawed process.
There is significant evidence that the previous
Administration manipulated the social cost of carbon
calculation to reflect significant benefits to enacting what
were ultimately job-killing regulations and policies across a
wide spectrum of issues. The social cost of carbon is a flawed
tool used by the Obama Administration to justify a green agenda
when, in reality, the prior Administration was seeking to
offset its costly regulations with far-reaching implications
that burden our industries and nation.
Unsurprisingly, the previous Administration ignored
specific guidelines set forth by the Office of Management and
Budget, OMB, and used the social cost of carbon as a vehicle to
tout the economic benefits of the new environmental
regulations. This is troubling and to me is not being honest
with the taxpayers.
Critics take issue primarily with two aspects of the social
cost of carbon methodology, specifically, the discount rate
used and the domestic versus global benefits claimed. Both
issues I look forward to discussing in more detail with our
panel of esteemed witnesses today.
I, too, take issue with the methodology but also the lack
of transparency with the use and development of the social cost
of carbon. Three statistical integrated assessment economic
models were used to develop the social cost of carbon: the
FUND, the DICE, and the PAGE. Experts have concluded these
three models are flawed and possess too many uncertainties to
be the foundation of the benefit analysis of environmental
regulations. If one were to change the assumptions these models
are based on, the result will drastically differ, demonstrating
malleability in the social cost of carbon calculation.
Because of these realities, last year, I was pleased to be
an original cosponsor of H.R. 5668, the Transparency and
Honesty in Energy Regulation Act, or THERA, introduced by my
friend and colleague Evan Jenkins of West Virginia. This
legislation is aimed at prohibiting the Department of Energy
and the Environmental Protection Agency from considering the
social cost of carbon as part of any cost-benefit analysis
unless specifically authorized by law. If signed into law, the
DOE and the EPA would no longer rely on manipulated and
fabricated economic benefits to justify or support new job-
killing environmental regulations. I look forward to working
with Congressman Jenkins again on this issue this Congress.
It appears that the social cost of carbon is nothing but a
political tool lacking scientific integrity and transparency
conceived and utilized by an Administration pushing a green
agenda to the detriment of the American taxpayers. Perhaps a
better measurement of the social cost of carbon is not the net
damages that result from a one-metric-ton increase in carbon
dioxide emissions in a given year but the damage inflicted on
domestic industries, including manufacturers in my district
like Caterpillar, by the environmental regulations justified by
this flawed calculation.
I would like to thank our witnesses for being here today to
discuss this important matter. In addition, I look forward
working with the Trump Administration to reverse the damage
caused by the Obama Administration as it relates to this issue.
With that, I yield back to the Chair.
[The prepared statement of Mr. LaHood follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Mr. LaHood.
I now recognize the Ranking Member of the Subcommittee on
Oversight, Mr. Beyer, for his opening statement.
Mr. Beyer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, all the
witnesses, for being here.
You know, the social cost of carbon is a complex metric
which our witness Dr. Greenstone has described as the most
important number you've never heard of. Assessing and
addressing the impact of climate change on current and future
generations is critical. It seems already that in just the
first few minutes of this hearing we see a dramatic difference
between the short-term emphasis on job creation, which is
important, and a long-term emphasis on protecting our planet.
The social cost of carbon permits the government to help
quantify the future economic damages as a result of carbon
pollution that contributes to climate change and global
warming. This metric didn't materialize out of thin and dirty
air. It took a federal judge to mandate its use during the Bush
Administration based on a law passed when Ronald Reagan was
President.
In 2009, the Obama Administration convened an interagency
effort to formalize a consistent value for it. This was not a
political tool. This was an attempt to protect our environment.
We'll hear today that this development process was
transparent, it was open to public comment, it's been validated
over the years, and, much like our climate, it's not static and
it changes over time in response to updated inputs. And
although its use has been challenged in the courts recently,
the courts have upheld the methodology used to obtain this
estimate as proper based on real science and appropriate
economic models.
As a Minnesota administrative law judge determined last
April, the preponderance of evidence supports the fact that
federal social cost of carbon is reasonable and the best
available measure to determine the environmental cost of
CO<INF>2</INF>. I'm pretty certain we won't hear any of that
today from the majority members and their witnesses. Instead,
we'll hear the same arguments made against climate regulations
that we've heard before. And sadly, those anti-science
arguments both ignore the abundant scientific evidence that
shows that climate change exists, that fossil fuel production
is its main contributor, and will also admonish virtually any
responsible regulatory mechanism to help protect our nation's
citizens from the environmental, economic, and public health
harm that results from climate change's global impacts.
These individuals will argue already that social cost of
carbon is outdated, inaccurate, and not a proper regulatory
mechanism for addressing climate change. We've heard these
arguments before. In fact, in 1982 the tobacco company R.J.
Reynolds produced internal talking points about the social cost
of smoking when Congressman Henry Waxman was holding hearings
regarding the harm to the public's health from cigarette
smoking. At the time, Representative Waxman said the annual
smoking-related cost in lost productivity was $25.8 billion and
$13.6 billion in annual medical costs. R.J. Reynolds said,
quote, that ``attempts to establish a dollar value of so-called
cost of smoking are ill-founded and unreliable,'' end quote.
More than one decade later, in 1994, the tobacco company
Philip Morris was producing glossy brochures to combat the
growing evidence revolving around the harm of cigarette
smoking. One was titled, quote, ``Debunking the Social Cost of
Smoking,'' and an internal memo from Philip Morris said simply,
``Philip Morris does not believe that smoking has been shown to
pose any social cost on society.''
So we're going to hear similar arguments today on the
social cost of carbon emissions from fossil fuels, their impact
on climate change. These arguments resonate loudly with the new
Trump Administration, but they contradict the economic analysis
and scientific evidence that supports the use of social cost of
carbon.
In a much-publicized recent memo, Dr.--or Thomas Pyle, the
head of Trump's Department of Energy transition team, stated,
quote, ``If the social cost of carbon were subjected to the
latest science, it would certainly be much lower than what the
Obama Administration has been using,'' end quote. And he
suggested ending the use of it in federal rulemaking. The memo
went on to describe plans to withdraw from the Paris Climate
Agreement, eliminate the Clean Power Plan, increase federal oil
and natural gas leasing, lift the moratorium on coal leasing--
in other words, more and more and more fossil fuels at greater
cost to the environment.
Mr. Chairman, climate change is real. Scientific evidence
across the world, we think we are the only country in the world
that doesn't--that has any internal disagreement about climate
change. And as members of the Science Committee, we should be
leading the fight to protect our nation against its impacts,
and I hope my colleagues will be persuaded by the weight of
evidence. The evidence becomes ever clearer with every passing
day. And we will work together to promote policies that protect
our future generations.
Mr. Chair, I yield back.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Beyer follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Mr. Beyer.
I now recognize the Chairman of the Full Committee, Mr.
Smith, for his opening statement. Chairman Smith.
Chairman Smith. Thank you, Chairman Biggs. And
congratulations on becoming the Chairman of the Environment
Subcommittee. I look forward to helping you restrain the EPA's
out-of-control regulatory agenda.
The EPA, along with other federal agencies, often bases
their regulations on models and science not familiar to most
Americans. Americans are led to believe that the EPA's
regulations are based on the best science available.
Unfortunately, this committee has discovered that that is not
the case.
The EPA's track record does not inspire trust. For example,
the EPA routinely relies on nondisclosed scientific studies to
justify its regulations, but how can Americans believe an
agency that isn't being open and honest?
Another little-known component of environmental regulations
is the social cost of carbon. The EPA attempts to put a price
on a ton of carbon emitted into the atmosphere. This term is in
many of the EPA's regulations. However, like many of the
Agency's determinations, it is often based on a one-sided
political agenda.
Many factors contribute to the value of the social cost of
carbon. While multiple models are used to determine a value for
carbon, the ones frequently used in regulations assume only a
worst-case scenario for climate change impacts. Similar to
climate models, which predict worst-case scenarios and are
repeatedly proved wrong, the social cost of carbon used by
federal agencies is also flawed.
The federal government should not include faulty
calculations to justify costly regulations. Examples would be
the Clean Power Plan and standards used by the Department of
Energy. Instead, it should eliminate the use of the social cost
of carbon until a credible value can be calculated.
Rushing to use unreliable calculations, such as the social
cost of carbon, to justify a regulation is irresponsible and
misleading. For instance, the EPA's Clean Power Plan would cost
billions of dollars every year in return for a minimal benefit
on the environment. In fact, the regulation would reduce global
temperatures by only 0.03 degrees Celsius and limit sea level
rise by only the width of three sheets of paper.
One of the many components used to justify this rule is the
social cost of carbon. This flawed value desperately attempts
to justify the Agency's alarmist reasoning for support of the
Clean Power Plan and other climate regulations. Agencies should
rely on sound science, not flawed data. The fact that different
models for the social cost of carbon exist and all have
different values is a testament to how uncertain the science
behind the value really is. For example, the social cost of
carbon ranges from negative values to $37 per ton, which is the
estimate used by government agencies under the Obama
Administration. Before the EPA includes this value in
rulemakings, the Agency should reassess how it is determined.
Americans deserve credible science, not regulations based
on data that is suspect and calculated to justify the EPA's
climate agenda. Sound science and actual data should lead the
way, not politically calculated social costs.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I'll yield back.
[The prepared statement of Chairman Smith follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Chairman Smith.
Let me introduce our witnesses. Our first witness today is
Dr. Ted Gayer, Vice President and Director of Economic Studies
and Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow at the Brookings Institute.
Dr. Gayer received his bachelor's degree in mathematics and
economics from Emory, and his master's degree and Ph.D. in
economics from Duke University.
Our next witness is Dr. Kevin Dayaratna, Senior
Statistician and Research Programmer at the Heritage
Foundation's Institute for Economic Freedom and Opportunities
Center for Data Analysis. Dr. Dayaratna received his bachelor's
degree in applied mathematics and mathematical physics from the
University of California at Berkeley, his master's degrees in
mathematical statistics and business management from the
University of Maryland, and his Ph.D. in mathematical
statistics from the University of Maryland.
Our third witness today is Dr. Michael Greenstone, Milton
Friedman Professor in Economics, the College, and the Harris
School; Director of the Interdisciplinary Energy Policy
Institute at the University of Chicago; and Director of the
Energy and Environment Lab at University of Chicago Urban Labs.
Dr. Greenstone received his bachelor's degree in economics at
Swarthmore College and his Ph.D. in economics from Princeton.
Our final witness today will be Dr. Patrick Michaels,
Director of the Center for the Study of Science at the Cato
Institute and contributing author to United Nations'
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, which was awarded
the Nobel Peace Prize. Dr. Michaels received his bachelor's and
master's degrees in biological sciences and plant ecology from
the University of Chicago and his Ph.D. in ecological
climatology from the University of Wisconsin at Madison.
I now recognize Dr. Gayer for five minutes to present his
testimony.
TESTIMONY OF DR. TED GAYER, PHD,
VICE PRESIDENT AND DIRECTOR OF ECONOMIC STUDIES
AND JOSEPH A. PECHMAN SENIOR FELLOW
AT BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
Dr. Gayer. Chairs Biggs, LaHood, and Smith; and Ranking
Members Bonamici and Beyer; and members of the subcommittees, I
appreciate the opportunity to appear here today to discuss the
social cost of carbon.
The social cost of carbon is a dollar estimate of the
damages caused by a 1-ton increase in greenhouse gas emissions
in a given year. It is a conceptually valid and important
consideration when devising policies and treaties to address
climate change, yet estimating the value of the social cost of
carbon is an enormously complex and uncertain exercise.
In 2009, the Obama Administration established an
Interagency Working Group to develop a range of estimates for
the social cost of carbon subsequently used by agencies to
evaluate federal regulations. My focus is on the specific
question of whether the social cost of carbon should account
for the global or the domestic harm of a ton of greenhouse gas.
In a world in which the United States and all the other
major emitters of greenhouse gases adopted a coordinated set of
policies to address climate change, then a global measure would
be appropriate since greenhouse gases contribute to damages
around the world no matter where they occur.
But we don't live in such a world. Instead, in the United
States we have opted for a suite of regulatory policies ranging
from subsidizing lower carbon energy sources; mandating energy
efficiency levels in buildings, vehicles, and household
appliances; requiring transportation fuels to contain minimum
volumes of different renewable fuels, and restricting emissions
from electric utilities.
Given the diversity of regulations directed at climate
change, it is useful and important for the agencies to
coordinate on a single measure of climate benefits. But the
question is whether they should report and consider the
benefits to U.S. citizens or to the world. The Interagency
Working Group opted for a global measure.
I believe the exclusive focus on a global measure runs
counter to standard benefit cost practice in which only the
benefits within the political jurisdiction bearing the cost of
the policy are considers. It also seems at odds with the
express intent of longstanding Executive orders and of
authorizing statutes. For example, the main regulatory guidance
document that has been in place for 20 years is Executive Order
12866, which makes clear that the appropriate reference point
for analyzing federal regulatory policy--policies is the U.S.
citizenry, not the world.
Similarly, when enacting the Clean Air Act, Congress stated
that its purpose was to, quote, ``protect and enhance the
quality of the nation's air resources so as to promote the
public health and welfare and productive capacity of its
population,'' end quote, which again suggests a focus on
domestic benefits.
The global measure is 4 to 14 times greater than the
estimated domestic measure, which is significant. For example,
for its proposed regulations for existing power plants, the EPA
estimated climate benefits amounting to $30 billion in 2030.
However, the estimated domestic climate benefits would have
only amounted to $2 to $7 billion, which is less than EPA's
estimated compliance cost for the rule.
I believe that adopting a global measure for the benefits
of a domestic policy would be justified if U.S. actions led to
complete reciprocity from other countries. The question is
whether efforts by the United States to regulate greenhouse
gases might spur reciprocity by other countries to do so as
well, generating domestic benefits that are 4 to 14 times as
great as the direct domestic benefits to the U.S.-only policy.
This is doubtful since the agency regulations taken under
existing U.S. laws such as the Clean Air Act are not tantamount
to treaty commitments that can establish a formal basis for
other countries matching the efforts undertaken domestically.
By using the global social cost of carbon, the agencies are
claiming that their rules provide benefits that in fact largely
accrue to foreign citizens. Of course, many Americans are
altruistic and care about the welfare of people beyond our
borders, but foreign aid decisions should be made openly and
not hidden in an obscure metric used in domestic rulemaking.
A global measure of the social cost of carbon is
appropriate if the intent is to use it to support the
development of a global system of reducing greenhouse gases,
such as through a worldwide carbon tax. I favor a carbon tax
for the United States that replaces regulations and relies on
border tax adjustments to incentivize other major emitters to
follow suit. But absent such an approach, for domestic agencies
considering domestic regulations in which the costs are
incurred domestically, a global measure deviates from standard
practice and requires more scrutiny and justification than it
has received to date. At the very least, agencies should report
the expected domestic benefits and only separately and
transparently report the expected foreign benefits of their
actions informed by concrete evidence of reciprocity expected
from other countries.
Thank you.
[The prepared statement of Dr. Gayer follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Dr. Gayer.
I now recognize Dr. Dayaratna for five minutes to present
his testimony.
TESTIMONY OF DR. KEVIN DAYARATNA, PHD,
SENIOR STATISTICIAN AND RESEARCH PROGRAMMER,
CENTER FOR DATA ANALYSIS,
INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC FREEDOM
AND OPPORTUNITY AT THE HERITAGE FOUNDATION
Dr. Dayaratna. Chairman Biggs, Ranking Member Bonamici, and
other Members of the Subcommittees, thank you for the
opportunity to testify about the social cost of carbon.
My name is Kevin Dayaratna. I'm the Senior Statistician and
Research Programmer at the Heritage Foundation. The views I
express in this testimony are my own and should not be
construed as representing any official position of the Heritage
Foundation.
One of the primary metrics that the previous Administration
had used to justify agenda regarding energy policy--justify
regulatory--its regulatory agenda regarding energy policy is
the social cost of carbon, which is defined as the economic
damages associated with a metric ton of carbon dioxide
emissions summed across a particular time horizon.
There are three primary statistical models that the Obama
Administration's Interagency Working Group had used to estimate
the SCC, the DC. model, the FUND model, and the PAGE model. My
colleagues and I have used the DC. and FUND models, testing
their sensitivity to a variety of important assumptions. Our
work, published both at Heritage, as well as in the peer-
reviewed literature, as repeatedly illustrated that while these
models might be interesting for academic exercises, they can be
readily manipulated by regulators and bureaucrats.
In particular, as with any statistical model, they are
dependent on various assumptions. I'd like to discuss three
assumptions regularly manipulated to achieve predetermined
outcomes: the choice of a discount rate, a time horizon, and
the specification of an equilibrium climate sensitivity
distribution.
The first easily manipulated assumption is the discount
rate. In this type of cost-benefit analysis, the discount rate
should reflect the rate of return on generally achievable
alternative investments. The IWG had run these models using
2.5, 3, and five percent discount rates despite the fact that
OMB guidance in circular A-4 had specifically stipulated that a
seven percent discount rate be used as well.
At Heritage, we re-estimated these models using a seven
percent discount rate and noticed drastic reductions to the
SCC. In 2020, for example, according to our recent analysis of
the DC. model published in the peer-reviewed journal Climate
Change Economics, under a three percent discount rate, the SCC
is estimated to cost $37.79 per ton, while under a seven
percent discount rate, it is estimated to be $5.87, an 84
percent reduction. The higher estimates previously found by the
IWG can enable policymakers to justify unnecessary regulations
and taxes on the economy.
The second easily manipulated assumption is the
specification of a time horizon. It is close to impossible to
forecast what the economy will look like decades into the
future. Foolishly, these models attempt to make projections not
decades but rather three centuries into the future. In my work
at Heritage, I have changed the time horizon to a significantly
shorter but still unrealistic time horizon of 150 years into
the future. With the DC. model, we find that these results
plummet by 25 percent in some instances.
The third readily manipulated variable is the model's
equilibrium climate sensitivity, or ECS, distribution,
quantifying the Earth's temperature response to a doubling of
carbon dioxide concentration. My colleague Dr. Pat Michaels
will go into this in more detail, but the IWG used an ECS
distribution that was published ten years ago in the journal
Science. Since then, a number of newer ECS distributions have
been published suggesting lower probabilities of extreme global
warming.
Using the more up-to-date ECS distributions generate
significantly lower estimates of the SCC. In our peer-reviewed
work, we found that, as a result of updating the ECS
distributions, the results drop by as much as 197 percent under
some circumstances. Inflated estimates of climate sensitivity
drive up the SCC, which can become manifested in unnecessary
regulations.
Finally, the unexplored issue here is are there any
benefits associated with carbon dioxide emissions? The answer
is surprisingly yes. The FUND model actually allows for
negative SCC, meaning a positive outcome. In fact, under some
assumptions, there are actual substantial probabilities of
negative SCC, meaning increased CO<INF>2</INF> fertilization,
leading to increased agriculture and forestry yields.
Moreover, if one were to take the IWG's interpretation of
these models seriously and implement the associated
regulations, there would be significant damage to the economy.
In particular, our analysis finds that by 2035 the country
would experience an average employment shortfall of 400,000
lost jobs, a marked increase in electricity prices, and an
aggregate $2.5 trillion loss in GDP.
Our analysis using the model for the assessment of
greenhouse gas-induced climate change has found that these
devastating impacts would be accompanied by insignificant
changes and less than 2/10 of a degree Celsius in temperature
mitigation and less than 2 centimeters of sea level rise
reduction.
In conclusion, the SCC is a broken tool for regulatory
policy and taking it seriously would provide significant harm
and little environmental benefit.
Thank you for your attention, and I look forward to your
questions.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Dayaratna follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Dr. Dayaratna.
I now recognize Dr. Greenstone for five minutes to present
his testimony.
TESTIMONY OF DR. MICHAEL GREENSTONE, PHD,
MILTON FRIEDMAN PROFESSOR IN ECONOMICS,
THE COLLEGE, AND THE HARRIS SCHOOL;
DIRECTOR OF THE INTERDISCIPLINARY
ENERGY POLICY INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO
AND THE ENERGY & ENVIRONMENT LAB
AT THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO URBAN LABS
Dr. Greenstone. Thank you, Chairmen Biggs and LaHood,
Ranking Members Bonamici and Beyer, and Members of the
Subcommittees, for inviting me to speak today.
My name is Michael Greenstone, and I'm the Milton Friedman
Professor in Economics and Director of the Energy Policy
Institute at the University of Chicago.
The social cost of carbon is a monetized value of the
damages from the release of an additional ton of
CO<INF>2</INF>. This means that it can be used to determine the
benefits of regulations that reduce CO<INF>2</INF> emissions.
Indeed, these benefits can then be compared to the costs that
regulations impose to determine whether the regulation is
beneficial or not.
In 2009, while working in the Obama Administration, Cass
Sunstein and I convened and co-led an Interagency Working Group
to determine a government-wide value for the social cost of
carbon. Ultimately, the Interagency Working Group determined a
central estimate of $21 per metric ton. That estimate has since
been revised to reflect scientific advances and is now about
$36.
The approach has been judged valid. Last August, the
Federal Court of Appeals rejected a legal challenge to the
metric. Further, the General Accounting Office has said that
the working group's processes and methods reflected key
principles that ensured its credibility: It used consensus-
based decision-making, relied largely on existing academic
literature and models; and disclosed limitations and
incorporated new information by considering public comments and
revising the estimates as updated research became available.
Indeed, the social cost of carbon's credibility is
underscored by the fact that it has been adopted by the
governments of California, Illinois, Minnesota, Maine, New
York, and Washington State, not to mention Canada and Mexico.
Before concluding my testimony today, I would like to
address two frequent critiques of the social cost of carbon.
One such critique is that the real discount rates used--2.5, 3,
and 5 percent--are too low. Why is a discount rate so
important? If we choose a discount rate that is too low, then
we're going to pay too much for mitigation efforts today. If
instead we choose one that's too high, then we will impose
higher climate damages on our children and grandchildren than
we intend.
Economic theory tells us that we'll be best off if the
discount rate is equal to the market interest rate from
investments that match the structure of payoffs that climate
mitigation provides. If we thought climate damages were likely
to be imposed consistently and predictably over time, then it
would be appropriate to set a discount rate equal to something
like the average return for the stock market. That's about 5.3
percent over the last 50 years.
But, on the other hand, if we think climate damages could
be unpredictable and that tail risk points towards major
losses, then markets, markets themselves, tell us to use a
lower discount rate. Consider the case of gold. Its average
return is only about three percent, yet people hold it as an
investment. Why is that? The reason is that it pays off
dramatically during infrequent episodes of economic distress.
For example, during the Great Recession, gold outperformed the
stock market by 67 percent.
When one considers the possibility of large temperature
changes for given increases in emissions, great sea level rise
in relatively short periods of time, the possibility of
physical tipping points or human responses to these changes
that include mass migration, then the case for using a low
discount rate to determine the social cost of carbon appears
strong.
In addition to this conceptual reason to prefer low
discount rates, the decline in global interest rates, so
another market-based reason, since the mid-1980s provides
another reason. The three percent real discount rate that has
been a cornerstone of regulatory analysis since 2003 draws its
justification from the fact that it was roughly equal to the
real rate of return on long-term government debt at that time.
However, the world has changed. Rates are now much lower
and indeed the comparable rate is now probably below two
percent. Put another way, capital markets are trying to tell us
to use discount rates that are lower than those currently being
used to determine the social cost of carbon.
A second criticism of the social cost of carbon is that it
reflects global costs from emissions, but the United States
should only be concerned with domestic damages. However, this
criticism misses an important point that the goal of policy is
to maximize net benefits to Americans and that recognizing
foreign damages is likely to increase net benefits.
Why is this the case? It's because each ton of CO<INF>2</INF>
emitted outside the United States inflicts damages on us. Thus,
we benefit when China, India, the European Union, and others
reduce their emissions. It absolutely strains credibility to
assume that these countries' emissions cuts would be as large
as if we reverted to a social cost of carbon based only on
domestic damages.
In many respects, the Paris Climate Agreement, where nearly
200 countries agreed to take action on carbon emissions, is a
validation of the importance of treating climate change is a
global problem.
To summarize, society needs to balance the cost to our
economy of mitigating climate change with the coming climate
damages. Wishing that we did not face this tradeoff will not
make it go away. Ultimately, we will be better off if a social
cost of carbon based on sound science, economics, and law,
continues to serve as a lynchpin of regulatory policy. Thank
you.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Greenstone follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Dr. Greenstone.
I'll now recognize Dr. Michaels for five minutes to present
his testimony.
TESTIMONY OF DR. PATRICK MICHAELS, PHD, DIRECTOR,
CENTER FOR THE STUDY OF SCIENCE, CATO INSTITUTE;
CONTRIBUTING AUTHOR TO UNITED NATIONS
INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE
(NOBEL PEACE PRIZE 2007)
Dr. Michaels. May we have the first image? Thank you.
[Slide.]
Dr. Michaels. Mr. Chairman, Ranking Members, Members of the
Subcommittees, thank you for inviting my testimony on
scientific problems relating to the current calculation of the
social cost of carbon or SCC. I am Patrick J. Michaels,
Director of the Center for the Study of Science at the Cato
Institute. Prior to that, I was a Research Professor of
Environmental Sciences at University of Virginia for 30 years.
A year-and-a-half ago I testified to the Committee on
Natural Resources that the Obama Administration's calculations
of the SCC were in contravention of a large and growing body of
scientific literature--next image----
[Slide.]
--demonstrating that the sensitivity of temperature to
human emission of carbon dioxide is not nearly as large as was
previously thought. And more important, the chance of a high-
end warming has greatly diminished. Since then, the evidence
has grown stronger.
Climate sensitivity is the amount of net warming one gets
for doubling atmospheric carbon dioxide. It also roughly
approximates the forecast for surface warming for the 21st
century. The Obama Administration used a sensitivity
specification by Roe and Baker, which is the top line there,
that had a mean sensitivity of 3.0 degrees C and a 5 to 95
percent confidence limit of 1.7 to 7.14 degrees C, a very large
number.
Beginning in 2011, all this work down here, a growing body
of the scientific literature has yielded 32 new estimates of
the sensitivity generated by more than 50 researchers from
around the world with a mean sensitivity of 2 degrees C and a 5
to 95 percent confidence limit of 1.1 to 3.5 degrees C.
The large distributions of warming--next image--
[Slide.]
--used in Roe and Baker resulted in large part because of
extremely wide range of estimates of the cooling effects of
sulfate aerosols, another human emission. These were
dramatically narrowed by researchers Nick Lewis and Judith
Curry of Georgia Tech, which greatly reduced the sensitivity,
as you can see here, and the spread around that sensitivity.
As my colleague Kevin Dayaratna has shown, the newer more
reality-based estimates result in a dramatic lowering of the
SCC. Next image.
[Slide.]
Let's now have a look at how well those climate models that
were used to calculate the previous Administration's SCC are
doing. This illustration is a further update of an analysis
initially presented in the testimony of John Christy in 2015
with data that ended in 2014. The uptick in observed warming at
the end of the record is an apparent improvement between the
models and reality. But it is not. Instead, it is the 2015/2016
El Nino.
Next image.
[Slide.]
And that spread is likely to widen again in recent years,
as you can see from surface temperatures here that they have
dropped back down very close to their previous El Nino value.
[Slide.]
Next is a chart of predicted trends and tropical
temperatures measured vertically. This is where the largest
integrated warming on Earth is forecast to occur. The green
line on the left is reality, which is--generally shows two to
three times less warming than has been predicted. At the top of
the active weather zone around here, the forecast is
approximately seven times less than--or seven times more than
is what is being observed. To deny this reality is to deny
science.
It is the vertical temperature distribution that largely
determines daily weather. If this is forecast incorrectly, then
any subsidiary forecast of surface weather regimes are of
little to no value. To deny that is to deny science.
There is another systematic error on the previous
calculations of the SCC. We live on a planet that is becoming
greener because of the direct--next image----
[Slide.]
--physiological effects of increasing carbon dioxide on
plant photosynthesis. A massive survey of the scientific
literature by Dr. Craig Idso shows this caused a $3.2 trillion
increment in agricultural output from 1961 through 2011. My
colleague Mr. Dayaratna has shown that a more realistic
sensitivity in carbon dioxide fertilization can result in a
negative SCC or a net external benefit from the production of
carbon dioxide.
In closing, I provide you this image of the greening of our
luke-warming home planet, as taken by NASA satellites. Where
there are dots, the changes are statistically significant. Note
that the greatest increases, the ones in pink, are in the
margins of the world's deserts and the tropical rainforest,
places we all feared for. To acknowledge this is to affirm
reality.
Thank you very much for inviting my testimony.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Michaels follows:]
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. I thank each of the witnesses
for their testimony today. The Chair recognizes himself for
five minutes.
Dr. Gayer, because the Interagency Working Group ignored
Office of Management and Budget guidelines and used a global
perspective in determining the SCC, agencies issue regulations
with substantial domestic cost based on benefits to non-
Americans. In what way does this global perspective method of
calculating the SCC potentially mislead the public?
Dr. Gayer. So I'll answer in two parts. First, the--it's--
the models that are discussed here today are global models, so
it's inordinately difficult for them to come up with domestic
estimates, but the interagency review--interagency process did
kind of benchmark it to 4 to 14 times differential. So the
domestic benefits are 1/4 to 1/14 what the global benefits are
based on the models that they used.
And just to clarify, based on comment earlier, I think the
approach should be taken, if it is going to use a global
measure, it is not a zero-one, right? You could use a domestic
measure, you can use a full global measure. Michael referred to
straining credibility to assume that there's no global
benefits. I think it strains credibility to suggest that
there's going to be full global benefits, meaning if we act,
the rest of the world will act instantaneously as well.
So to the extent that that doesn't happen and we're using a
domestic measure, we're overestimating the benefits. And the
example I gave with the Clean Power Plan on the climate benefit
side, it's enough to tip the scales that the costs outweigh the
benefits.
Chairman Biggs. And, Dr. Gayer, just to follow up, do
agencies have a duty to inform the American public of the
domestic benefits in a cost-benefit analysis for federal
regulations?
Dr. Gayer. Yes. And those are the OMB guidelines. As I
suggested at the end, I think I'd be less kind of worked up
over it if they did both, but they should lead with the
domestic measure.
Chairman Biggs. Dr. Dayaratna, what are your biggest
concerns about using the SCC in policymaking?
Dr. Dayaratna. Thank you for the question, Congressman.
So there are a variety of issues with these SCCs, with
these IAMs associated with these SCCs. The most fundamental
issue is that they are extremely sensitive to very, very
reasonable changes in assumptions. As I was referring to, the
time--using the time horizon to 300 years, if you shift that to
150 years, which is still unrealistic, you get a drastically
different estimate of the SCC.
The discount rate, if you use a seven percent discount
rate, as mandated by the OMB, under the FUND model you will get
a negative social cost of carbon. And the policy implication
there would be that we shouldn't be taxing carbon dioxide
emissions but subsidizing it.
Then lastly, with the equilibrium climate sensitivity
distributions, there--the ECS distribution used has--was
published ten years ago, and it's not even based on empirical
research. More up-to-date ECS distributions also will result in
a substantially lower and even potentially negative SCC
depending on the model that you use.
So with these results all over the map, I do not understand
how policymakers can garner any meaningful advice for
regulatory policy.
Chairman Biggs. So just for the laymen who are here, what
does the negative value of the SCC kind of connote? I mean,
what are we really saying there when we say negative value?
Dr. Dayaratna. Basically, in a nutshell, in general when
people think of SCC they talk about economic damages associated
with carbon dioxide emissions. When those damages are negative,
that implies that the SCC actually provides benefits. And the
result of that is, you know, mostly increased photosynthesis,
agriculture, and so forth. But that would suggest that
increased CO<INF>2</INF> is actually good for the planet.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. Dr. Michaels, in 2015 the
Interagency Working Group released a report to the public
comments on the determination of the social cost of carbon. You
were one of the commenters. What is the significance of having
a comment period in the process of developing an SCC? And did
the interagency group adopt any of these comments?
Dr. Michaels. No, they did not, and many of the comments
were well-reasoned based upon recent peer-reviewed literature
reinforcing the notion that the sensitivity of temperature that
was used in the models was too high. Nature is trying to tell
us something. If you look at that satellite image that I showed
earlier, you can see that the observed warming in the lower
atmosphere is about half of what was predicted. If you look in
the tropics, you can see that the observed warming in the
vertical in the tropics is about half, actually maybe even a
little bit less than what was predicted. All these things point
to a consistent story. About twice as much warming was
predicted as is going to occur.
Now, the U.N.'s mean sensitivity is 3.2 degrees Celsius.
Why don't we settle this out at 1.6, and everybody can go home
because we're going to meet the 2 degree guideline with
business as usual, declare victory, and let's go on.
Chairman Biggs. So when the report refused to adopt any of
the comments, what does that say to the validity of the report
and its objectivity?
Dr. Michaels. I would say that they were wedded to a point
of view, and I understand. I live in Washington. I understand
the pressures in this town. If anyone gave an official answer
that this was not a problem, I hate to say we probably wouldn't
be chatting here so amiably because nobody would care.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Dr. Michaels.
I recognize Ranking Member Bonamici for questions.
Ms. Bonamici. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Dr. Greenstone, it's been suggested that the Interagency
Working Group operated under some sort of veil of secrecy while
developing the social cost of carbon. The GAO, in a 2014
report, found that many of the social cost of carbon estimates
were developed with input from the public. Now, you and Cass
Sunstein convened and led this Interagency Working Group. So
did the Interagency Working Group hear concerns that were
raised by the other witnesses today, and how were those
considered in the process? And can you also talk about the role
that public comment played in the development of the social
cost of carbon?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. Thank you, Congresswoman, for letting
me talk about that. So it's probably worth going back in time a
little bit. The process--the social cost of carbon was
developed in a very methodical way. The--we convened and led
this group that met many times and it drew expertise from
agencies across the Administration. We then first put out--the
first put-out was an interim number that was put out for public
comment. Then, the final number of $21 was released in 2010.
That has been attached to, I think, approximately 80 different
rules. Public comment was received on that through that
process. And then the Administration later I think in 2013 just
put it out for public comment by itself.
So there was tremendous effort to engage the public. There
was tremendous effort to draw expertise from all corners of
government, and it was a highly technical exercise that led to
what we perceive to be and I believe to be describing the
frontier of science.
Now, it is possible that some of my fellow witnesses feel
spurned, and I think that's why we often use peer-reviewed
literatures to determine what's true and what's not true. And I
think just because their ideas were not judged to be on the
frontier does not mean that the whole process was flawed.
Ms. Bonamici. Thank you. And, Dr. Greenstone, just because
a comment is made and received but not included does not mean
it was not considered, correct?
Dr. Greenstone. Indeed.
Ms. Bonamici. So, Dr. Greenstone, Dr. Dayaratna said that
if the social cost of carbon was implemented, the country would
suffer--I believe it was--he said disastrous economic
consequences, including a loss of jobs and income and an
increase in electricity prices. I'd like you to address what
would happen if indeed the Trump Administration has been
promoting energy policies without regard to what the policies
may do to the environment. So will you explain what would
happen if we were to roll back regulations designed to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions, if there's an economic price to pay
for undermining the science supporting the social cost of
carbon and environmental regulations? And also, how would other
countries like China or India respond if the United States
retreats from or even appears to be retreating from its
obligations to address greenhouse gas emissions?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. So I think Dr. Dayaratna is making a
very important point, which is that regulations have costs, so
we should all agree on that and we should--we can move on.
On the flipside of that is that regulations to reduce
carbon emissions have benefits, and there's--it's a tradeoff,
like many things in economics. There's no free lunch. And, you
know, if we were to roll back regulations on climate emissions
or carbon emissions, what we would--the world would face and
certainly the United States would face higher temperatures; it
would face sea level rise. It would face a variety of risks
that would impose costs on us, our children, and our
grandchildren.
And let me just also return--you also asked, Congresswoman,
about how it would be perceived globally if we reverted to a
domestic social cost of carbon, and I think that's an important
question because it's not--what--a narrative here about using
the domestic damages only I think misses that this is an
international problem. And in particular when--as I said in my
testimony, when China or India or the EU reduces emissions, it
gives great benefits to the citizens of the United States. And
to not account for that leverage puts us at risk of higher
costs.
And so I think the case for reverting to a domestic-only
damage is essentially asking the rest of the world to ramp up
their measures.
Ms. Bonamici. And finally, I know the recent National
Academy of Sciences report ``Valuing Climate Damages: Updating
Estimation of the Social Cost of Carbon'' provides some
recommendations to the Interagency Working Group on how to
improve the methodology. Do the recommendations for an updated
estimation undermine the current working group values of the
social cost of carbon or would using the Academy's
recommendation methodology invalidate existing regulations----
Dr. Greenstone. No, the----
Ms. Bonamici. --that use the----
Dr. Greenstone. Thank you for that question. I think rather
than have people cherry-pick particular features, which seems
to be what's happening today, that they dislike or that they
know can change the social cost of carbon, a methodical and
scientific approach would be to follow the National Academy of
Sciences' recommendations. And indeed, in the Interagency
Working Group, we suggested that, as science advanced, the
numbers should be updated periodically. And the National
Academy of Sciences' report gives a terrific blueprint that
would allow for updating.
And, you know, it is true things have advanced since 2009
and 2010. Our understanding about the impacts of climate
change, for instance, on human mortality have greatly advanced.
And I expected a--following NAS's blueprint would allow for a
refresh.
Ms. Bonamici. Thank you. My time is expired. I yield back.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
Dr. Michaels, you wish to respond?
Dr. Michaels. Yes, I think it's time to actually take a
good, clear look at the effect of policies with regard to the
Paris agreement. The EPA uses a model called the Model for the
Assessment of Greenhouse Gas-Induced Climate Change. And if
you're following, the acronym for that model is MAGIC. It is
the standard tool that is used. And you can put in emissions
scenarios, climate sensitivity, and come out with a temperature
saving as a result of any given policy.
So let's assume a sensitivity that is probably too high, 3
degrees Celsius, and let's reduce United States' emissions to
zero right now through the year 2100. The amount of warming
that would be prevented would be between 1/10 and 2/10 of a
degree Celsius.
Now, let's talk about China and India candidly rather than
merely using adjectives and adverbs. The Chinese emission
commitments at the Paris agreement are nothing but business as
usual. It has long been recognized as their economy matures
that their emissions will stabilize around 2030, and that is
precisely what they said they would do.
The Indian commitment is less than nothing. As economies
mature, the amount of CO<INF>2</INF> you emit per unit GDP
declines. It's called an increase--or a decrease in emissions
intensity. They vowed in Paris to decrease their emissions
intensity less, underline less, than the business-as-usual
scenario for the country of India.
So really what we do doesn't mean anything to these other
countries because they're not doing anything. Thank you.
Chairman Biggs. I recognize the Chairman of the Oversight
Committee, LaHood, for his five minutes of questions.
Mr. LaHood. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to thank all
the witnesses for being here today and your valuable testimony.
Dr. Gayer, I wanted to ask you, you know, as we try to
better understand what Congress and the Trump Administration
can do to make agency rulemaking based on more accurate cost-
and-benefit information, I do have concerns--I'm not sure
whether you're familiar--last year, the Seventh Circuit Court
of Appeals, the federal jurisdiction, ruled in a unanimous
decision basically against the petitioners, which was an
organization by the name of Zero Zone, which is an air-
conditioning/heating unit that sued the Department of Energy
based on the rulemaking process. And that unanimous decision,
their conclusion--and I'm summarizing here--but the DOE
conducted a cost-benefit analysis that is within the statutory
authority and is supported by substantial evidence. Its
methodology and conclusions were not arbitrary or capricious.
And I guess do you have concerns that the court did not
criticize this process in this court case?
Dr. Gayer. Thank you for the question.
I feel like I'm in a funny position in many ways. If you
lock me and Michael Greenstone in a room, I'm not sure that
we'd come up with a very different policy outcome. But I think
the process of getting there matters, and I think the
regulatory process that was used did involve a lot of
assumptions and complexities that I would say lean into
arbitrary considerations.
That's not to say I think that the social cost of carbon,
this true number out there is negative; I don't. And as I
alluded to in my testimony, I do think we should act. I just
don't think we should act through kind of the mechanisms of
existing statutes through regulations that take a very
piecemeal approach and to my mind sort of put a veneer of
scientific legitimacy on something that I think is highly,
highly uncertain. So that's a longwinded way of me getting at
your question, so I apologize.
Yes, I'm concerned when the courts disagree with me to some
degree. I don't know what--you know, in the kind of motivation
of your question, we are existing in a world where all the
action on climate is happening under existing statutes and
therefore do--and going through the agencies. And so to the
extent that there's too much focus on global, not domestic, I
do think it's addressable from Office of Information and
Regulatory Affairs and guidance given to the agencies about how
they should conduct this.
And I don't want to speak for other people on the panel,
but I think there is, you know, a lot of discretion in the
choices that were made in how we come up with these numbers. I
don't think it was kind of rigged or deception or manipulated.
I just think that people disagree. And I think with the new
Administration and new OMB and OIRA Director, they can come to
a different determination of how much to weigh global versus
domestic, as well as issues like discount rates and others,
which is a highly difficult, complex, in many ways ethical
question.
Mr. LaHood. Well, thank you for that.
And just as a follow-up, I think in your opening testimony
you went through kind of, you described it as a suite of
regulatory policies that we put in place domestically that, you
know, have worked fairly well with reducing some of those
environmental concerns that people talked about.
In terms of a public policy position here in Congress on
what we should do, beyond what you said with working in the
Administration, any recommendations for us here in terms of
legislation and what we should look at to address this problem?
Dr. Gayer. Well, I think I--you know, I have an
iconoclastic view perhaps on this. I first approached this
problem because I thought a lot of these regulations--not
because I didn't think climate change was a problem but I
thought these regulations were much too costly way to go about
doing it. And in the analysis that they were using to justify
it, I thought they were in some sense making decisions I
disagreed with to make them look better than they are.
I testified actually at the House a few years ago. A lot of
these regulations are justified not on environmental grounds
but because they purport to save consumers money because the
underlying thesis there is that consumers are kind of
irrational in their consumption decisions, so therefore, you
know, the regulator has to come and make the decision for them,
which is to my mind kind of a dangerous assumption and
shouldn't be used to justify rules.
I have the kind of minority opinion on what should be done,
but I think it should go through Congress. I, as I said before,
favor kind of a trade for a carbon tax on one side that's
revenue-neutral, meaning affording a tax cut and also lighter
regulations so that we're not going to the regulatory approach,
as we currently have been.
Mr. LaHood. Thank you. Those are all my questions.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
I recognize Mr. Beyer for five minutes.
Mr. Beyer. Yes, Thank you, Mr. Chairman, very much.
Thank you all very much for being here. It's fun to have
three economists and mathematicians, which we don't often get
and a bona fide Ph.D. climatologist. And I want to thank all of
you for recognizing that climate change is in fact real. You
may have different notions of is it as fast as it was, but this
is a great leap forward for the Committee and for America.
And I'm particularly pleased that Dr. Greenstone is the
Milton Friedman Professor of Economics, which should make all
of my Republican friends very comfortable and happy. And I
thank Dr. Gayer for the quote that says that ``The social cost
of carbon is a conceptually valid and important consideration
when devising policies and treaties to address climate
change.''
Dr. Greenstone, the two things that have come up again and
again--in fact, our Chairman's opening statement was, number
one, this whole notion of the appropriate discount rate. And
you said--you quoted the appropriate discount rate comes down
to a judgment about whether climate change involves a
substantial risk of being disruptive. Now, the OMB has a
circular that says we should use seven percent. Why the
decision to ignore the seven percent. Can you tell us simply
again why we would choose a number like three percent rather
than a 7?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes, thank you for your question, Mr.
Congressman.
So the discount rate is, as Dr. Gayer mentioned, it's a
very tough issue. With respect to climate change or with
respect to any public investment, what one would like to do is
to use a discount rate where--that reflects an interest rate
from the market where the payoffs from that investment are
similar to the payoffs from climate mitigation.
And if you think--when you start to think about what
climate change might offer, and a lot of it is unknown--as you
put it, it could be very disruptive--that would tend to push
people to lower discount rates and lower interest rates. And as
I said in my testimony, the example of gold is really a good
one in the sense that people are willing to hold gold. It has a
very low mean rate of return of about three percent, but the
reason they're willing to hold it is because it pays off when
times are bad. And so if we end up with a bad state of the
world with respect to climate, I think that would push us to
having--wish we'd used the low discount rate.
It's also worth noting that we're having a somewhat
artificial discussion about the 3 and seven percent. Those were
set in 2003 when global capital markets looked extraordinarily
different than they do today. If we were to instead use what
global capital markets are trying to tell us now, the three
percent number would very likely be below two percent. That is
that's the return on a long--on a long-term government bond.
That is a real return. The real return is probably less than
two percent to be honest. And there--the seven percent number
would also be much lower as well.
So, ultimately, we chose to go with 3 and five percent to
reflect the character of the climate problem.
Mr. Beyer. Okay. Great. Thanks.
The second half of that is that there are apparently--
according to the majority memo--longstanding OMB guidance to
only consider the domestic cost-benefits. And Dr. Gayer I think
went on pretty eloquently about, you know, we're considering
what's happening around the world, but they're not necessarily
affecting their policies. How would you justify the notion of
using a global measure of the impacts?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. So actually--so let's establish that
I'm not a lawyer, and how nice it was to hear that there was--
people were interested in having economists in the room. So
that was a surprise. But my understanding of OMB circular A-4,
which is what we're talking about, is that it leaves open the
option to look at global effects, and that was the path that we
drove on. Now, I'm not the legal expert.
The second thing that I want to come back to, and I thought
it was very interesting. I saw some light or--between mine and
Dr. Gayer's testimony there, which is that I think to do an
analysis where--of the benefits of carbon regulations that
ignore the leverage from emissions reductions inside the United
States, and that leverage comes in the form of emissions
reductions in other countries I think is an extraordinarily
incomplete analysis. And using the global number is one way and
I think a valid way to reflect that leverage.
Mr. Beyer. Thank you. Thank you very much.
Dr. Michaels, congratulations on your Nobel Prize.
Dr. Michaels. I didn't say that. That went to the group.
Mr. Beyer. Okay. Well, still.
Dr. Michaels. People there, certainly not to the worker
bees.
Mr. Beyer. You know, so it was the group that came up with
the two percent target I think----
Dr. Michaels. Two degree target.
Mr. Beyer. Two degree target, two degree target.
Dr. Michaels. That was----
Mr. Beyer. Now you're thinking that we're going to be more
like 1.6. Will you be part of the IPCC going forward? And will
they come to a 1.6----
Dr. Michaels. The----
Mr. Beyer. --consensus in the next couple of years?
Dr. Michaels. The numbers that I have always given in my
decades of testifying in both the House and the Senate are all
within the range of the IPCC consensus so there's nothing new
here.
Mr. Beyer. Okay. Great. Thank you very much.
Mr. Chairman, I yield back.
Dr. Greenstone. Can I just add one----
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
Dr. Greenstone. I believe the IPCC----
Chairman Biggs. Dr. Greenstone, please.
Dr. Greenstone. --is from 1.5 to 4 or is it 1.5 to----
Dr. Michaels. Yes, I believe 1.6 is in there.
Dr. Greenstone. I think you're right at the bottom of the
range, yes, but I think the IPCC's consensus is actually--
you're right at the bottom of that range.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. I recognize----
Dr. Greenstone. Just making sure we're all on the same
page.
Chairman Biggs. I recognize Chairman Smith.
Chairman Smith. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Dr. Dayaratna, let me address my first question to you, and
it is this: Do you feel that the social cost of carbon is based
upon legitimate science or is it based upon arbitrary figures
and subjective reasoning?
Dr. Dayaratna. That's a very interesting question, so thank
you, Congressman. In terms of the science, so as, you know, Pat
and I both alluded to, the ECS--the equilibrium climate
sensitivity distribution that is implemented in these models by
the IWG has--was published ten years ago in the journal
Science. That is a whole decade ago, and it is not even
empirically estimated. It was calibrated to a priori
assumptions that the IWG wanted to use regarding climate
change.
Now, if you look at the more recent distributions, you will
notice significantly lower probabilities of extreme global
warming. So what ended up happening was that using this
outdated distribution, there was an overstated probability of
extreme global warming, and that gets manifested in higher
estimates of the SCC. So basically, the SCC estimates were
essentially beefed up.
Chairman Smith. Okay. Thank you.
And, Dr. Michaels, are there benefits to carbon emissions?
And if so, should they be factored into the social cost?
Dr. Michaels. Well, if you're going to factor costs, you
should factor benefits, and the increment just from direct
carbon dioxide fertilization for agricultural production is
about $3 trillion from 1961 through 2011. But more importantly,
the satellite data shows a remarkable greening of the planet
Earth, and the illustration that I showed earlier is remarkably
reassuring because the massive greenings, the largest greenings
are occurring in the margins of the great desert. The Sahelian
region in Africa that you and I were taught in school this is
desertifying and it will never come back. The tropical
rainforest, the lungs of the Earth, have the largest increase
in greening on the planet, all brought to you by carbon
dioxide. So, yes, you should factor those things in I would
think. Thank you.
Chairman Smith. Okay. Thank you, Dr. Michaels, for that.
One other question. What are some important climate change
factors that are not accounted for in the social cost?
Dr. Michaels. Oh, God. How many hours do I have to answer
that?
Chairman Smith. How about a minute-and-a-half but----
Dr. Michaels. Okay.
Chairman Smith. Okay.
Dr. Michaels. One of the problems is that we spend
tremendous amounts of taxpayer money on climate models--
Chairman Smith. Okay.
Dr. Michaels. --and very, very--models for what happens
when you increase carbon dioxide and very, very little money on
what's called natural climate variability. We know there are
these great oscillations in the Atlantic and the Pacific that
drive, modulate hurricanes, modulate storm tracks, modulate
weather. Those things are not simulated in these climate
models, and we need to understand that variability and subtract
that out.
I'll close in one second here. The warming of the late 20th
century, which began in 1976 and either ended in 1998 or
continued--attenuated after 1998 depending upon what we
believe--is the same magnitude as the warming of the early 20th
century that occurred between 1910 and 20--and 1945. That
warming could not have been caused by carbon dioxide.
Chairman Smith. Right.
Dr. Michaels. It means that natural variability is as large
as the largest human signal, and yet we only model the human
signal. What's wrong with this picture, Congressman?
Chairman Smith. Yes. Yes. That last point, the last couple
points you seldom see covered in the media, but I think they're
great points to make.
Final question is should we be using the social cost at
all?
Dr. Michaels. We should use the social cost of carbon if
it's accurately calculated, and I think there's a lot of debate
about what we're supposed--what----
Chairman Smith. Yes.
Dr. Michaels. --what it comprises----
Chairman Smith. Okay.
Dr. Michaels. --and what the natural variability component
of it is and all this good stuff. We're just not there. It's
not ready for prime time, Congressman.
Chairman Smith. Okay. Thank you, Dr. Michaels.
I yield back, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I recognize Chairman LaHood.
Mr. LaHood. Mr. Chairman, I would just like--I forgot to
submit a document for the record from the American Road and
Transportation Builders Association regarding our hearing
today. I would ask to submit it for the record.
Chairman Biggs. Without objection.
[The information appears in Appendix II]
Chairman Biggs. The Chair recognizes Mr. McNerney.
Mr. McNerney. Well, thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you for
holding the hearing. I thank the witnesses this morning.
Dr. Gayer, I'm very pleased to hear that you support a
carbon tax. I think that's the way to go. I'm going to be
proposing a carbon tax and benefit package a little bit later,
and I hope to get your support on that. Can we follow through
with that?
Dr. Gayer. I'd be delighted to, yes.
Mr. McNerney. Very good.
About the domestic versus international impacts, do you
believe that the physical impacts of climate change on other
nations don't have an impact on our domestic economy or
security?
Dr. Gayer. No, I don't believe that, but what I believe is
that the actions that we've taken thus far won't lead to
reductions matched throughout the entire world. And there are
many policies that we have outside of environmental or climate
that we--that if other countries did the same thing--and you
can think about foreign aid or any number of policies, the
world would be a better place and we'd benefit perhaps from it,
but we don't take those benefits into account. The regulations
where----
Mr. McNerney. So if we drop out of the Clean Power Plan and
the Paris agreements, then that's not going to have an impact
on China or India or the other countries that are big emitters?
Dr. Gayer. I don't think the Clean Power Plan--well, I
don't know that the Clean Power Plan would have an effect. If
there's an international agreement and a treaty that is
binding, then certainly we should consider the global benefits.
Absent that, an EPA regulation I don't think will actually lead
to realize the effects throughout the world and certainly not
100 percent throughout the world.
Mr. McNerney. So you think--you do think that climate
change is a problem?
Dr. Gayer. Sure. Yes. Yes.
Mr. McNerney. And that the United States should have a
leadership role in this issue?
Dr. Gayer. Yes.
Mr. McNerney. Thank you.
Dr. Greenstone, what impact will eliminating the SCC have
on current and future environmental protections designed to
reduce greenhouse gas emissions? How is that going to affect us
if we eliminate that measure?
Dr. Greenstone. Thank you for the question. I think it will
increase emissions. Of course it would naturally increase
emissions in the United States, and that would increase the
rate of climate change and global warming. What I think--the
point I've been trying to make that I just want to underscore
is I think it would also increase emissions in other countries,
and so there would be a multiplier effect. And I think it's a
mistake to conclude that the Paris agreement did not reflect
U.S. leadership and did not reflect that the United States had
adopted a robust climate policy. So--you know, let me also add
there's I think again surprising agreement on this panel, at
least among two of us, that there is climate change. Climate
change is real. And there seems to be a little disagreement on
the tactics.
You know, our other two witnesses here I think are much
more focused on cherry-picking particular features of it, and I
think I couldn't agree with them more that updating the
assumptions that underlie the social cost of carbon based on
the advances in science in the last 7 or eight years is an
important thing to do. And indeed, thankfully, the National
Academy of Sciences has put out a very clear report on how to
go about doing that.
Mr. McNerney. Thank you. Now, some of the critics have
implied that the SCC is created by the Obama Administration and
pushed by environmentalists, but it's my understanding that the
Reagan Administration first demanded the Federal Government to
do a cost-benefit analysis, and the federal courts required the
George W. Bush Administration to monetize these benefits. Is
there any other way to do that than using the social cost of
carbon?
Dr. Greenstone. No. The--really what the courts were
requiring that a social cost of carbon be developed. And I
think when one thinks back to 2009, what was striking is that
even though a ton of CO<INF>2</INF>, wherever it's emitted in
the U.S. economy has the same impact, you had a complete
discordant approach. The department--some departments were
treating it as if there were zero costs associated with it,
which is, just to be clear, effectively implying that climate
change has no negative impacts.
Mr. McNerney. Right.
Dr. Greenstone. And others were effectively treating it as
if it were infinity costs. And so I think landing at the
approach and the number that we ended--tried to instill some
discipline and coherence across--policy across the government.
Mr. McNerney. And so what's the context of how this came
about, how this measure came about?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. No, it was--sorry. The Court had
required it, and the President had ordered that a number be
developed and that--as I mentioned earlier, that used expertise
from all branches of government.
Mr. McNerney. And this was done in a transparent fashion?
Dr. Greenstone. It was done in a transparent fashion.
There's been endless opportunities for public comments. It's
been at least 80 rules. In addition, it was put out for public
comment on its own.
Mr. McNerney. Is there some kind of consensus on what
parameters to use for this model?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. There was great debate about it, and
what--actually what--a rule that I tried to impose when we were
leading the process was that we should not be making science--
we are, after all, faceless bureaucrats sitting in a room--but
instead that our job was to summarize the frontier of science.
And I feel that we were quite faithful to that goal.
Mr. McNerney. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield
back.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. Dr. Michaels, you looked like
you might want to respond to the assertion of cherry-picking.
Dr. Michaels. I would like to--oh, sorry. I would like to
respond to the assertion that without the social cost of carbon
that our emissions would go up. That's what I call maybe herd
reasoning, and I'd like to show you how well herd reasoning
works with regard to emissions.
This, which I just happen to be carrying in my backpack, is
a shale oil rock. Ten years ago if I said that there were
hundreds of years of oil--shale gas rather, which produces half
the emissions of carbon dioxide when combusted for power
production under our feet, polite company--and we would get it
by exploding rocks, polite company would have laughed me out of
every Washington cocktail hour. But that's the way people work.
Regulation is not required to create efficiency. Markets
are required to create efficiency. This is cheaper than its
competitors, and emissions will continue to go down as long as
our economy is free for the simple reason that the future
belongs to the efficient.
Mr. McNerney. Industry can be relied on to clean itself up.
That's basically what you're saying.
Dr. Michaels. No, the market can be relied upon to clean up
industry.
Mr. McNerney. Mr. Greenstone----
Chairman Biggs. I'm sorry. The gentleman's time is expired.
Mr. McNerney. I'm sorry.
Chairman Biggs. The Chair recognizes Mr. Posey.
Mr. Posey. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
As policymakers, I think it's important that we all know
what we don't know, and therefore, our attempts to predict the
future impact of regulations are always speculative and subject
to error.
And that being said, it's also true that some predictions
are more speculative and uncertain than others. The time
between the implementation of a regulation and the onset of any
potential benefits is a great example of a factor that makes
some forecasts more reliable and others less so. Clearly, the
longer the period of time is between the implementation of a
rule and the realization of its benefits, the less reliable the
analysis of the predicted benefits can be due to the increased
likelihood of intervention from unforeseen sources.
My first question is for Dr. Dayaratna. With what I've said
in mind, can you give me an idea of the time horizon used in
calculating the social cost of carbon? How far into the future
are we looking at when we talk about this cost?
Dr. Dayaratna. The time horizon for computing the social
cost of carbon by the IWG is 300 years into the future. And
it's interesting that you ask that question, Congressman.
Firstly, it's difficult to forecast what the economy will look
like, you know, even a couple decades into the future, let
alone centuries.
Now, Dr. Michaels had a slide about the temperature
projections that John Christy talked about juxtaposing the
IPCC's forecast versus satellite and weather balloon data. And
I just find it astounding that people would want to use these
models to try to make forecasts 300 years into the future when
they can't even predict 20.
Mr. Posey. Yes, we have trouble getting the weather
predicted a day ahead of time----
Dr. Dayaratna. Oh, absolutely.
Mr. Posey. --oftentimes. So, wow, you're telling me we're
basing our regulatory decisions on assumptions about what the
world will be like in 300 years. In some ways that's kind of
like our Founding Fathers trying to predict and regulate the
internet.
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes. I gave a talk, you know, a couple weeks
ago on this topic. You know, John Adams once said America will
one day become the greatest empire in the world, and he was
right, but yet he'd have no idea what people are doing today
using microphones, smartphones, tablets, and so forth.
Similarly, we have no idea what things are going to look like
that far into the future. And I quite frankly find it's--these
models are quite foolish in actually trying to make those types
of forecasts.
Mr. Posey. Okay. Can you describe for us how the social
cost of carbon estimates change when you use a more reasonable
horizon?
Dr. Dayaratna. So as I was referring to in my testimony,
they change as--by--a reasonable figure is around 25 percent.
That figure varies but on average around I think around 25
percent or so, perhaps more.
Mr. Posey. And given what you just said, do you think it's
advisable to continue using the current social cost of carbon
estimates in rulemaking proceedings?
Dr. Dayaratna. Absolutely not. I think these models--you
know, they're interesting for academic exercises but they need
to be revised to be suitable for regulatory policy.
Mr. Posey. Do you think in the future the agencies can and
should be more forthcoming about the highly speculative nature
and variable quality of social cost of carbon estimates?
Dr. Dayaratna. I tend to think so, yes. To be quite honest,
like the sheer fact that they are using an ECS distribution
that was--that is ten years old and not even based on empirical
research is one thing that is, you know, just not in detail
talked about in the IWG's analysis. They did respond to this in
the public comments; I will say that. But, yes, there are so
many other things out there that they should be more
forthcoming about.
And, you know, there was a question that came up earlier
about the use of a seven percent discount rate and why it was
not used. Quite frankly, here's the reason why I think it
wasn't used. Even using the outdated Roe Baker distribution,
you still get a negative estimate of the SCC under a seven
percent discount rate. That's why it wasn't used.
Mr. Posey. Okay. There's been a lot of discussion about
climate change. Can anyone on the panel give me a date certain,
even a year certain that there was absolutely no climate change
on this planet since the forming of it?
Dr. Dayaratna. I believe that the climate has been changing
since the planet was first formed.
Mr. Posey. Any others?
Dr. Greenstone. Mr. Congressman, are you talking about--
just so we're on the same page, are you talking about climate
changing or climate changing due to the release of
CO<INF>2</INF>? Because I can't quite tell from your question.
Mr. Posey. I thought I was fairly clear.
Dr. Greenstone. Okay. Well, then----
Mr. Posey. Can you give me any date certain----
Dr. Greenstone. The climate has certainly----
Mr. Posey. --in the history of the Earth that the climate
has not changed?
Dr. Greenstone. Since the release of CO<INF>2</INF>, it has
been changing more rapidly.
Dr. Michaels. That's not true.
Mr. Posey. You know, that's speculative, and I didn't ask
you to describe a clock. I asked you if you knew what time it
was.
Yes, sir, at the end.
Dr. Michaels. I think the climate was quite stable about
one year before the Big Bang.
Mr. Posey. Okay. Dr. Dayaratna.
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes, there was actually a paper published in
the Journal of the American Statistical Association last year
that looked at tree ring analysis in Tornetrask, Sweden, and
they found interestingly using their Bayesian modeling that in
1750 the temperatures there it may have been just as warm if
not warmer than they were today in 1750 before, you know, all
the things that we--people tend to complain about today.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
Mr. Posey. Do you have any idea what----
Chairman Biggs. The gentleman's time is expired.
Mr. Posey. Any idea what the temperature was pre the last
Ice Age when the dinosaurs were roaming the Earth?
Dr. Dayaratna. Pat actually might have an answer to that.
Dr. Michaels. The answer--that's a very good question and
I'm glad you asked that. I don't think we have to go pre the
last Ice Age. Let's go not to the most recent interglacial but
to the penultimate one, the one between what some people call
the Illinois glaciation and the Wisconsin glaciation. At the
end of the current Ice Age, temperatures got quite a bit warmer
than they are now, the beginning of the current interglacial.
The beginning of the penultimate one, they were much warmer
than they were in our interglacial.
In Greenland, temperatures in summer averaged around 6
degrees Celsius higher than now for 6,000 years. And guess
what? The vast majority of the ice on Greenland survived, a
heat load that human beings could not put on Greenland if they
tried. And then somebody found a skeleton of a bear from 5,000
years before that, and it turns out the DNA sequence was that
of a polar bear.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. The gentleman's time is expired.
Dr. Michaels. Thank you very much.
Mr. Posey. Thank you.
Chairman Biggs. The Chair recognizes my friend from
Florida, Mr. Crist.
Mr. Crist. Thank you very much. Good morning.
I was wondering--Dr. Michaels, good morning. How are you?
Dr. Michaels. I'm good.
Mr. Crist. Do you believe that climate change is real?
Dr. Michaels. Of course.
Mr. Crist. Fabulous.
Dr. Michaels. I also believe the sun will rise tomorrow.
Mr. Crist. That's breathtaking.
Dr. Michaels. I know. It's mindboggling.
Mr. Crist. Do you--what would you estimate is the cause of
the climate change you believe in?
Dr. Michaels. There are natural causes and there is a human
component. You have to understand, the warming of the second--
the second warming in the 20th century is accompanied by a
cooling of the lower stratosphere. Now, if you change the
greenhouse effect, because you change the upwelling flux of
infrared radiation, you will warm the lower layers of the
atmosphere but you will cool the stratosphere. That's what Karl
Popper would call a difficult test of a theory. And indeed, the
lower stratosphere cools concurrent with the warming of the
troposphere, our neck of the woods. That's a greenhouse
signature.
But here's the cool part, Congressman Crist. In 1997, 1998,
everybody knows that something happened to warming unless you
really jimmy the records and it either slowed down or stopped.
Mr. Crist. Attenuated you said.
Dr. Michaels. Attenuated is a good word because you can
attenuate----
Mr. Crist. Sure.
Dr. Michaels. --a lot or you can attenuate a little. But
the stratospheric cooling also stopped. Now, if you want me to
explain that, I'm going to tell you the three most important
words in life.
Mr. Crist. My question is simple. What causes climate
change in your estimation?
Dr. Michaels. Lots of things.
Mr. Crist. What's the primary cause?
Dr. Michaels. The fact that we live on a fluid
discontinuous earth with long-period oscillations. I mean, the
biggest climate change that you and I know of is an ice age
oscillation, and I don't think CO<INF>2</INF> is going to be
capable of doing that, and those occurred, you know, without
human influence. Again, I say the warming of the late 20th
century has a greenhouse component because of the stratospheric
cooling. By did the stratosphere stop cooling when the surface
warming either stopped or attenuated? You know what the answer
why that happened is?
Mr. Crist. May I ask another member a question?
Dr. Michaels. No one knows is the answer.
Mr. Crist. Dr. Greenstone, what do you think causes climate
change, please?
Dr. Greenstone. I think what we're here to talk about today
is the climate change is caused from the release of
CO<INF>2</INF>----
Mr. Crist. Yes, sir.
Dr. Greenstone. --of which I think that's a settled issue
scientifically. And I can't help but note the contrast here
between the concerns of the development of the SCC was an
opaque process, which is the claims here. Let me just say the
character of the conversation that occurred in those many, many
meetings was really quite sober. It was rigorous. It was very
scientifically based. And we--at no point did anyone talk about
a skeleton of a polar bear as a way to make an argument.
And my own view is that there's a great path forward, and I
think there's agreement in the room that there should be a
development that the social cost of carbon should be refreshed
to reflect the scientific advances that have occurred since
2009 and 2010. And literally, the National Academy of Sciences
has outlined a terrific way forward that would also be
rigorous, scientifically based, and sober, and I think there's
a great opportunity for the Trump Administration to do that.
Mr. Crist. Thank you. I'm from the Sunshine State, and I'm
very proud of that. But having said that, we use less solar
energy than New Jersey. And New Jersey's a great place, but
it's the Garden State and we're the Sunshine State. And so the
point I'm trying to make is if we're going to address climate
change and probably the primary cause, which is CO<INF>2</INF>,
carbon, then wouldn't it be better for us to try to get more of
our energy from solar, from sun or wind in order to mitigate
the cause?
Dr. Greenstone. I think there's a great case for energy
markets being in a very unlevel playing field. In particular,
the fossil fuels, which involve the release of CO<INF>2</INF>,
when we go to the gas pump and when we pay our electricity
bill, we don't pay for the climate damages that are associated
with using them. And if we were to level the playing field so
that all sources of energy could compete on equal grounds, it
would naturally be the case that there would be a greater
reliance on, as you suggested, renewables, probably on nuclear
as well, and other low-carbon energy sources.
Mr. Crist. Thank you, Doctor.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
The Chair recognizes Mr. Rohrabacher from California.
Mr. Rohrabacher. Thank you very much. And let me just note
that I--one of my colleagues suggested that there is a
consensus among scientists that global warming is being caused
by CO<INF>2</INF> emissions, and let me just note that a
consensus may mean 75 percent, it may mean 60 percent, it may
mean ten percent and the others don't know for sure. But a
consensus is not how you determine whether or not something is
scientifically viable. You have to really look to see whether
or not it makes sense what people are saying and whether or
not, for example, attempts to receive government contracts for
research were in some way influencing someone to target their
outcome of their research because what I have heard in the last
few years is that droughts are caused by global warming and the
CO<INF>2</INF> level and then now it's floods are caused by
CO<INF>2</INF> level and more tornados. I mean, how many times
have we heard that the tornados and the hurricanes are more
frequent, but they're not. You know, come to find out they are
not more frequent. And all of this coming back to CO<INF>2</INF>
and whether or not it is something that we should be concerned
about at the level of CO<INF>2</INF>.
You know, I drove across the country last year and I saw
all these hothouses, and covered-up places, and they were
growing all sorts of vegetables. And I went and stopped at
several of them and guess what they were pumping into the
hothouses? CO<INF>2</INF>. Now, why? Because it makes the
plants grow better and that means there's more food.
Now, let me ask you this. If we have less CO<INF>2</INF> in
the air, does that mean that the plants, and I think we saw
something there, that the plants will not grow as robustly if
we have less CO<INF>2</INF> in the air? Whoever wants to go
into that.
Dr. Dayaratna. That is actually one of the aspects about
the FUND model compared to the other models that is actually
incorporated, the feedback from CO<INF>2</INF> into plants and
agriculture from CO<INF>2</INF> fertilization. So the other
models, the DC. and PAGE model the IWG used, do not account for
this type of feedback.
Mr. Rohrabacher. So that's a great benefit if we have trees
that are growing stronger and more trees, more edible plants
growing stronger, but that benefit was not calculated into the
cost-benefit of other studies?
Dr. Dayaratna. That benefit was incorporated in the FUND
model analysis. Out of the three models used by the IWG, the
FUND model actually incorporated that benefit. And, you know,
Pat can talk more about this, but there are other benefits in
there that could potentially be modeled that, you know, the
FUND model doesn't take into account such as, say, aquatic
life----
Mr. Rohrabacher. Okay.
Dr. Dayaratna. --you know, detailed aspects about
vegetation, detailed aspects about agriculture, and so forth
that the economy could benefit from.
Mr. Rohrabacher. Well, let me just put it this way. It's
clearer that in the past there were higher levels of CO<INF>2</INF>
and great plant life throughout the planet, and we know that
and that's very easily discovered in any research. But now, our
CO<INF>2</INF> level is looked at as if it's going to be
harmful, and let me just say that I don't think that there is a
consensus at a high level of percentage, and I think we need to
make sure that before we jump into international agreements
that it's not just whether it's global benefit or whether it's
local benefit. We just have to see whether there's any validity
to this concept in the first place so----
Dr. Michaels. Congressman, can I offer an observation?
Mr. Rohrabacher. Please do.
Dr. Michaels. I understand that it is thought to be
socially responsible to pay for the costs of emission of carbon
dioxide, and I also would argue that the fossil fuel-driven
societies since 1900 in the developed world have increased
their lifespan by 100 percent and their per capita wealth 11-
fold. Are we to not also take into account that massive
benefit? We should all be dead given our ages in this room if
this were 1900, but it is that society that allows us to live.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you.
Mr. Rohrabacher. That's a very good point and I'm glad I'm
not dead. There you go.
Chairman Biggs. The gentleman's time is expired. Thank you.
The Chair recognizes Mr. Marshall from Kansas.
Mr. Marshall. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I wish my colleague
from Florida was still here. I was going to share with him that
we have more sunny days in Kansas than there. Oh, you are still
here, Governor. So we have more sunny days in Kansas than
Florida, so we look forward to continuing the diversity of
energy from Kansas. So thanks for sharing that. I want to
acknowledge a good friend of mine, John Francis, who's in the
audience, flew all the way in from Great Bend, America, to hear
our President speak.
Dr. Gayer, the first question's for you. You mentioned that
you would be in favor of a carbon tax being implemented. If we
implemented a carbon tax, do you think we could also do away
with some of the regulations governing all these carbon
producers and just let us pay a tax and be done with it if we
can measure it in some way?
Dr. Gayer. Yes. So certainly in many ways that's kind of
the thrust of my critique of what's going on in the regulatory
sphere. The--and I'm a--Michael Greenstone mentioned leveling
the playing field. And so for me the carbon tax is a way to
level the playing field, and the regulatory interventions that
we've had are a very, very flawed approach to trying to do
that. And in my view, the modeling and the global versus
domestic are sort of justifications for what I think is a
flawed approach.
So, you know, the ultimate trade is a carbon tax in
exchange for a tax reduction for more harmful taxes and less
regulation and just stick to the pricing.
Mr. Marshall. Anybody else want to weigh in on that? Dr.
Greenstone, please.
Dr. Greenstone. Yes, I think there's a great opportunity
for applying a carbon tax at an appropriate level and using--
the revenues could be used in a variety of ways. It could be
refunded. They could be used to reduce other taxes. And I think
they would provide a great opportunity as well for--as a--they
could be an excellent substitute for a lot of the regulations
that are in place. So there's agreement here.
Dr. Michaels. And with regard to the revenue neutrality, I
would offer my comment in the form of a question. Do you really
expect $3 trillion to walk down K Street unmolested?
Mr. Marshall. Okay. I don't know what to say to that. I
hope the question wasn't for me.
This social carbon tax is a perfect example of government
making the simple complicated. I don't think we'll ever agree.
It's a social number; it's a political number. That's what it
seems to me and I'm very new to this game.
I guess what I'm more concerned about is, as I watched the
Olympics in China and so on and so forth, it would seem to me
that whatever measure you use that some of our biggest
competitors are producing more of this carbon. And I'm just
curious in the big scheme of things in today's world how much
carbon is America producing in relationship to China or India,
regardless of the social cost we can argue? But what percentage
are we now responsible for?
Dr. Greenstone. I think this is a rough number. I think
historically--I think right now China is producing about 50
percent more per year than we are. I think we are the second-
largest emitter, larger than the EU, larger than India. I think
starting from the Industrial Revolution--someone else might
know here--but I'm going to guess that I think we're
responsible for about maybe a quarter of all emissions.
Mr. Marshall. Okay.
Dr. Michaels. Yes, but we are becoming more efficient. Our
emissions intensity, which is the amount of CO<INF>2</INF>
produced per unit GDP has dropped more rapidly than pretty much
everywhere, and that didn't happen because of regulations. It
happened because of markets. So if you want efficiency, you
would prefer economic----
Mr. Marshall. And I want to move on. So I grew up in a
small town between two refineries, oil refineries. So proud
that our air in Kansas is cleaner today than it was when I was
growing up and the waters are cleaner. I want to keep moving in
that direction. Back to my point: manufacturing. I'm trying to
figure out why manufacturing jobs have left Kansas, and one of
them is the cost of energy. Does anybody have any solutions?
How do we encourage China, India, other countries to take leads
in this responsibility? Does anybody have any solutions? Do we
tax them or--I don't want to--does anybody have any solutions
on how we encourage them to get into this game?
Dr. Greenstone. I think Dr. Gayer outlined one effective
tool, which would be to have a carbon tax and then have some
border tariff--border tax adjustment so that if people tried to
import--so let's say steel that had carbon embedded in it or
carbon was used to produce it, they would face the same carbon
tax that domestic producers would face.
Mr. Marshall. But you would adjust that per country or how
would you figure out--so Europe's doing good, Germany's doing
good, but China's not.
Dr. Greenstone. Yes, so you'd have to--there would be some
complexity, I think, but it's imminently doable.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. The Chair recognizes Mr. Higgins
from Louisiana.
Mr. Higgins. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
We're here to discuss the real cost of carbon as it's
imposed upon the American people. And it's interesting to note
that in discussing the social cost of carbon I've heard terms
like ``overwhelming consensus of scientific opinion'' and
``real science'' and yet the measurement standards use a 300-
year window to determine actual taxation and cost placed upon
the American people. And it's interesting to consider that
we're very fortunate that we're not bound by the science of 300
years ago when we would be discussing egocentricity, alchemy,
spontaneous generation of life, and the hollow Earth. And yet
scientists tend to speak as if their scientific calculations
are absolute and unchallengable. To me, the real overwhelming
consensus is that the social cost of carbon is a cost measured
not by 300-year windows of manipulated science but the
contemporary and very real cost of American jobs and American
treasure.
So I ask Dr. Dayaratna, you mentioned there are updated
equilibrium climate sensitivity distributions. These ECS
distributions quantify the Earth's projected temperature
response to a doubling of carbon dioxide concentrations. As you
note, these recent ECS distributions appear to reflect a lower
chance of extreme global warming in response to increased
carbon dioxide concentrations. Can you explain or can you give
us some insight or are you aware of why the previous
Administration, through their Interagency Working Group failed
to update the SCC or any other social cost of greenhouse gas
estimates to reflect these more up-to-date ECS distributions?
If it was not a political decision, then please explain, what
was it?
Dr. Dayaratna. So the Roe Baker distribution that was
published in 2007 is calibrated to a priori assumptions that
the IWG wanted to make regarding global warming based on, you
know, a compiled research discussed by the IPCC. The thing is
that--again, that distribution is calibrated. It is not an
empirical distribution. The percentiles were fitted based to
assumptions that the working group wanted to make. Subsequent
ECS distributions are actually empirically estimated, so they
are much more worth considering.
Now, the question regarding why were these new
distributions not included, I think, quite frankly, the reason
is that they lower the estimate of the SCC substantially even
if you don't use a seven percent discount rate, even if you use
the assumptions that the IWG wanted to make regarding 2.5, 3,
and five percent. You can still get a negative SCC using more
up-to-date distributions because the fat tail of the Roe Baker
distribution has essentially gone on a diet with the newer more
up-to-date ECS distributions, signifying the lower probability
of global warming.
Mr. Higgins. Dr. Michaels, do you have something to add?
Dr. Michaels. I think Kevin is right.
Dr. Dayaratna. Your mike's not on.
Chairman Biggs. Please press your mike. Thank you.
Dr. Michaels. It was not a lower probability of global
warming. It's a lower probability of high-end global warming--
--
Dr. Dayaratna. High-end global--yes.
Dr. Michaels. --which is--and that is correct.
Mr. Higgins. And with the increase of carbon emissions
measured globally, would it not be a reasonable consideration
that greenhouse gas effect would in fact assist the economies
of the earth regarding agricultural production?
Dr. Michaels. Well, the effect of carbon dioxide--the
direct effect on plants is well-documented, and the image that
I showed at the end of my presentation, which is a very recent
image, documents the actual greening of much of the Earth, not
just the agricultural component of the Earth. And it's very
reassuring to see that the largest greenings--and they are
very, very large--tends to take place in the margins of the
deserts south of the Sahara and in the northern parts of the
tropical rainforest where we were very concerned.
Mr. Higgins. Dr. Greenstone, I believe----
Dr. Greenstone. Yes.
Mr. Higgins. --Mr. Chairman, he has something to add
although I'm out of time.
Chairman Biggs. Your time is expired. Sorry.
The Chair recognizes Mr. Babin.
Mr. Babin. Yes, sir. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Fascinating testimony. I want to thank everyone for being
here, these witnesses.
I represent the 36th District in Texas, which contains the
highest concentration of chemical plants and oil refineries of
any one district in the entire country. So when the federal
government issues carbon regulations based on questionable data
and methods, this is of great concern to me because they have a
direct and significant impact on my constituents.
And, Dr. Dayaratna, putting things in a perspective from
the Industrial Revolution, what association do you see between
carbon dioxide emissions and the health of our economy? And
along with what some of you folks have already said, obviously
it's going to be a drag but I'd like to hear you elaborate a
little bit more on that.
Dr. Dayaratna. Okay. Well, no, that's a very good question,
Congressman. So here's the thing. And a lot of people take for
granted that energy is a fundamental building block of
civilization. So whether it's, you know, powering this room,
lighting up our homes, powering our cars and so forth, we all
depend on energy.
So when we think about, you know, this whole concept of
SCC, the whole goal is to reduce carbon dioxide emissions, and
what we end up doing is moving away from the least expensive
and most efficient forms of electricity to more expensive and
less efficient forms.
So--and the bottom line is economically what we'll notice
is that when we go to these so-called lower carbon-emitting,
you know, forms of energy, what we would notice is a dramatic
change to the economy in the long run. You--you know, a carbon
tax, as I was talking about in my testimony, would--in
conjunction with the SCC would result in around 400,000 lost
jobs on average by 2035, 13 to 20 percent increase in
electricity prices, a $2.5 trillion loss in GDP.
Now, on the other hand--and I've also researched this
question--if we were to take advantage of the vast shale oil
and gas we have in this country, we'd actually see the exact
opposite, in fact, even more so in the other direction. We
would see a $3.7 trillion increase in GDP, personal income
would skyrocket----
Mr. Babin. Absolutely.
Dr. Dayaratna. --and, yes, all sorts of things that would
benefit the economy.
Mr. Babin. Absolutely. Thank you so very much for that
testimony. And, Dr. Michaels, it's interesting to hear you put
a historic and prehistoric context into all this.
Dr. Michaels. I've lived that long.
Mr. Babin. Well, as a student of history, I've read some of
the Norse settlements coming from Norway over to Iceland and
onto Greenland, and they had settlements there I think from the
year 1000 and had trade and routine ships calling on them from
Europe for a couple of 300 years. And they were in the process
of raising livestock, had hay crops, and then strangely, it had
been over 150 years when a ship called on them in the 1500s and
none of that community was left. And by that time the climate
had cooled off considerably. The hay crops were no longer
there. The folks had disappeared.
So I don't think there was a huge amount of industrialism,
carbon dioxide being released into the earth from humans during
those centuries, so if you can kind of address that as well,
along with some of the other----
Dr. Michaels. Well, the nature of climate is to change.
Mr. Babin. Right.
Dr. Michaels. It is because we are not a uniform earth. We
do not have a circular orbit. The sun varies and the infrared
absorption of the atmosphere varies, sometimes with human
activities. It's--what do they say? It's complicated,
Congressman. And the problem is in the illustration that I
showed, comparing the satellite and weather balloon
observations to the average of the United Nations' 107 computer
models shows that it's so complicated that we haven't gotten
close to getting it right and why would you base a policy upon
something that is so blatantly wrong?
Mr. Babin. Thank you so very much. And the American people
deserve to know the truth here and have sound scientific data,
and that's what this hearing's all about. I want to thank
everybody again for being here, and I'll yield back, Mr.
Chairman. Thank you.
Chairman Biggs. Thank you. The Chair recognizes Mr. Weber
from Texas.
Mr. Weber. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a question for
each of you all. There seemed to be some discussion about
whether climate change was real and what that meant and the
definition, so here's my question for each of you individually,
and we'll start with you, Dr. Gayer. Would you agree that
climate change is caused by temperature fluctuation?
Dr. Gayer. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Dr. Dayaratna?
Dr. Dayaratna. Dayaratna.
Mr. Weber. Thank you.
Dr. Dayaratna. The question is would I agree that climate
change is caused by----
Mr. Weber. Is caused by temperature fluctuation?
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes.
Mr. Weber. How about you, Dr. Greenstone?
Dr. Greenstone. It's a function of temperature variation.
It's also a function of CO<INF>2</INF> emissions.
Mr. Weber. Temperature variation is a good one, too. I
didn't mention CO<INF>2</INF>. I'll come back to you. Dr.
Michaels, would you agree climate change is caused by
temperature fluctuation?
Dr. Michaels. It is the contrast--oh, sorry. It is the
contrast in temperature between the surface and the upper
atmosphere that derives--drives most of the precipitation
mechanisms on Earth, so the answer would be if that changes,
yes.
Mr. Weber. Okay. I'll take that as a yes.
Dr. Gayer, would you agree that temperatures fluctuate when
seasons change?
Dr. Gayer. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Doctor?
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Dr. Greenstone?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. I also think they fluctuate----
Mr. Weber. Dr. Michaels?
Dr. Greenstone. --from CO<INF>2</INF> emissions.
Dr. Michaels. Me four.
Mr. Weber. Okay. Dr. Gayer, back to you. Would you
believe--would you agree that temperatures fluctuate in
historical, global, cyclical fashion? In other words, we have
historical evidence that temperatures changed up or down
historically.
Dr. Gayer. Yes, I don't know cyclical necessarily but yes--
--
Mr. Weber. Well, okay.
Dr. Gayer. --it's gone up, it's gone down.
Mr. Weber. I'll give you that. How about--
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes.
Mr. Weber. --you, Doctor?
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Dr. Greenstone, would you agree with that?
Dr. Greenstone. Yes. I also think that it varies----
Mr. Weber. It's just a yes or no.
Dr. Greenstone. --because of CO<INF>2</INF> emissions----
Mr. Weber. Dr. Michaels?
Dr. Michaels. I will use the weasel word quasi-cyclical.
Mr. Weber. Got you. Okay. Now, would you agree also,
Doctors, that the temperatures actually fluctuate more when
seasons change? Obviously, they go up drastically in Texas to
100, 110 in the desert area sometimes or they go way down
below, so when it changes from fall to winter, for example,
temperatures fluctuate wildly. Would you agree with that, Dr.
Gayer?
Dr. Gayer. I'm confused by the question because I thought
that was the previous question.
Mr. Weber. Would you agree that temperatures fluctuate more
when seasons change than they just do from week to week, for
example?
Dr. Gayer. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Okay. Dr. Dayaratna?
Dr. Dayaratna. Yes.
Mr. Weber. Okay. Dr. Greenstone, minus the COT component--
CO<INF>2</INF>?
Dr. Greenstone. I think CO<INF>2</INF>'s important in terms
of temperature. I also think seasons are important in terms of
temperature.
Mr. Weber. Dr. Michaels, would you agree they fluctuate
more wildly when seasons change?
Dr. Michaels. Yes, sir.
Mr. Weber. Great. So we know that the temperatures
fluctuate when seasons change. Now, we're talking about a
carbon tax. And so if you go back to where we're going to
charge carbon tax for people on industry or countries, let's
say, that have industry, are we going to take into account when
their seasons change because now they're using more electricity
when it's hot or more electricity when it's cold? Do you take
that into account at all in the proposed carbon tax?
Dr. Gayer. I'm not----
Mr. Weber. Do they get a credit when----
Dr. Gayer. No, the----
Mr. Weber. --they have a mild season.
Dr. Gayer. The goal of the carbon tax is to include a price
into the energy decision. So certainly when they use more
energy, the tax will go higher and the----
Mr. Weber. Okay. So they could put----
Dr. Gayer. If you're tying it to like tax reduction
somewhere else, the revenue would go higher then.
Mr. Weber. They do get a credit when it's mild. I got you.
Okay. Now, what happens when those countries have a tremendous
catastrophe, whether it's a huge hurricane or a huge cyclone,
tsunami, or you name it, and they are really hard hit and they
have to have more energy production to rebuild their country,
do they then get a tax credit to be able to go back and rebuild
their country or do we punish them more because now they're
using more energy to rebuild?
Dr. Greenstone. Can I ask a clarifying----
Mr. Weber. No, I'm asking him first, Dr. Gayer.
Dr. Gayer. I don't--I didn't--I don't understand the tax--
--they level--you level--the tax increases the price of energy,
yes.
Mr. Weber. So no matter what happens in a country, if they
have a huge catastrophe and they have to use a lot of energy to
rebuild their country, they don't get a break? They're just
going to pay more carbon tax at that point?
Dr. Gayer. Yes, that's the nature of a tax.
Mr. Weber. Doctor, do you agree with that?
Dr. Dayaratna. That--I've never put together a carbon tax
proposal myself----
Mr. Weber. I'm just----
Dr. Dayaratna. --but in principle, the--yes, that seems to
be what----
Mr. Weber. That's what's going to happen.
Dr. Dayaratna. --we would want to do, yes.
Mr. Weber. Dr. Greenstone, do you agree that's going to
happen, they use more energy, more carbon to rebuild their
country and they're going to get taxed on it?
Dr. Greenstone. I just want to clarify if we're talking
about a hurricane disaster that's due to CO<INF>2</INF>
accumulation in the atmosphere or just one that has----
Mr. Weber. I'm talking about the tax once they have a
disaster. Do you know where I'm going, Dr. Michaels? Can you
see what I'm asking here?
Dr. Michaels. Yes. I believe that you are drawing the
analogy to what happened to this House when it passed cap-and-
trade in 2009.
Mr. Weber. Well, that was a catastrophe all right but----
Dr. Michaels. Correct.
Mr. Weber. So here's the point I'm making. Now, suppose an
industry comes along and they develop a process of capturing
CO<INF>2</INF> and putting it underground. Do we revoke the
carbon tax?
Dr. Gayer. No, you credit it. That's the--that----
Mr. Weber. Credit it?
Dr. Gayer. That's--and that's one of the nice incentives of
having a tax because it incentivizes those kind of
technological improvements.
Mr. Weber. Okay.
Dr. Greenstone. In fact, it would be terrific. It would
provide a market incentive----
Mr. Weber. Okay.
Dr. Greenstone. --to engage for people to find ways to
reduce----
Mr. Weber. Okay.
Dr. Greenstone. --CO<INF>2</INF> in the atmosphere.
Mr. Weber. Okay. Well, let me just----
Dr. Gayer. And be more resilient going forward.
Mr. Weber. --add for the record, Mr. Chairman, and I'm done
that in my district we have the largest carbon capture storage
unit, Air Products in--over in Jefferson County in the country.
So just interesting food for thought where we're headed with
this idea.
Mr. Chairman, I yield back.
Chairman Biggs. Thanks. I thank the witnesses for their
valuable testimony and the members for their questions. The
record will remain open for two weeks for additional comments
and written questions from members. This hearing is adjourned.
[Whereupon, at 12:03 p.m., the Subcommittees were
adjourned.]
Appendix I
----------
Answers to Post-Hearing Questions
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
Appendix II
----------
Additional Material for the Record
[GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]
[all]
</pre></body></html>